Impact of Government Environmental Regulations on Remanufacturing Supply Chain with Multi-Subject Responsibility for Recycling and Disposal
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
2.1. Research on Recycling and Remanufacturing from the Perspective of Government Financial Subsidy Policy
2.2. Research on Recycling and Remanufacturing from the Perspective of Government Rewards and Penalties
2.3. Research on Recycling and Remanufacturing from the Perspective of “Trade-In” Policies
3. Analytical Framework
3.1. Model Overview
3.2. Parameters and Variables
3.3. Model Assumptions
- (1)
- The market area is a deterministic demand market. The manufacturer determines the production of original and remanufactured products according to consumer demand, and the retailer determines the wholesale quantity of original and remanufactured products according to consumer demand.
- (2)
- In Model L, the game decision problem among the government, manufacturer, and retailer belongs to the three-stage Stackelberg game. The government decides in the first stage, the manufacturer decides in the second stage, and the retailer decides in the third stage. In Model N, this is a two-stage Stackelberg game, that is, the manufacturer decides in the first stage, and the retailer decides in the second stage.
- (3)
- All game players are completely rational, aiming at maximizing profits.
- (4)
- In Model N, the market demands of original and remanufactured products, respectively, are , [27].
- (5)
- In Model L, the consumer pays recycling and disposal fee when purchasing a unit of the original product; then, the price can be considered as . Therefore, the original and remanufactured product market demand, respectively, is , .
- (6)
- Government revenue is expressed as social welfare (which has been widely used in the relevant research literature [28,29,30]), including six elements: (i) Manufacturer’s profit ; (ii) Retailer’s profit ; (iii) The total utility of consumers (+); (iv) The original product recycling and disposal fee (zero if there is no government regulation) levied on the three parties; (v) The environmental benefits of the manufacturer’s production of remanufactured products ; (vi) The environmental governance cost (the number of products disposed of by the government is the number of products circulating in the supply chain, assuming that the d value of the original product is consistent with that of the remanufactured product).
- (7)
- This paper does not discuss the product life cycle problem, only considers the case of a single-period game. In this single period, the current market has enough old products to meet the remanufacturing production needs.
4. The Model
4.1. No Government Regulation Model (Model N)
4.2. Tripartite Liability System Model (Model L)
4.3. Comparison of the Two Models
- (i)
- , ;
- (ii)
- , ;
- (iii)
- , .
- (i)
- When government regulation is not implemented, the wholesale price and retail price of the original product have nothing to do with the unit production cost of the remanufactured product. When implementing government regulation, the wholesale price and retail price of the original product are related to the unit production cost of the remanufactured product, and the correlation is affected by the responsibility sharing ratio of the three parties.
- (ii)
- When government regulation is not implemented, the wholesale price and retail price of the original product are not related to the consumer’s acceptance of the remanufactured product. When government regulation is not implemented, the wholesale price and retail price of the original product are related to the consumer’s acceptance of the remanufactured product, and the correlation is affected by the responsibility sharing ratio of the three parties.
- (iii)
- The wholesale price and retail price of the original products will be affected by government regulation, and the price increase or decrease depends on the responsibility sharing ratio of the three parties.
- (i)
- , ;
- (ii)
- , .
- (i)
- , thus . , thus .
- (ii)
- , . □
- (i)
- Given that other parameters are unchanged, the optimal recycling and disposal fee has no relationship with the responsibility sharing ratio of the three parties.
- (ii)
- When , there are always , , , , .
- (i)
- Observing the expression of does not include the responsibility sharing ratio of the three parties, so the conclusion is established.
- (ii)
- When , , , , , . □
5. Numerical Analysis
5.1. Impact of the Change in the Responsibility Sharing Ratio on the Results
- (i)
- Compared with the absence of government regulation, although the tripartite liability system reduces the profits of remanufacturing supply chain members, it increases the output of remanufactured products and government social welfare and reduces the output of original products.
- (ii)
- In the tripartite liability system, when other parameters are fixed, the change in the responsibility sharing ratio among manufacturers, retailers, and consumers only affects the wholesale price and retail price of the original products, and other decisions and profits are not affected.
5.2. Impact of Main Parameters on the Profit of Supply Chain Members and Social Welfare
6. Conclusions
- (1)
- Compared with the absence of government regulation, the government’s implementation of the tripartite liability system helps to increase the output of remanufactured products while reducing the output of original products and increasing the government’s revenue (i.e., total social welfare), thus suggesting that the tripartite liability system is a useful policy to promote the development of the remanufacturing industry.
- (2)
- When the government implements the tripartite liability system, the share of tripartite responsibility only affects the wholesale and retail prices of original products, while other optimal decisions of supply chain members (e.g., production setting, pricing of remanufactured products) are not affected. In other words, given the other parameters remain unchanged, the optimal output of each product, the optimal recycling and disposal fee, the profit of supply chain member enterprises, and the government revenue are also fixed, independent of the apportionment ratio.
