Next Article in Journal
Gelfand–Phillips Type Properties of Locally Convex Spaces
Previous Article in Journal
KOC_Net: Impact of the Synthetic Minority Over-Sampling Technique with Deep Learning Models for Classification of Knee Osteoarthritis Using Kellgren–Lawrence X-Ray Grade
Previous Article in Special Issue
A Divestment Model: Migration to Green Energy Investment Portfolio Concept
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Optimal Consumption and Investment with Income Adjustment and Borrowing Constraints

1
School of Natural Sciences, Seoul National University of Science and Technology, Seoul 01811, Republic of Korea
2
Department of Applied Mathematics, Kyung Hee University, Yongin 17104, Republic of Korea
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
Mathematics 2024, 12(22), 3536; https://doi.org/10.3390/math12223536
Submission received: 20 October 2024 / Revised: 8 November 2024 / Accepted: 12 November 2024 / Published: 12 November 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Financial Mathematics and Applications)

Abstract

:
In this paper, we address the utility maximization problem of an infinitely lived agent who has the option to increase their income. The agent can increase their income at any time, but doing so incurs a wealth cost proportional to the amount of the increase. To prevent the agent from infinitely increasing their income and borrowing against future income, we additionally consider a non-negative wealth constraint that prohibits borrowing based on future income. This utility maximization problem is a mixture of stochastic control, where the agent chooses consumption and investment, and singular control, where the agent chooses a non-decreasing income process. To solve this non-trivial and challenging problem, we derive the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equation with a gradient constraint using the dynamic programming principle (DPP). Then, using the guess-and-verify method and a linearization technique, we obtain a closed-form solution to the HJB equation and, based on this, find the optimal strategy.

1. Introduction

In recent decades, there has been substantial interest in continuous-time consumption and investment problems (e.g., Cheng and Escobar-Anel [1], Lee [2], and Wang et al. [3]), particularly in scenarios where agents have flexibility in labor decisions, such as adjusting working hours or choosing when to retire (see Bodie et al. [4], Bodie et al. [5], Choi et al. [6], Yang and Koo [7], Lee et al. [8], Park et al. [9], Jeon and Oh [10], and the references therein). However, existing research has largely overlooked the case where agents can actively increase their income through deliberate effort. Most models emphasize consumption and portfolio choices, but fail to fully account for the strategic role of income enhancement, which is crucial for understanding long-term financial planning, especially in the context of human capital development.
Incorporating the option to increase income is both novel and economically relevant. Individuals in real-world financial planning often have opportunities to boost their earnings, whether through additional work, skill acquisition, or entrepreneurial ventures. These opportunities can significantly influence consumption and investment behavior by providing a dynamic mechanism for wealth accumulation over time. Exploring the impact of such income adjustments is key to developing more realistic models that capture the flexibility people have in optimizing their financial decisions.
This paper introduces a model in which an agent has the option to increase their income at any time, but must incur a wealth cost proportional to the size of the income increase. This reflects the real-world situation where earning more—whether through overtime work, career progression, or business ventures—usually entails costs, such as education investments or lost leisure time. By incorporating a proportional wealth cost, we capture the fundamental trade-off between current consumption and future financial stability, which is at the heart of many financial decisions. This model provides a rich framework to study optimal consumption, investment, and income-adjustment strategies under realistic economic conditions.
The agent’s utility maximization problem discussed in this paper is highly applicable in scenarios where individuals have flexible income opportunities and need to balance immediate consumption with long-term financial stability. This type of model is especially useful for understanding financial planning decisions in real life, where people can increase income through additional work, skills training, or investments in their careers. It helps illustrate the trade-offs they face, such as spending on immediate needs versus investing in income-generating efforts for future growth.
This model is valuable for fields like retirement planning, human capital investment, and entrepreneurial finance, as it provides insights into how people can optimize both their consumption and savings while navigating real-world opportunities to grow income, ultimately enhancing their financial well-being.

Aim and Purpose of the Study

The main aim of this paper is to develop and solve a model that addresses optimal consumption, investment, and income adjustment for an infinitely lived agent, focusing on scenarios where income can be increased at any time with a proportional wealth cost. By examining this setup, we aim to provide insights into how agents with opportunities for income enhancement can best manage their consumption and investment choices over time. The purpose is to expand on the traditional consumption and portfolio optimization models by introducing the ability to alter income, capturing an essential aspect of real-world financial decision-making that has been largely neglected in the existing literature.
Specifically, we focus on solving the utility maximization problem for an agent with the flexibility to increase income while facing a non-negative wealth constraint to prevent borrowing against future earnings. This setup requires the integration of stochastic control for consumption and investment decisions with singular control for income adjustments, presenting a complex optimization problem.
To address this challenge, we derive the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equation with a gradient constraint through the dynamic programming approach. Using a guess-and-verify method and a linearization technique, we find a closed-form solution for the HJB equation, identifying the optimal strategies for consumption, investment, and income adjustment. This model offers a robust framework for understanding the trade-offs faced by agents with the ability to alter their income in the pursuit of long-term financial well-being.
Various Free Boundary Problems have been studied within the continuous-time consumption and investment problem framework (e.g., Davis and Norman [11], Dybvig [12], Deng et al. [13], and Jeon and Kwak [14]). We contribute to the literature by investigating the Free Boundary Problem that arises from the utility maximization problem, where the agent has the option to increase their income.
Our paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we introduce the agent’s preferences and income structure, and define the utility maximization problem. In Section 3, we derive the HJB equation with a gradient constraint using the DPP and obtain the solution in closed form. In Section 4, we characterize the optimal strategy by proving its optimality.

2. Model

We consider a continuous-time model with a complete financial market and an infinitely lived agent. Let ( B t ) t 0 be a standard Brownian motion defined on a usual probability space ( Ω , F t , F , P ) and equipped with the natural filtration F generated by ( B t ) t 0 .
For simplicity, we assume that there are only two assets in the financial market: a risk-free asset S 0 and a risky asset S 1 , with their dynamics given as follows:
d S 0 , t S 0 , t = r d t and d S 1 , t S 1 , t = μ d t + σ d B t ,
where r > 0 is the constant risk-free interest rate, μ r and σ > 0 are the expected return and volatility of stock S 1 , respectively.
Let c t and π t denote the agent’s consumption rate and the amount invested in the stock S 1 at time t 0 , respectively. Additionally, the agent receives a labor income flow Ξ t at time t. The agent can always increase the income process Ξ t , but doing so incurs a wealth cost p d Ξ t proportional to the increase by a factor of p > 0 .
Remark 1.
In practice, individuals may increase their income by taking on extra work, investing in education, or improving skills, but these adjustments involve costs. For instance, additional work can lead to physical and mental strain, often requiring financial resources for health maintenance. Likewise, pursuing further education entails financial expenses and time commitments, reflecting both opportunity and direct costs. In our model, we introduce a proportional cost p d Ξ t for any increase in income Ξ t , where p > 0 captures the intensity of these adjustment costs. This formulation aligns with labor economics findings, which highlight the rising costs associated with additional income efforts.
Remark 2.
From a mathematical perspective, it is possible to set Ξ t as a finite variation process. In this case, the income process Ξ t could be increased by incurring a cost, while a reduction in Ξ t would generate an additional income stream proportional to the decrease. Although this extension could lead to an interesting and challenging problem, from a practical standpoint, reducing income does not yield a compensatory "negative cost"; thus, there is no meaningful economic interpretation for receiving benefits simply by reducing income.
In this setting, the dynamics of the agent’s wealth X t c , π , Ξ under the given strategy ( c t , π t , Ξ t ) are as follows:
d X t c , π , Ξ = [ r X t c , π , Ξ + ( μ r ) π t c t + Ξ t ] d t + σ π d B t p d Ξ t with X 0 c , π , Ξ = x ,
where x is an initial endowment for the agnet.
Since the agent can borrow up to the present value of future income flows, Ξ t / r , at time t, the following non-negative wealth constraint or borrowing constraint is imposed to prevent unlimited borrowing:
X t c , π , Ξ 0 for   all t 0 .
Furthermore, we assume that the agent’s utility function follows the constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) form, as given below:
u ( c ) = c 1 γ 1 γ for γ > 0 , γ 1 ,
where γ is the constant relative risk aversion coefficient.
Now, we state our main problem.
Problem 1.
Let x > 0 and ξ > 0 be given. The agent faces the following utility maximization problem:
V ( x , ξ ) : = sup ( c , π , Ξ ) A ( x , ξ ) E 0 e β t u ( c t ) d t ,
where A ( x , ξ ) is the set of all admissible strategies ( c , π , Ξ ) , such that: (i) c t > 0 and π t are F -progressively measurable, satisfying 0 t c s d s < a.s., 0 t π s 2 d s < a.s., for all t 0 ; (ii) Ξ t is a F -adapted, positive, non-decreasing, and right-continuous with right limits process starting at Ξ 0 = ξ ; and (iii) the wealth X t c , π , Ξ corresponding to ( c , π , Ξ ) satisfies the borrowing constraint (3).
If the cost of increasing income exceeds the present value of the increase, the agent has no incentive to increase income. Thus, we impose the following assumption.
Assumption 1.
0 < p < 1 r .
If p is greater than or equal to 1 r , the agent will never increase their income. In this case, it is equivalent to a problem with a borrowing constraint on constant income (see El Karoui and Jeanblanc-Picqué [15]).
Additionally, for the well-definedness of the infinite horizon problem, the following assumption is necessary.
Assumption 2.
The Merton constant K (see Merton [16,17]), defined as
K : = r + β r γ + γ 1 γ 2 θ 2 2
is positive.
Problem 1 is a stochastic control problem mixed with singular control, where the agent must choose not only the consumption c t and investment π t , but also the non-decreasing income process Ξ t . To address this problem, we first derive the Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman (HJB) equation with a gradient constraint that the value function V ( x , ξ ) of Problem 1 satisfies, using the dynamic programming principle (DPP). By employing the guess-and-verify method, we derive a non-linear Free Boundary Problem from the HJB equation. We then obtain a closed-form solution to this Free Boundary Problem using a linearization technique.