- (3)
- The profit of supply chain members under the tripartite liability system is convexly negatively related to the environmental benefit spillover per unit of recycled product, but the total social welfare is convexly positively related to it. This indicates that the stronger the pro-environmental spillover effect of remanufactured products under the implementation of the tripartite principal responsibility system, the higher the total social welfare.
- (4)
- When the government implements the tripartite principal responsibility system, the profit of supply chain member firms tends to decrease and then increase as consumer acceptance of remanufactured products increases, while the total social welfare tends to increase at the margin.
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Consumer Utility
References
- Esenduran, G.; Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya, E.; Swaminathan, J.M. Impact of take-back regulation on the remanufacturing industry. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2017, 26, 924–944. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zheng, Y.; Zhou, W.; Liu, C. Design of EPR under recycling channel competition. J. Manag. Sci. China 2017, 20, 103–115. [Google Scholar]
- Gui, L.; Atasu, A.; Ergun, O.; Toktay, L.B. Design incentives under collective extended producer responsibility: A network perspective. Manage. Sci. 2018, 64, 5083–5104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Yan, B.; Li, H.; Wang, T.; Liu, Y. Autonomous trade-in strategy for retailer with market segmentation. J. Manag. Sci. China 2017, 20, 120–136. [Google Scholar]
- Heydari, J.; Govindan, K.; Jafari, A. Reverse and closed loop supply chain coordination by considering government role. Transp. Res. D Transp. Environ. 2017, 52, 379–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mitra, S.; Webster, C. Competition in remanufacturing and the effect of government subsidies. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2008, 111, 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feng, D.; Shen, C.; Pei, Z. Production decisions of a closed-loop supply chain considering remanufacturing and refurbishing under government subsidy. Sustain. Prod. Consum. 2021, 27, 2058–2074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, X.; Li, Q.; Liu, Z.; Chang, C.T. Optimal pricing and remanufacturing mode in a closed-loop supply chain of WEEE under government fund policy. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2021, 151, 106951. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, J.; Lin, J. Pricing models of closed-loop supply chain under different subsidy policies. J. Ind. Eng. Eng. Manag. 2017, 31, 85–92. [Google Scholar]
- Gorji, M.A.; Jamali, M.B.; Iranpoor, M. A game-theoretic approach for decision analysis in end-of-life vehicle reverse supply chain regarding government subsidy. Waste Manag. 2021, 120, 734–747. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hammond, D.; Beullens, P. Closed-loop supply chain network equilibrium under legislation. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2007, 183, 895–908. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bansal, S.; Gangopadhyay, S. Tax/subsidy policies in the presence of environmentally aware customers. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2003, 45, 333–355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, W.; Zhang, Y.; Zhang, K.; Bai, T.; Shang, J. Reward-penalty mechanism for closed-loop supply chains under responsibility-sharing and different power structures. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 170, 178–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sheu, J.B.; Chen, Y.J. Impact of government financial intervention on competition among green supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2012, 138, 201–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, Q.; Zhang, H.; Liu, K. Research on closed-loop supply chain decision-making in different cooperation modes with government’s reward-penalty mechanism. Sustainability 2021, 13, 6425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huang, Y.; Wang, Z. Pricing decisions for closed-loop supply chains with technology licensing and carbon constraint under reward-penalty mechanism. J. Ind. Manag. Optim. 2023, 19, 3671–3693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alev, I.; Agrawal, V.V.; Atasu, A. Extended producer responsibility for durable products. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2019, 22, 364–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miao, C.; Xia, Z. Decision models for closed-loop supply chains with trade-ins. J. Manag. Sci. China 2016, 19, 49–66. [Google Scholar]
- Li, C.; Zhu, L. Optimal recovery strategies of home appliance trade-in scheme under EPR. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2017, 26, 67–75. [Google Scholar]