3. Optimization Problem: Dynamic Programming Principle

By utilizing DPP, we derive the HJB equation with a gradient constraint for V ( x , ξ ) on D : = { ( x , ξ ) 0 < x < , 0 < ξ < } ,
max sup c > 0 , π R L c , π V ( w , ξ ) + u ( c ) , p x V + ξ V = 0 ,
where the operator L c , π for given ( c , π ) is defined by
L c , π : = σ 2 π 2 2 x x + ( r x + ( μ r ) π + ξ c ) x β .
Remark 3.
The HJB Equation (6) consists of two parts: the region where income is not increased, and the region where income is increased. This characteristic is similar to the form of the HJB equation dealt with in durable goods (e.g., Hindi and Huang [18], Steffensen [19]).
For given ( x , ξ ) , from the first-order condition of the static optimization problem inside the HJB equation, we obtain the following candidates for c and π :
u ( c ) = c γ = x V and π = θ σ x V x x V ,
where θ is the market price of risk (or Sharpe ratio), given by
θ : = μ r σ .
Let us consider the substitution
V ( x , ξ ) : = ξ 1 γ V ˜ ( z ) with z : = x ξ
and it follows from (8) that
c ξ = C ( z ) : = V ˜ ( z ) 1 γ and π ξ = θ σ V ˜ V ˜ .
By putting (8) into (6), it follows from (10) that
sup c > 0 , π R L c , π V ( w , ξ ) + u ( c ) = θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ
and
p x V + ξ V = ξ γ ( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) .
Thus, the HJB Equation (6) can be reduced as follows on the domain z > 0 :
max θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ , ( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ = 0 .
From the HJB Equation (12), we define the increasing region (IR) and waiting region (WR) as follows:
IR : = { z > 0 ( p + z ) V ˜ + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ = 0 } , WR : = { z > 0 ( p + z ) V ˜ + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ < 0 } .
We aim to solve the HJB Equation (12) by employing the guess and verify method, given the high nonlinearity of the equation. To proceed, we make the following intuitive conjectures:
  • The value function V ˜ ( z ) is strictly increasing, strictly concave, and twice continuously differentiable with respect to z ( 0 , ) .
  • There exists a critical boundary, z H , such that whenever the wealth to income ratio X t / Ξ t hits z H , the agent increases his/her income, incurring a cost. That is, IR = { z > 0 z z H } .
  • When the agent’s wealth decreases to 0, the agent reduces the risky investment to 0. That is, π t = 0 when X t = 0 .
Remark 4.
It is standard to impose the C 2 -condition on the solution of the HJB Equation (12) with a gradient constraint derived from the singular control problem (Problem 1). This C 2 -condition is essential for verification through Itô’s lemma, as it shows that the solution to the HJB Equation (6) corresponds to the solution of the agent’s utility maximization problem (Problem 1). Furthermore, the C 2 -condition implies that the agent optimally chooses the boundary z H where the income is increased.
According to the above conjectures, we consider the following Free Boundary Problem arising from the HJB Equation (12).
Free Boundary Problem: Find a strictly increasing, strictly concave, and twice continuously differentiable function V ˜ ( z ) in z > 0 , such that
θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ = 0 for 0 < z < z H , ( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) = ( p + z ) V ˜ + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ = 0 at z = z H , θ σ V ˜ V ˜ = 0 at z = 0 .
To linearize the first part of the Free Boundary Problem (14), we first assume that V ˜ is strictly increasing and concave with respect to z > 0 , i.e., V ˜ > 0 and V ˜ < 0 , and we will verify these assumptions later. From (10), there exists a inverse function X ( · ) of C ( · ) , i.e.,
X ( C ( z ) ) = z and C ( X ( λ ) ) = λ .
We define λ L and λ H by
λ H : = C ( z H ) and λ L : = C ( 0 ) .
Thus,
z H = X ( λ H ) and 0 = X ( λ L ) .
It follows that
V ˜ ( z ) = ( C ( z ) ) γ , V ˜ ( z ) = γ ( C ( z ) ) γ 1 C ( z ) = γ ( C ( z ) ) γ 1 X ( C ( z ) ) .
Since
0 = θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ for 0 < z < z H ,
we deduce that
β V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) + r z γ X ( λ ) + θ 2 2 γ λ 1 γ X ( λ ) + γ 1 γ λ 1 γ + λ γ = 0 .
or, equivalently,
V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) = 1 β r λ γ X ( λ ) + θ 2 2 γ λ 1 γ X ( λ ) + λ γ + γ 1 γ λ 1 γ .
By differentiating both sides of Equation (20) with respect to λ , we obtain that
θ 2 2 γ λ 2 X ( λ ) + r β + 1 γ 2 γ θ 2 λ X ( λ ) r γ X ( λ ) + γ λ γ = 0 for λ L < z < λ H .
Given that the ordinary differential equation (ODE) in (22) is of Cauchy–Euler form, we assumed a solution of the form X ( λ ) = λ n , where n is a constant to be determined. Substituting this form into the differential equation yields the following characteristic equation:
θ 2 2 n 2 + β r θ 2 2 n β = 0 .
This is a quadratic equation in n, and solving it gives two roots, n 1 > 0 and n 2 < 0 . Using these roots, we construct the general solution for the second-order Cauchy–Euler ODE as a linear combination of terms involving n 1 and n 2 , as shown in (24):
X ( λ ) = D 1 λ γ ( n 1 1 ) + D 2 λ γ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 K λ 1 r ,
where D 1 and D 2 are constants determined by the boundary conditions specific to the problem. This method is a well-established technique for solving Cauchy–Euler ODEs, utilizing the characteristic equation to find a complete solution.
By using the relation
( n 1 1 ) ( n 2 1 ) = 2 r θ 2 and n 1 n 2 = 2 β θ 2 ,
we can represent V ˜ in (21) as
V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) = n 1 1 n 1 D 1 λ γ n 1 + n 2 1 n 2 D 2 λ γ n 2 + 1 K λ 1 γ 1 γ for λ L < λ < λ H .
By the C 2 condition of V ˜ ( z ) at z = z H in (14),
( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( X ( λ H ) ) = ( p + X ( λ H ) ) ( λ H ) γ
and
0 = γ V ˜ ( X ( λ H ) ) ( p + X ( λ H ) ) V ˜ ( X ( λ H ) ) = γ λ H γ + ( p + X ( λ H ) ) γ λ H γ 1 X ( λ H ) .
From (27), we have
p + X ( λ H ) = λ H X ( λ H ) .
By (26), (27), and (28), we have
0 = ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) D 1 ( λ H ) γ ( n 1 1 ) + ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) D 2 ( λ H ) γ ( n 2 1 ) 1 r p , 0 = ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) n 1 D 1 ( λ H ) γ ( n 1 1 ) + ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) n 2 D 2 ( λ H ) γ ( n 2 1 ) 1 r p .
This yields that
D 1 = n 1 n 1 n 2 ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) 1 r p ( λ H ) γ ( n 1 1 ) , D 2 = n 2 n 2 n 1 ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) 1 r p ( λ H ) γ ( n 2 1 ) .
By Assumption 1,
0 < p < 1 r .
Thus, it follows from n 1 > 0 , n 2 < 0 , 1 γ + γ n 1 > 0 and 1 γ + γ n 2 < 0 that
D 1 > 0 and D 2 > 0 .
Since ( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) = 0 for z z H , there exists a constant D 3 , such that
V ˜ ( z ) = D 3 ( z + p ) 1 γ 1 γ for z z H .
By (26), we have
( p + z H ) ( λ H ) γ = D 3 ( p + z H ) 1 γ , or   equivalently D 3 = λ H p + z H γ .