- Tang, F.; Ma, Z.; Dai, Y.; Choi, T.M. Upstream or Downstream: Who Should Provide Trade-in Services in Dyadic Supply Chains? Decis. Sci. 2021, 52, 1071–1108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Quan, Y.; Hong, J.; Song, J.; Leng, M. Game-theoretic analysis of trade-in services in closed-loop supply chains. Transp. Res. E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2021, 152, 102428. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ke, C.; Yan, B. Trade-in value effects of used products in remanufacturing with considering consumer purchase behavior. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2022, 73, 608–633. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fan, X.; Guo, X.; Wang, S. Optimal collection delegation strategies in a retail-/dual-channel supply chain with trade-in programs. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2022, 303, 633–649. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Giovanni, P.; Reddy, P.V.; Zaccour, G. Incentive strategies for an optimal recovery program in a closed-loop supply chain. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 249, 605–617. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ferrer, G.; Swaminathan, J.M. Managing new and remanufactured products. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 15–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wu, C.H. Product-design and pricing strategies with remanufacturing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2012, 222, 204–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ferguson, M.; Toktay, L. The effect of competition on recovery strategies. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2006, 15, 351–368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Walls, M.; Palmer, K. Upstream pollution, downstream waste disposal, and the design of comprehensive environmental policies. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2001, 41, 94–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dobbs, I.M. Litter and waste management: Disposal taxes versus user charges. Can. J. Econ. 1991, 24, 221–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sheu, J.B. Bargaining framework for competitive green supply chains under governmental financial intervention. Transp. Res. E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2011, 47, 573–592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Optimal Solution | Model N | Model L |
---|---|---|
N/A | ||
0.1 | 0.65 | 0.45 | 0.1667 | 0.0119 | 0.825 | 0.575 | N/A | 0.0613 | 0.0307 | 0.1003 | |
0 | 0.9 | 0.63 | 0.45 | 0.1333 | 0.0452 | 0.831 | 0.575 | 0.04 | 0.0553 | 0.0277 | 0.1004 |
0.1 | 0.8 | 0.634 | |||||||||
0.2 | 0.7 | 0.638 | |||||||||
0.3 | 0.6 | 0.642 | |||||||||
0.4 | 0.5 | 0.646 | |||||||||
0.5 | 0.4 | 0.65 | |||||||||
0.6 | 0.3 | 0.654 | |||||||||
0.7 | 0.2 | 0.658 | |||||||||
0.8 | 0.1 | 0.662 | |||||||||
0.9 | 0 | 0.666 |
0.1 | 0.65 | 0.45 | 0.1667 | 0.0119 | 0.825 | 0.575 | N/A | 0.0613 | 0.0307 | 0.1003 | |
0 | 0.9 | 0.63 | 0.45 | 0.1333 | 0.0452 | 0.799 | 0.575 | 0.04 | 0.0553 | 0.0277 | 0.1004 |
0.1 | 0.8 | 0.634 | 0.803 | ||||||||
0.2 | 0.7 | 0.638 | 0.807 | ||||||||
0.3 | 0.6 | 0.642 | 0.811 | ||||||||
0.4 | 0.5 | 0.646 | 0.815 | ||||||||
0.5 | 0.4 | 0.65 | 0.819 | ||||||||
0.6 | 0.3 | 0.654 | 0.823 | ||||||||
0.7 | 0.2 | 0.658 | 0.827 | ||||||||
0.8 | 0.1 | 0.662 | 0.831 | ||||||||
0.9 | 0 | 0.666 | 0.835 |
0.1 | 0.65 | 0.45 | 0.1667 | 0.0119 | 0.825 | 0.575 | N/A | 0.0613 | 0.0307 | 0.1003 | |
0 | 0.9 | 0.634 | 0.45 | 0.1333 | 0.0452 | 0.799 | 0.575 | 0.04 | 0.0553 | 0.0277 | 0.1004 |
0.1 | 0.8 | 0.803 | |||||||||
0.2 | 0.7 | 0.807 | |||||||||
0.3 | 0.6 | 0.811 | |||||||||
0.4 | 0.5 | 0.815 | |||||||||
0.5 | 0.4 | 0.819 | |||||||||
0.6 | 0.3 | 0.823 | |||||||||
0.7 | 0.2 | 0.827 | |||||||||
0.8 | 0.1 | 0.831 | |||||||||
0.9 | 0 | 0.835 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Jiang, X.; Hu, Q.; Lou, T.; Zuo, W.; Li, J. Impact of Government Environmental Regulations on Remanufacturing Supply Chain with Multi-Subject Responsibility for Recycling and Disposal. Mathematics 2023, 11, 1780. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11081780
Jiang X, Hu Q, Lou T, Zuo W, Li J. Impact of Government Environmental Regulations on Remanufacturing Supply Chain with Multi-Subject Responsibility for Recycling and Disposal. Mathematics. 2023; 11(8):1780. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11081780
Chicago/Turabian StyleJiang, Xiao, Qiang Hu, Tingyuan Lou, Wenjin Zuo, and Jicai Li. 2023. "Impact of Government Environmental Regulations on Remanufacturing Supply Chain with Multi-Subject Responsibility for Recycling and Disposal" Mathematics 11, no. 8: 1780. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11081780
APA StyleJiang, X., Hu, Q., Lou, T., Zuo, W., & Li, J. (2023). Impact of Government Environmental Regulations on Remanufacturing Supply Chain with Multi-Subject Responsibility for Recycling and Disposal. Mathematics, 11(8), 1780. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11081780