Since V ˜ ( z ) = ( C ( z ) ) γ for z ( 0 , z H ) , we can extend X ( λ ) from λ ( λ L , λ H ) to λ ( λ L , ) as
X ( λ ) = D 1 λ γ ( n 1 1 ) + D 2 λ γ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 K λ 1 r for λ L < λ < λ H z H + p λ H λ p for z λ H .
Since X ( C ( z ) ) = z , it follows from (25) that
V ˜ ( z ) = n 1 1 n 1 D 1 ( C ( z ) ) γ n 1 + n 2 1 n 2 D 2 ( C ( z ) ) γ n 2 + 1 K ( C ( z ) ) 1 γ 1 γ for 0 < z < z H , λ H p + z H γ ( z + p ) 1 γ 1 γ for z z H .
Moreover, X ( λ L ) = 0 implies that
1 K λ L = n 1 n 1 n 2 ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) 1 r p λ H λ L γ ( n 1 1 ) + n 2 n 2 n 1 ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) 1 r p λ H λ L γ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 r .
Since θ σ V ˜ ( 0 ) V ˜ ( 0 ) = 0 in (14), we deduce that X ( λ L ) . = 0 . This yields that
0 = λ L X ( λ L ) = γ ( n 1 1 ) D 1 ( λ L ) γ ( n 1 1 ) γ ( n 2 1 ) D 2 ( λ L ) γ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 K λ L = ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) D 1 ( λ L ) γ ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) D 2 ( λ L ) γ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 r = ψ λ H γ λ L γ ,
where ψ ( ζ ) is defined as
ψ ( ζ ) : = n 1 ( n 2 1 ) n 1 n 2 ζ n 1 1 + n 2 ( n 1 1 ) n 2 n 1 ζ n 2 1 + 1 1 r p .
Since ψ ( 1 ) = r p / ( 1 r p ) > 0 , ψ ( ) = , and ψ ( ζ ) < 0 for ζ > 1 , there exists a unique ζ ¯ > 1 , such that ψ ( ζ ¯ ) = 0 .
By (36), we have
1 K λ L = n 1 n 1 n 2 ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) 1 r p ζ ¯ ( n 1 1 ) + n 2 n 2 n 1 ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) 1 r p ζ ¯ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 r
and
λ H = ζ ¯ 1 γ λ L .
Lemma 1.
λ L > 0 and λ H > 0 .
Proof. 
It suffices to show λ L > 0 .
Let us temporarily denote Υ ( ζ , γ ) by
Υ ( ζ , γ ) : = n 1 n 1 n 2 ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) 1 r p ζ ( n 1 1 ) + n 2 n 2 n 1 ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) 1 r p ζ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 r
Clearly, λ L = K Υ ( ζ ¯ , γ ) .
Since ζ ¯ is independent of γ in ψ ( ζ ¯ ) = 0 , we have
γ Υ ( ζ ¯ , γ ) = n 1 n 1 n 2 ( n 1 1 ) ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) 2 1 r p ζ ¯ ( n 1 1 ) n 2 n 2 n 1 ( n 1 1 ) ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) 2 1 r p ζ ¯ ( n 2 1 ) > 0 .
Hence,
Υ ( ζ ¯ , γ ) > Υ ( ζ ¯ , 0 ) = 1 r p ψ ( ζ ¯ ) = 0 .
Thus, we conclude that λ L > 0 and λ H > 0 . □
Lemma 2.
X ( λ ) in (34) is a continuously differentiable and strictly increasing function in λ ( λ L , ) . Moreover,
X ( λ ) > 0 f o r λ > λ L .
Proof. 
By the construction of X ( λ ) , it is easy to check that X ( λ ) is continuously differentiable with respect to λ > λ L .
By direct computation, it follows from D 1 > 0 and D 2 > 0 that
X ( λ ) = γ ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) D 1 λ γ ( n 1 1 ) 2 + γ ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) D 2 λ γ ( n 2 1 ) > 0 for   all λ > λ L .
Since X ( λ L ) = X ( λ L ) = 0 , we conclude that, for all λ ( λ L , ) ,
X ( λ ) > 0 and X ( λ ) > 0 .
Proposition 1.
V ˜ ( z ) in (35) satisfies the following properties:
(a) 
V ˜ ( z ) is twice continuously differentiable, strictly increasing and strictly concave in z > 0 .
(b) 
V ˜ ( z ) satisfies the HJB equation in (12). Moreover,
IR = { z > 0 z z H } a n d WR = { z > 0 0 < z < z H } .
Proof. 
Since
V ˜ ( z ) = ( C ( z ) ) γ , ( p + z H ) V ˜ ( z H ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z H ) = 0 , and p + z H = λ H X ( λ H ) ,
we can easily confirm that
lim z z H V ˜ ( z ) = ( z H + p ) λ H γ 1 γ = lim z z H + V ˜ ( z ) , lim z z H V ˜ ( z ) = λ H γ = lim z z H + V ˜ ( z ) , lim z z H V ˜ ( z ) = lim z z H γ ( C ( z ) ) γ 1 C ( z ) = lim z z H γ ( C ( z ) ) γ 1 X ( C ( z ) ) = γ λ H γ z H + p = lim z z H + V ˜ ( z ) .
Thus, V ˜ ( z ) is twice continuously differentiable with respect to z > 0 .
Moreover,
V ˜ ( z ) = ( C ( z ) ) γ > 0 for 0 < z < z H , λ H z H + p γ ( z + p ) γ > 0 for z z H ,
and
V ˜ ( z ) = γ ( C ( z ) ) γ 1 C ( z ) < 0 for 0 < z < z H , γ λ H z H + p γ ( z + p ) γ 1 < 0 for z z H ,
where we have used the fact C ( z ) > 0 and C ( z ) > 0 . That is, V ˜ ( z ) is strictly increasing and strictly concave in z > 0 .
By the construction of V ˜ ( z ) in (35), we can easily check that, for 0 < z < z H ,
θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ = 0 .
Let us temporarily denote Ψ ( λ ) by
Φ ( λ ) : = λ γ ( p + X ( λ ) ) V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) .
It follows from (34) and (35) that, for λ L < z < λ H ,
Φ ( λ ) = ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) n 1 D 1 λ γ ( n 1 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) n 2 D 2 λ γ ( n 2 1 ) + 1 r p .
This yields that, for λ L < λ < λ H ,
Φ ( λ ) = γ ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) 2 ( n 1 1 ) n 1 D 1 λ γ ( n 1 1 ) 2 γ ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) 2 ( n 2 1 ) n 2 D 2 λ γ ( n 2 1 ) 2 < 0 .
Since Φ ( λ H ) = Φ ( λ H ) = 0 , we obtain that
Φ ( λ ) > 0 for λ L < z < λ H .
and
Φ ( λ ) < Φ ( λ H ) = 0 for λ L < λ < λ H .
That is,
Φ ( λ ) = z γ ( p + X ( λ ) ) V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( X ( λ ) ) < 0 .
By putting C ( z ) into the above equation instead of λ , we have
( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) < 0 for 0 < z < z H .
Overall,
WR = { z > 0 ( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) < 0 } = { z > 0 0 < z < z H } .
On the other hand, if z z H ,
V ˜ ( z ) = λ H z H + p γ ( z + p ) 1 γ 1 γ .
Thus, it is clear that
( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) = 0 .
Moreover, for z z H , we derive that
θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ = θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r ( z + p ) + 1 r p ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ = γ 1 γ λ H p + z H γ λ H p + z H K ( p + z ) 1 γ + λ H p + z H γ ( p + z ) γ ( 1 r p ) .
It follows from (24) and (28) that
λ H p + z H K = K X ( λ H ) 1 K X ( λ H ) = K X ( λ H ) γ ( n 1 1 ) D 1 ( λ H ) γ ( n 1 1 ) 1 + γ ( n 2 1 ) D 2 ( λ H ) γ ( n 2 1 ) 1 = K λ H X ( λ H ) γ ( n 1 1 ) ( n 2 1 ) n 1 n 2 1 r p n 1 1 γ + γ n 1 + n 2 1 γ + γ n 2 = 1 γ γ ( 1 r p ) p + z H ,
where we have used the following relation:
r K = γ 2 ( n 1 1 ) ( n 2 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 1 ) ( 1 γ + γ n 2 ) .
This implies that, for z z H ,
θ 2 2 ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 2 V ˜ ( z ) + ( r z + 1 ) V ˜ ( z ) β V ˜ ( z ) + γ 1 γ ( V ˜ ( z ) ) 1 γ γ = λ H p + z H γ ( 1 r p ) ( p + z ) γ 1 p + z p + z H 0 ,
and IR = { z > 0 ( p + z ) V ˜ ( z ) + ( 1 γ ) V ˜ ( z ) = 0 } = { z > 0 z z H } .
Hence, we conclude that V ˜ ( z ) satisfies the HJB equation in (12). □
From (9),
V ( x , ξ ) = ξ 1 γ V ˜ x ξ .
Consequently, we directly obtain the following corollary.
Corollary 1.
V ( x , ξ ) in (62) is a strictly increasing and strictly concave function of x > 0 , satisfying the HJB Equation (6). Moreover, V ( x , ξ ) C 2 ( R + × R + ) .

4. Optimal Strategies

By the strictly increasing property of X ( η ) , for given x > 0 and ξ > 0 , there exists a unique λ ( λ L , ) , such that
x ξ = X ( λ ) .
To describe the optimal strategy, we introduce a regulated geometric Brownian motion Λ t with boundaries at λ L and λ H . This process is governed by the following stochastic differential equation with two reflecting boundaries (SDER):
d Λ t = r β γ + ( γ + 1 ) 2 γ 2 θ 2 Λ t d t + θ γ Λ t d B t + d L t d H t , Λ 0 = λ [ λ L , λ H ] ,
Here, H = { H t } and L = { L t } , t 0 , represent the regulators at the boundaries λ H and λ L , respectively. These are the local times of Λ at the boundaries λ H and λ L . The processes H and L are determined by the following properties:
(i)
Both H t and L t are continuous, non-decreasing functions with H 0 = L 0 = 0 .
(ii)
Λ t remains in the interval [ λ L , λ H ] for all t 0 .
(iii)
H and L increase only when Λ hits the boundaries, i.e.,
0 t 1 { Λ s = λ H } d H s = H t and 0 t 1 { Λ s = λ L } d L s = L t ,
for any t [ 0 , T ] .
As shown by Lions and Sznitman [20], the SDER (64) admits a unique strong solution Λ t , which remains confined within the interval [ λ L , λ H ] for all t 0 .
Let us define Ξ t as
d log Ξ t = X ( Λ t * ) p d H t with Ξ 0 = ξ .
Based on Ξ t and Λ t , let us denote c t , π t , and X t by
c t = Λ t Ξ t , π t = θ γ σ X ( Λ t ) Λ t Ξ t , and X t = X ( Λ t ) Ξ t .
By applying the generalized Itô lemma to X t , we deduce that
d X t = [ r X t + ( μ r ) π t c t + Ξ t ] d t + σ π t d B t p d Ξ t with X 0 = x .
That is, X t = X t c , π , Ξ and ( c , π , Ξ ) A ( x , ξ ) .
Thus, by utilizing a standard verification argument, we can easily obtain the following theorem.
Theorem 1.
Let x > 0 and ξ > 0 be given. Then,
V ( x , ξ ) = sup ( c t , π t , Ξ t ) A ( x , ξ ) E 0 e β t u ( c t ) d t = E 0 e β t u ( c t ) d t .
That is, ( c , π , Ξ ) A ( x , ξ ) is the optimal strategy.

5. Implications

In this section, we provide numerical results regarding the optimal strategies obtained in Theorem 1. The baseline parameters used for this purpose are given as follows:
β = 0.04 , r = 0.02 , μ = 0.08 , σ = 0.2 , and γ = 2 .
Figure 1 shows the simulation paths of consumption to income c t / Ξ t , wealth to income X t / Ξ t , and income Ξ t . As seen in the figure, whenever c t / Ξ t or X t / Ξ t reaches the upper boundary λ H or z H , the agent increases their income Ξ t .
As the proportional cost p of increasing income rises, the agent is less inclined to raise their income. This intuition can be observed in Figure 2. More precisely, the agent increases income each time the wealth to income ratio X t / Ξ t reaches the upper boundary z H . As shown in Figure 2, since z H is an increasing function of p, we can infer that a higher p discourages the agent from increasing their income as frequently.
Figure 3 illustrates the impact of the cost p on the optimal strategy. As seen in the figure, as the cost p increases, the agent tends to increase consumption and reduce investment in risky assets.

6. Concluding Remarks

In this paper, we address the optimal consumption and investment problem for an infinitely lived agent who has the option to increase income at a cost. The agent also faces a borrowing constraint, which prevents them from borrowing against future income flows. This utility maximization problem for the agent features both stochastic control and singular control characteristics, and the domain of the state variable is restricted due to the borrowing constraint. To tackle this challenging problem, we derive the HJB equation arising from the agent’s utility maximization problem and, using the guess-and-verify method, obtain the agent’s optimal strategy in closed form.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, G.K.; Methodology, J.J.; Formal analysis, G.K.; Investigation, G.K. and J.J.; Writing—original draft, J.J. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by Seoul National University of Science and Technology.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Cheng, Y.; Escobar-Anel, M. Optimal Consumption and Robust Portfolio Choice for the 3/2 and 4/2 Stochastic Volatility Models. Mathematics 2023, 11, 4020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Lee, H.-S. Life Insurance and Subsistence Consumption with an Exponential Utility. Mathematics 2021, 9, 358. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Wang, Y.; Lin, J.; Chen, D.; Zhang, J. Optimal Investment–Consumption–Insurance Problem of a Family with Stochastic Income under the Exponential O-U Model. Mathematics 2023, 11, 4148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Bodie, Z.; Merton, R.C.; Samuelson, W.F. Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Choice in a Life Cycle Model. J. Econ. Dyn. Control. 1992, 16, 427–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Bodie, Z.; Detemple, J.B.; Otruba, S.; Walter, S. Optimal Consumption–Portfolio Choices and Retirement Planning. J. Econ. Dyn. Control. 2004, 28, 1115–1148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Choi, K.J.; Shim, G.; Shin, Y.H. Optimal Portfolio, Consumption-Leisure, and Retirement Choice Problem with CES Utility. Math. Financ. 2008, 18, 445–472. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Yang, Z.; Koo, H.K. Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Selection with Early Retirement Option. Math. Oper. Res. 2018, 43, 1378–1404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lee, H.S.; Shim, G.; Shin, Y.H. Borrowing Constraints, Effective Flexibility in Labor Supply, and Portfolio Selection. Math. Financ. Econ. 2019, 13, 173–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Park, K.; Lee, H.; Shin, Y.H. Effects of a Government Subsidy and Labor Flexibility on Portfolio Selection and Retirement. Quant. Financ. 2021, 21, 967–989. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Jeon, J.; Oh, J. Labor Supply Flexibility and Portfolio Selection with Early Retirement Option. Appl. Math. Optim. 2023, 88, 88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Davis, M.H.A.; Norman, A.R. Portfolio Selection with Transaction Costs. Math. Oper. Res. 1990, 15, 676–713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Dybvig, P.H. Dusenberry’s Ratcheting of Consumption: Optimal Dynamic Consumption and Investment Given Intolerance for any Decline in Standard of Living. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1995, 62, 287–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Deng, S.; Li, X.; Pham, H.; Yu, X. Optimal Consumption with Reference to Past Spending Maximum. Financ. Stochastics 2022, 26, 217–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Jeon, J.; Kwak, M. Optimal Consumption and Investment with Welfare Constraints. Financ. Stochastics 2024, 28, 391–451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. El Karoui, N.; Jeanblanc-Picqué, M. Optimization of Consumption with Labor Income. Financ. Stochastics 1998, 2, 409–440. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Merton, R. Lifetime Portfolio Selection Under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1969, 51, 247–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Merton, R. Optimum Consumption and Portfolio Rules in a Continuous-Time Model. J. Econ. Theory 1971, 3, 373–413. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Hindi, K.; Huang, C.F. Optimal Consumption and Portfolio Rules with Durability and Local Substitution. Econometrica 1993, 61, 85–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Steffensen, M. On Merton’s Problem for Life Insurers. ASTIN Bull. 2004, 34, 5–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Lions, P.L.; Sznitman, A.S. Stochastic Differential Equations with Reflecting Boundary Conditions. Commun. Pure Appl. Math. 1984, 37, 511–537. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Simulation results for consumption to income, wealth to income, and income processes. (a) Consumption to income c t / Ξ t ; (b) wealth to income X t / Ξ t ; (c) income Ξ t .
Figure 1. Simulation results for consumption to income, wealth to income, and income processes. (a) Consumption to income c t / Ξ t ; (b) wealth to income X t / Ξ t ; (c) income Ξ t .
Mathematics 12 03536 g001
Figure 2. The wealth to income boundary z H .
Figure 2. The wealth to income boundary z H .
Mathematics 12 03536 g002
Figure 3. The effect of cost p on the optimal strategy. (a) X t / Ξ t and c t / Ξ t . (b) X t / Ξ t and π t / Ξ t .
Figure 3. The effect of cost p on the optimal strategy. (a) X t / Ξ t and c t / Ξ t . (b) X t / Ξ t and π t / Ξ t .
Mathematics 12 03536 g003
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kim, G.; Jeon, J. Optimal Consumption and Investment with Income Adjustment and Borrowing Constraints. Mathematics 2024, 12, 3536. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12223536

AMA Style

Kim G, Jeon J. Optimal Consumption and Investment with Income Adjustment and Borrowing Constraints. Mathematics. 2024; 12(22):3536. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12223536

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kim, Geonwoo, and Junkee Jeon. 2024. "Optimal Consumption and Investment with Income Adjustment and Borrowing Constraints" Mathematics 12, no. 22: 3536. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12223536

APA Style

Kim, G., & Jeon, J. (2024). Optimal Consumption and Investment with Income Adjustment and Borrowing Constraints. Mathematics, 12(22), 3536. https://doi.org/10.3390/math12223536

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop