Do Trade and Investment Agreements Promote Foreign Direct Investment within Latin America? Evidence from a Structural Gravity Model
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- (i)
- What is the impact of regional agreements and BITs on intraregional FDI in Latin America? In particular, the paper focuses on the FDI creation and diversion effects of the two main RTAs in the region, Mercosur (Southern Common Market) and ALADI (The Latin American Integration Association). The study explores the relative effectiveness—interaction and complementarity—of trade and investment treaties regarding their impact on FDI.
- (ii)
- Do the qualitative aspects of BITs, as measured by a new index, matter for their efficacy?
- (iii)
- Do the specific institutional characteristics of recipient countries determine or condition the effectiveness of major RTAs and BITs?
2. An Overview of Integration Agreements in Latin America and the Links between RTAs, BITs and FDI
2.1. The Relationship between Regional Trade Agreements and Foreign Direct Investment
2.2. Bilateral Investment Treaties and Foreign Direct Investment
3. Theoretical Framework: The Gravity Model for FDI
4. Data and Empirical Strategy
4.1. Descriptive Analysis
4.2. Empirical Strategy: Estimation of the Gravity Equation for FDI
- The analysis uses time invariant country pair fixed effects to correct for endogeneity due to unobserved heterogeneity in country pairs. In cross sections of country-pairs observed repeatedly over time, previous empirical studies suggest the inclusion of country-pair fixed effects in order to absorb the potential correlation between one or several regressors and the error term [13,47]. This way of controlling for country-pair and multilateral resistances with country-time fixed effects leads to estimates that can be interpreted as a difference-in-difference direct effect of the Mercosur, ALADI and BIT agreements on bilateral FDI.
- If a group of countries interchange vast amounts of FDI, it is possible that they may be prompted to set up a RTA or a BIT. In this case, refs [3,47] recommend testing for endogeneity associated with reverse causation by including future leads of the RTA and BIT variables in the estimation. The empirical analysis also incorporates this approach in the estimations.
- The GDP of the home and host country are expected to have a positive impact on FDI. In the case of the destination country, a larger level of income is tantamount to a more dynamic market.
- The variable, , which is the sum of the GDP of the countries linked to the recipient by a trade agreement, is intended to capture the extended market effect [10]. Note that the gravity equation is an expenditure function and we must use variables in nominal terms, to avoid what is called the bronze medal mistake (see [3]).
- The analysis uses two dyad variables, one to capture the FDI creation and the other the FDI diversion effect of Mercosur, in the spirit of [10,53]. The variables are Mercosur and One Mercosur, respectively. The Mercosur variable reflects the original treaty and the subsequent creation of free trade agreements with the associate members. Mercosur is a dummy which takes the value one when both countries, i and j, are part of Mercosur (either as original signatories, as an associated member or as signing a FTA with full scope, as described in the Appendix A) in a particular year t, and 0 otherwise. Since associated members incorporated in Mercosur in different years, it follows that the variable Mercosur exhibits time and country-pair variation.
- 4.
- The empirical analysis captures the effect of BITs in two ways. The variable BIT takes the value 1 if a ratified agreement is in place between the pair of countries at time t, and 0 otherwise. This variable captures the signaling effect. Second, the variable BIT-index is a continuous variable in the interval (0,1) which captures the degree of investment protection conferred by the said BIT. It is constructed in the spirit of [17,18].
- 5.
- To capture the enhancing or overlapping effects between trade agreements and BITs, the empirical analysis includes interactions in the model, i.e., Mercosur and ALADI are multiplied by the BIT investor protection index.
- 6.
- The relative availability and costs of inputs, which may have an important role in location decisions are FactorEndow and laborCost [9]. Following [57], FactorEndow measures the difference in the capital/labor ratio between the two countries. LaborCost captures the gap between countries in the price of labor. Because of the absence of good data on this issue, the analysis uses official data from the International Labor Organization (ILO). ILO assumes that real wages are equal to productivity, defined as the ratio GDP/number of workers.
- 7.
- The Political Risk variable accounts for the degree of consolidation of the rule of law, social, economic and political institutions and political stability. It has been constructed from the World Bank Aggregate Governance Indicator 1995–2018, complemented with the International Country Risk Indexes from Princeton University.
5. Empirical Results
6. Concluding Remarks
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Abbreviations
ALADI | The Latin American Integration Association/Asociación Latinoamericana de Integración |
ASEAN | Association of Southeast Asian Nations |
BITs | Bilateral investment treaties |
CEPII | French Centre d’Etudes Prospectives et d’Informations Internationales |
CUSFTA | The Canada-United States Free Trade Agreement |
FDI | Foreign direct investment |
FE | Fixed effects |
FET | Fair and equitable treatment |
GDP | Gross Domestic Product |
GNLM | Generalized Nonlinear Linear Model |
IHS | Inverse hyperbolic sine transformation |
ILO | International Labor Organization |
IMF | International Monetary Fund |
ISDS | Investor-state dispute settlement |
Mercosur | Mercado comun del sur |
MFN | Most-favored-nation clause |
MNEs | Multinational enterprises |
MRs | Multilateral resistances |
NAFTA | North American Free Trade Agreement |
NT | National treatment |
OECD | The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development |
OLS | Ordinary least square |
PPML | Poisson pseudo-maximum likelihood |
RTAs | Regional trade agreements |
SSDS | State-State dispute settlement |
UNCTAD | United Nations Commission for Trade and Development |
WTO | World Trade Organization |
Appendix A
Appendix A.1. Clauses Mapped in the BIT Investment Protection Index
- National treatment (NT) pre-establishment: Ensures that requirements for foreign firms upon entry in the host country, such as establishment and participation in existing enterprises, are no greater than those for domestic firms. If the clause is present, the index in this section sums 1 in this category, 0 otherwise.
- National treatment post establishment: The same as 1 but associated with “the treatment of the investment after its entry”. If present, the index in this category takes value 1, 0 otherwise.
- Most-favored-nation (MFN) treatment pre-establishment: MFN treatment of the foreign firm regarding entry, establishment and participation in existing enterprises. If present, the index in this category takes value 1, 0 otherwise.
- Most-favored-nation (MFN) treatment post-establishment: The same as 3, after the entry of the foreign firm. If the clause is present it takes value 1.
- Fair and equitable treatment (FET): Can be qualified either by reference to International Law (General International Law, Principles of International Law or Customary International Law) or “by listing the elements of the FET obligation”. In the last case, the FET obligation may “include an indicative or exhaustive list of more specific elements” to avoid.
- Full protection and security: This commitment, in turn, may be:
- Standard “if the treaty contains an unqualified obligation to provide full protection and security” (with formulations such as most constant protection, legal protection and security, and so forth).
- Referenced to domestic law of the host country
- No general security exception: Ensures that the host country does not prevent investment in a particular sector for security reasons.
- Indirect expropriation: Treaties may refer to this issue under two approaches: the scope of measures covered, and/or refining expropriation clauses.
- Indirect expropriation mentioned, whatever the formulae it employs (“measures having effect equivalent to nationalization or expropriation”, measures tantamount to expropriation, de facto expropriation).
- No expropriation clause “if the treaty does not include a provision that protects foreign investors against non-compensated dispossession of their investments”.
- 9.
- Transfer of funds: A “provision regarding the free transfer of funds relating to investments (covering outward and/or inward transfers”. If present, the index in this category takes a value of 1.
- 10.
- Performance requirements: If the treaty includes a provision that restricts the use of performance requirements, the measure in these clause takes value 1.
- 11.
- Umbrella clause: requiring the signatories “to respect or observe any obligation assumed by it with regard to a specific investment”, hence protecting it de facto under its umbrella. The measure in these clause takes value 1.
- 12.
- State-State Dispute Settlement (SSDS): If the treaty provides for a dispute settlement procedure (e.g., arbitration) between States, the measure in this clause takes value 1.
- 13.
- Investor-State Dispute Settlement (ISDS): If the treaty establishes a mechanism for the settlement of disputes between covered investors and the host State (arbitration and/or domestic courts of the host State) the measure in these clause takes value 1.
- 14.
- Alternatives to arbitration: The more options at investors’ disposal the better, although we assign a value of 0.5 to a treaty that establishes that the investor needs to go first through a local court before international arbitration.
- “Voluntary Alternative Dispute Resolution (conciliation/mediation)” “If the treaty mentions the possibility of such procedures (e.g., non-binding, third-party procedures) but does not prescribe them as a necessary step”.
- “Compulsory Alternative Dispute Resolution (conciliation/mediation) If the treaty prescribes the use of compulsory conciliation or mediation.
- “None” if the treaty does not refer to alternative means of settling investor–State disputes (conciliation/mediation or similar non-binding procedures).
Appendix A.2. Construction of the Mercosur and ALADI Variables
- All Mercosur original countries (Argentina, Brazil, Paraguay and Uruguay) and Chile entered into a FTA (Free Trade Agreement named AAP.CE number 35) in 1996.
- All Mercosur original countries and Bolivia entered into a FTA (Free Trade Agreement AAP.CE number 36) in 1997.
- All Mercosur original countries and Colombia and Ecuador entered into a FTA (Free Trade Agreement named AAP.CE number 59) in 2005.
- All Mercosur original countries and Mexico entered into a FTA (Free Trade Agreement named AAP.CE number 54 and 55) in 2006.
- All Mercosur original countries and Peru entered into a FTA (Free Trade Agreement, named AAP.CE number 58) in 2006.
- Paraguay was suspended as a member during 2012.
Argentina | Bolivia | Brazil | Chile | Colombia | Ecuador | Mexico | Paraguay | Peru | Uruguay | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Argentina | 1995 | |||||||||
Bolivia | 2006 | |||||||||
Brazil | 1995 | |||||||||
Chile | 2006 | 2007 | 1999 | 2007 | ||||||
Colombia | 2007 | 1995 | ||||||||
Costa Rica | ||||||||||
Ecuador | 2010 | |||||||||
Mexico | 1999 | 1995 | 2004 | |||||||
Paraguay | ||||||||||
Peru | 2007 | |||||||||
Uruguay | 2004 |
- Argentina and Brazil signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 14 in 1999.
- Bolivia and Chile signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 22 in 2006.
- Chile and Mexico signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 41 in 1999.
- Chile and Bolivia signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 22 in 2006.
- Chile and Colombia signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 22 in 2007 (they had a previous partial agreement since 1995).
- Chile and Mexico signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 41 in 1999.
- Chile and Peru signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 38 in 2007 (they had a previous partial scope agreement since 1998).
- Colombia and Mexico signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 33 in 1995.
- Ecuador has not engaged in any free trade zone with other Latin American countries. It has a partial scope agreement with Chile since 2010.
- Mexico and Uruguay signed the RTA called AAP.CE number 60 in 2004.
Argentina | Bolivia | Brazil | Chile | Colombia | Costa Rica | Ecuador | Mexico | Paraguay | Peru | Uruguay | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Argentina | 2005 | 1995 | 2001 | 1996 | 1998 | 1995 | 1996 | ||||
Bolivia | 2005 | 1999 | 1997 | 2003 | 1995 | ||||||
Brazil | |||||||||||
Chile | 1995 | 1999 | 2000 | 1996 | 1998 | 2001 | 2010 | ||||
Colombia | 2004 | ||||||||||
Costa Rica | 2001 | 2000 | 2001 | ||||||||
Ecuador | 1996 | 1997 | 1996 | 1995–2008 | 2000 | 1985–2008 | |||||
Mexico | 1998 | 2002 | |||||||||
Paraguay | 1995 | 2003 | 1998 | 2001 | 1995–2008 | 1995 | 1994 | ||||
Peru | 1996 | 1995 | 2001 | 2004 | 2000 | 1995 | |||||
Uruguay | 2010 | 1985-2008 | 2002 | 1994 |
Appendix A.3. Gravity Model for FDI
Appendix A.4. Data and Robustness Tests
Variable | Description | Source |
---|---|---|
Bilateral Foreign Direct Investment stocks | UNCTAD (proprietary data from 1990–2008 and 2012–2018). Foreign Direct Investment Statistics database. | |
GDP home/host country (dollars 2010) | Balance of Payments, IMF | |
Bilateral distance between two countries based on distances between their biggest cities | CEPII dataset available http://www.cepii.fr/CEPII/en/bdd_modele/presentation.asp?id=6 | |
Sum of GDP to which the host country has tariff-free access. | Own elaboration from IMF http://www.imf.org/external/ns/cs.aspx?id=28 | |
Adjacency | Dummy, takes value 1 when countries share border, 0 otherwise. | Own elaboration |
Mercosur | Dummy, 1 when both countries belong to Mercosur, including associated members and deep FTA within Mercosur framework, 0 otherwise. | Own elaboration |
ONE Mercosur | Dummy: 1 if recipient country belongs to Mercosur, and sender country does not, 0 otherwise. | Own elaboration |
ALADI | Dummy: 1 when both countries belong to a FTA within the ALADI framework, 0 otherwise. | Own elaboration |
BITs | Dummy: 1 when there is a BIT in force among the two countries, 0 otherwise | World Trade Organization database (WTO) |
BIT index | Continuous variable in the interval (0,1). See text for details and Appendix A below | Own elaboration with data from UNCTAD (2017) |
FactEndow | Difference between home and host country ratio of gross fixed capital formation over labor force | World Development Indicators; labor force from ILO, UN |
LaborCost Dif | Difference in the Relative Cost of Labor among the home and host country | International Labor Organization http://www.ilo.org/global/statistics-and-databases/lang--en/index.htm |
PolitRisk | Role of Institutions, law enforcement and government stability. Complemented with International Country Risk | World Bank and Princeton University |
Estimations with the Inverse Hyperbolic Sine (IHS) Transformation Method
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mercosur | 0.132 (0.028) *** | 0.127 (0.031) *** | 0.122 (0.028) *** | 0.112 (0.036) *** | 0.117 (0.029) *** | 0.119 (0.027) *** | 0.121 (0.031) *** |
ALADI | 0.025 (0.011) * | 0.021 (0.009) * | 0.017 (0.008) * | 0.023 (0.012) * | 0.018 (0.008) * | 0.015 (0.007) * | 0.019 (0.012) |
BITs | 0.047 (0.015) ** | 0.045 (0.022) ** | 0.038 (0.019) ** | 0.032 (0.014) ** | 0.036 (0.018) ** | 0.035 (0.018) * | 0.039 (0.020) * |
ONE_Mercosur | −0.064 (0.020) *** | −0.061 (0.015) *** | −0.066 (0.018) *** | −0.058 (0.013) *** | −0.052 (0.023) *** | −0.054 (0.020) *** | −0.056 (0.018) *** |
ONE_ALADI | −0.012 (0.005) * | −0.014 (0.007) * | −0.016 (0.008) * | −0.015 (0.006) * | −0.011 (0.015) | −0.010 (0.015) | −0.009 (0.019) |
BIT index | 0.044 (0.020) * | 0.039 (0.019) * | 0.043 (0.021) * | ||||
BIT Index < 0.68 (less pro-investor) | 0.016 (0.022) | 0.018 (0.026) | 0.014 (0.029) | ||||
BIT Index 0.68 (pro-investor) | 0.032 (0.017) * | 0.030 (0.015) * | 0.028 (0.013) * | ||||
Mercosur * BIT Index | 0.042 (0.012) *** | 0.036 (0.009) *** | |||||
Mercosur * BIT Index 0.68 | 0.048 (0.010) *** | 0.052 (0.006) *** | |||||
Aladi*BIT Index | 0.016 (0.023) | 0.014 (0.028) | 0.011 (0.031) | ||||
ISDS concluded | −0.015 (0.048) | −0.012 (0.052) | −0.006 (0.043) | −0.009 (0.039) | |||
Mercosur_LAG5 | 0.096 (0.033) *** | 0.102 (0.038) *** | |||||
ALADI_LAG5 | 0.008 (0.003) * | 0.010 (0.005) * | |||||
BITs_LAG5 | 0.036 (0.018) ** | ||||||
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
No. Observations | 1962 | 1962 | 1962 | 1962 | 1632 | 1632 | |
Individual country−year fixed effect | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | |
Country−pair fixed effect | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
fdi stock | gdp_d | gdp_o | Distance | Adjacency | Mercosur | ONE_Mercosur | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
fdistock | 1 | ||||||
gdp_d | 0.1534 * | 1 | |||||
gdp_o | 0.1921 * | 0.0109 | 1 | ||||
distance | −0.0300 | 0.1615 * | 0.1615 * | 1 | |||
adjacency | 0.0687 * | 0.1115 * | 0.0541 * | −0.5483 * | 1 | ||
Mercosur | 0.2109 * | 0.1511 * | 0.1511 * | −0.0853 * | 0.1681 * | 1 | |
ONE_Mercosur | −0.1201 * | 0.2538 * | 0.0334 | −0.0191 | 0.1101 * | 0.4601 * | 1 |
Aladi | 0.1389 * | 0.1356 * | 0.1356 * | 0.1188 * | 0.0679 * | 0.1637 | 0.0902 |
ONE_Aladi | −0.1370 * | 0.5079 * | 0.0292 | 0.1104 * | 0.0775 * | 0.2341 | 0.357 |
l5_Mercosur | 0.2194 * | 0.1190 * | 0.1190 * | −0.2246 * | 0.2270 * | 0.3857 * | 0.2604 |
l5_Aladi | 0.1133 * | 0.1598 * | 0.1598 * | 0.0942 * | 0.0441 | 0.1682 | 0.0843 |
Mercosur_LEAD5 | 0.1743 | 0.1386 * | 0.1386 * | −0.0069 | 0.1322 * | 0.4438 | 0.3889 |
Aladi_LEAD5 | 0.1006 | 0.1261 | 0.1261 | 0.1569 | 0.069 | 0.0838 | 0.0496 |
bit_enforced | 0.0251 * | 0.2224 * | 0.2138 * | 0.0235 | 0.0481 * | 0.1113 | 0.0974 |
bit_index | 0.0151 * | 0.2066 * | 0.2061 * | 0.0527 * | 0.1042 * | 0.0244 | −0.0164 |
BIT_LAG5 | 0.0307 * | 0.2202 * | 0.2113 * | 0.0164 | 0.0165 | 0.1657 | 0.1119 |
BIT_LEAD5 | 0.0119 | 0.2506 | 0.2422 | 0.0558 | 0.0674 | 0.0211 | 0.0677 |
sum_gdp_partner | 0.2215 * | 0.0832 * | 0.0927 * | 0.1982 | 0.0408 | 0.1879 * | 0.0264 |
factendow | 0.0828 * | 0.2192 * | 0.1093 * | 0.0000 | −0.0203 | 0.0000 | 0.2208 |
laborcostdif | 0.0495 * | 0.1286 * | 0.1014 * | 0.0000 | −0.0122 | 0.0000 | −0.2745 * |
politrisk | −0.1233 * | −0.0046 * | −0.0273 | 0.0890 * | −0.1127 | 0.0451 | −0.0245 |
Aladi | ONE_Aladi | Mercosur_LAG5 | Aladi_LAG5 | Mercosur_LEAD5 | Aladi_LEAD5 | bit_enforced | |
Aladi | 1 | ||||||
ONE_Aladi | 0.2386 * | 1 | |||||
Mercosur_LAG5 | 0.0838 * | 0.1541 * | 1 | ||||
Aladi_LAG5 | 0.4325 * | 0.1784 * | 0.1251 * | 1 | |||
Mercosur_LEAD5 | 0.1706 * | 0.2052 * | 0.3531 * | 0.1647 * | 1 | ||
Aladi_LEAD5 | 0.4713 * | 0.2274 * | −0.0018 | 0.6186 * | 0.1637 * | 1 | |
bit_enforced | 0.004 | −0.0921 | 0.0211 | −0.0816 * | 0.1657 * | 0.0185 | 1 |
bit_index | 0.0265 | −0.0457 | −0.1609 * | −0.0879 * | 0.0393 | 0.0561 * | 0.4251 * |
BIT_LAG5 | 0.0185 | −0.0935 | 0.1145 * | −0.0530 * | 0.1620 * | −0.0581 | 0.4461 * |
BIT_LEAD5 | −0.0816 * | −0.1800 | 0.0242 | −0.1479 * | 0.0663 * | 0.0067 | 0.3105 * |
sum_gdp_partner | 0.1561 * | −0.0068 | 0.1460 * | 0.1762 * | 0.1507 * | 0.1419 * | −0.1323 * |
factendow | 0.000 | −0.0562 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.000 | 0.0210 |
laborcostdif | 0.000 | −0.0095 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.0000 | 0.000 | 0.0311 |
politrisk | 0.1008 * | −0.0283 | −0.0202 * | 0.0478 | −0.0204 | 0.1297 | −0.0032 |
bit_index | BIT_LAG5 | BIT_LEAD5 | sum_gdp_partner | factendow | laborcostdif | politrisk | |
bit_index | 1 | ||||||
BIT_LAG5 | 0.3493 * | 1 | |||||
BIT_LEAD5 | 0.3778 * | 0.3466 * | 1 | ||||
sum_gdp_partner | 0.2232 | 0.2205 | 0.2735 | 1 | |||
factendow | 0.0121 | 0.0193 | 0.0166 | 0.1268 * | 1 | ||
laborcostdif | −0.0116 | 0.0332 | 0.0274 | 0.1217 * | 0.2015 * | 1 | |
politrisk | −0.0612 * | −0.0302 | 0.0380 | 0.0270 | 0.2530 * | 0.1381 * | 1 |
References
- Borensztein, E.; De Gregorio, J.; Lee, J. How does FDI affect economic growth? J. Int. Econ. 1998, 45, 115–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Alvarado, R.; Iñiguez, M.; Ponce, P. FDI and economic growth in Latin America. Econ. Anal. Policy 2017, 56, 176–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yotov, Y.; Piermartini, R.; Monteiro, J.A.; Larch, M. An Advanced Guide to Trade Policy Analysis: The Structural Gravity Model; World Trade Organization: Geneva, Switzerland, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Santos-Silva, J.; Tenreyro, S. The Log of gravity. Rev. Econ. Stat. 2006, 88, 641–658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jang, Y. The Impact of bilateral FTA on bilateral FDI among developed countries. World Econ. 2011, 34, 1628–1651. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Egger, P.; Merlo, V. BITs bite: An anatomy of the impact of BITs on multinational firms. Scand. J. Econ. 2012, 114, 1240–1266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aisbett, E.; Busse, M.; Nunnenkamp, P. BITs as deterrents of host-country discretion: The impact of investor-state disputes on FDI in developing countries. Rev. World Econ. 2018, 154, 119–155. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Markusen, J.R.; Venables, A. The theory of endowment, intra-industry and multi-national trade. J. Int. Econ. 2000, 52, 209–234. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Markusen, J.R.; Maskus, K. Discriminating among alternative theories of the multinational enterprise. Rev. Int. Econ. 2002, 104, 694–707. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levy-Yeyati, E.; Stein, E.; Daude, C. Regional Integration and the Location of FDI. Working Paper 492; Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department: Washington, DC, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Ramondo, N.; Rappoport, V.; Ruhl, K. Intra-firm trade and vertical fragmentation in U.S. multinational corporations. J. Int. Econ. 2016, 98, 51–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Egger, P.; Merlo, V. The impact of BITs on FDI dynamics. World Econ. 2007, 30, 1536–1549. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baltagi, B.H.; Egger, P.; Pfaffermayr, M. Estimating Regional Trade Agreement effects on FDI in an interdependent world. J. Econom. 2008, 145, 194–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chenaf-Nicet, D.; Rougier, E. The effect of macroeconomic instability on FDI flows: A gravity estimation of the impact of regional integration in the case of Euro-Mediterranean agreements. Int. Econ. 2016, 145, 66–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Felbermayr, G.; Toubal, F. Cultural Proximity and Trade. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2010, 54, 279–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Büthe, T.; Milner, H. FDI and institutional diversity in trade agreements: Credibility, commitment and economic flows in the developing world, 1971–2007. World Politics 2014, 66, 88–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dixon, J.; Haslam, P.A. Does the quality of investment protection affect FDI flows to Developing Countries? Evidence from Latin America. World Econ. 2016, 39, 1080–1108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frenkel, M.; Walter, B. Do bilateral investment treaties attract FDI? The role of international dispute settlement provisions. World Econ. 2019, 42, 1316–1342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Markusen, J.R. Multinationals, multiplant economies and the gains from trade. J. Int. Econ. 1984, 16, 205–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Helpman, E. A simple theory of international trade with multinational corporations. J. Political Econ. 1984, 92, 451–471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Neary, J.P. FDI and the single market. Manch. Sch. 2002, 70, 291–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Castilho, M.; Zignago, S. Trade, FDI and regional integration in Mercosur. Revue Econ. 2000, 51, 761–774. [Google Scholar]
- Anderson, J.E.; Larch, M.; Yotov, Y. Trade liberalization, growth and FDI: A structural estimation framework. ETSG Work. Pap. 2017. Available online: http://www.etsg.org/ETSG2016/Papers/052.pdf (accessed on 1 November 2018).
- Blomström, M.; Kokko, A. Regional Integration and FDI; NBER Working Paper 1997; NBER: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Egger, P.; Pfaffermayr, M. FDI and European integration in the 1990s. World Econ. 2004, 27, 99–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Büge, M. Do PTA Increase Their Members’ FDI? German Development Institute Discussion Paper; DIE-GDI: Bonn, Germany, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Carr, D.L.; Markusen, J.R.; Maskus, K.E. Estimating the knowledge-capital model of the multinational enterprise. Am. Econ. Rev. 2001, 91, 693–708. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cherif, M.; Dreger, C. Institutional determinants of financial development in MENA countries. Rev. Dev. Econ. 2016, 20, 670–680. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kerner, A. Why should I believe you? Costs and consequences of BITs. Int. Stud. Q. 2009, 53, 73–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Busse, M.; Königer, J.; Nunnenkamp, P. FDI promotion through bilateral investment treaties: More than a bit? Rev. World Econ. 2010, 146, 147–177. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Neumayer, E.; Spess, L. Do BITs increase FDI to developing countries? World Dev. 2005, 33, 1567–1585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Salacuse, J.W.; Sullivan, N. Do BITs really work? An evaluation of BITs and their grand bargain. Harv. Int. Law J. 2005, 46, 67–130. [Google Scholar]
- Sirr, G.; Garvey, J.; Gallagher, L. BITs and FDI: Evidence of asymmetric effects on vertical and horizontal investments. Dev. Policy Rev. 2017, 35, 93–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hallward-Driemeier, M. Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Attract FDI? Only a Bit… and They Could Bite; Policy Research Working Paper WPS3121 2003; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Rose-Ackerman, S.; Tobin, J. FDI and the business environment in developing countries: The impact of BITs. Yale Law Econ. Res. Paper 2005, 293. Available online: http://ssrn.com/abstract=557121 (accessed on 1 November 2018).
- Gallagher, K.P.; Birch, M.B. Do investment agreements attract investment? Evidence from Latin America. J. World Investig. Trade 2006, 7, 961–974. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yackee, J.W. BITs, credible commitment, and the rule of (International) Law: Do BITs promote foreign direct investment? Law Soc. Rev. 2008, 42, 805–832. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tobin, J.L.; Rose-Ackerman, S. When BITs have some bite: The political-economic environment for bilateral investment treaties. Rev. Int. Organ. 2011, 6, 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Blonigen, B.A.; Piger, J. Determinants of FDI. Can. J. Econ. 2014, 47, 775–812. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Egger, P.; Pfaffermayr, M. The proper panel econometric specification of the gravity equation: A three-way model with bilateral interaction effects. Empir. Econ. 2003, 28, 571–580. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Head, K.; Ries, J. FDI as an outcome of the market for corporate control: Theory and evidence. J. Int. Econ. 2008, 74, 2–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Anderson, J.E.; Yotov, Y. Terms of trade and global efficiency effects of free trade agreements, 1990–2002. J. Int. Econ. 2016, 99, 279–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Anderson, J.E.; van Wincoop, E. Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. Am. Econ. Review 2003, 93, 170–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Head, K.; Mayer, T. Gravity equations: Workhorse, toolkit, and cookbook. In Handbook of International Economics; Gopinath, G., Helpman, E., Rogoff, K., Eds.; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2014; Volume 4, pp. 131–195. [Google Scholar]
- Mátyás, L. Proper econometric specification of the gravity model. World Econ. 1997, 20, 363–368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Egger, P. A note on the proper econometric specification of the gravity equation. Econ. Lett. 2000, 66, 25–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Baier, S.L.; Bergstrand, J.H. Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? J. Int. Econ. 2007, 71, 72–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Olivero, M.P.; Yotov, Y. Dynamic gravity: Endogenous country size and asset accumulation. Can. J. Econ. 2012, 45, 64–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feenstra, R. Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Egger, P.; Pfaffermayr, M. Distance, trade and FDI: A Hausman–Taylor SUR approach. J. Appl. Econom. 2004, 19, 227–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Babetskaia-Kukharchuk, O.; Maurel, M. Russia’s accession on to the WTO: The potential for trade increase. J. Comp. Econ. 2004, 32, 680–699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McPherson, M.; Trumbull, W. Rescuing observed fixed effects: Using the Hausman-Taylor method for out-of-sample trade projections. Int. Trade J. 2008, 22, 315–340. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frankel, M.; Funke, K.; Stadtmann, G. A panel Analysis of bilateral FDI flows to emerging economies. Econ. Syst. 2004, 28, 281–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, S.; Martinez-Zarzoso, I. A panel data analysis of trade creation and trade diversion effects: The case of ASEAN-China Free Trade Area. China Econ. Rev. 2014, 29, 138–151. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Berger, A.; Busse, M.; Nunnenkamp, P.; Roy, M. Do trade and investment agreements lead to more FDI? Accounting for key provisions inside the black box. Int. Econ. Econ. Policy 2013, 10, 247–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kohl, T.; Brakman, S.; Garretsen, H. Do trade agreements stimulate international trade differently? Evidence from 296 trade agreements. World Econ. 2016, 39, 97–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Janicki, H.P.; Warin, T.; Wunnava, P. Endogenous OCA theory: Using the gravity model to test Mundell’s intuition. CES Work. Pap. 2005, 125. [Google Scholar]
- Eicher, T.S.; Papageorgiou, C.; Raftery, A.E. Default priors and predictive performance in Bayesian model averaging, with application to growth determinants. J. Appl. Econom. 2011, 26, 30–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bergstrand, J.; Egger, P. A knowledge-and-physical-capital model of international trade flows, FDI and multinational enterprises. J. Int. Econ. 2007, 73, 278–308. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Borchert, I.; Larch, M.; Shikher, S.; Yotov, Y. Disaggregated Gravity: Benchmark Estimates and Stylized Facts from a New Database; School of Economics Working Paper Series 2020-8; LeBow College of Business, Drexel University: Philadelphia, PA, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Egger, P.; Nigai, S. Structural gravity with dummies only: Constrained ANOVA-type estimation of gravity models. J. Int. Econ. 2015, 97, 86–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hausman, J.A.; Taylor, W.E. Panel data and unobservable individual effects. Econometrica 1981, 49, 1377–1398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Yi,t (log) | 0.726 (0.000) *** | 0.764 (0.003) *** | 0.701 (0.006) *** | 0.693 (0.007) *** | 0.752 (0.003) *** | 0.628 (0.005) *** | |||
Yj,t (log) | 0.815 (0.002) *** | 0.804 (0.003) *** | 0.831 (0.003) *** | 0.809 (0.004) *** | 0.802 (0.002) *** | 0.813 (0.003) *** | |||
0.935 (0.490) ** | 0.947 (0.486) ** | 0.895 (0.488) ** | 0.906 (0.475) ** | 0.926 (0.468) ** | 0.985 (0.506) ** | ||||
Distanceij (log) | −0.702 (0.104) *** | −0.713 (0.096) *** | −0.724 (0.109) *** | −0.743 (0.113) *** | −0.782 (0.095) *** | −0.736 (0.079) ** | −0.801 (0.108) *** | −0.751 (0.123) *** | −0.762 (0.114) *** |
Adjacencyij | 0.216 (0.065) *** | 0.261 (0.053) *** | 0.272 (0.048) *** | 0.260 (0.047) *** | 0.206 (0.052) *** | 0.214 (0.050) *** | 0.236 (0.044) *** | 0.221 (0.039) *** | 0.274 (0.049) *** |
Mercosurij,t | 0.143 (0.033 *** | 0.146 (0.031) *** | 0.138 (0.029) *** | 0.147 (0.026) *** | 0.136 (0.027) *** | 0.142 (0.022) *** | 0.136 (0.019) *** | 0.138 (0.017) *** | 0.140 (0.021) *** |
ALADIij,t | 0.061 (0.024) ** | 0.049 (0.026) * | 0.055 (0.029) * | 0.062 (0.030) * | 0.056 (0.031) * | 0.053 (0.026) ** | 0.054 (0.024) ** | 0.060 (0.026) ** | 0.049 (0.027) ** |
BITsij,t | 0.086 (0.046) * | 0.082 (0.044) * | 0.074 (0.039) ** | 0.069 (0.036) * | 0.065 (0.035) * | 0.063 (0.033) * | 0.052 (0.028) * | ||
BIT indexij,t | 0.045 (0.024) * | 0.043 (0.023) * | 0.042 (0.022) * | 0.039 (0.021) * | |||||
ONE_Mercosurij,t | −0.081 (0.022) *** | −0.076 (0.032) *** | −0.074 (0.026) *** | −0.070 (0.024) *** | −0.065 (0.028) *** | −0.064 (0.031) *** | |||
ONE_ALADIij,t | −0.026 (0.025) | −0.023 (0.023) | −0.028 (0.032) | −0.025 (0.037) | −0.018 (0.042) | −0.021 (0.041) | |||
Factor Endowij,t | 0.104 (0.031) *** | 0.113 (0.039) *** | 0.107 (0.042) *** | ||||||
Political Riskj,t | −0.043 (0.010) *** | −0.052 (0.009) *** | −0.053 (0.014) *** | ||||||
Labor Cost difij,t | 0.037 (0.020) * | 0.042 (0.0321) * | 0.045 (0.022) * | ||||||
No. Observations | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 |
Adj. R2 | 0.537 | 0.521 | 0.546 | 0.557 | 0.560 | 0.529 | 0.587 | 0.579 | 0.601 |
Individual Country Fixed Effect | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Time Fixed effect | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Stock FDIij,t | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
Mercosur | 0.129 (0.018) *** | 0.122 (0.023) *** | 0.115 (0.019) *** | 0.103 (0.013) *** | 0.096 (0.010) *** |
ALADI | 0.030 (0.016) * | 0.032 (0.017) * | 0.027 (0.016) * | 0.025 (0.014) * | 0.031 (0.013) * |
BITs | 0.042 (0.021) ** | 0.039 (0.019) ** | 0.034 (0.019) ** | ||
BIT index | 0.034 (0.018) * | 0.039 (0.019) * | |||
BIT Index < 0.68 (less pro−investor) | 0.026 (0.029) | 0.018 (0.036) | |||
BIT Index 0.68 (pro−investor) | 0.037 (0.020) * | 0.042 (0.019) * | |||
Mercosur * BIT Index | 0.062 (0.013) *** | ||||
Mercosur * BIT Index 0.68 | 0.068 (0.020) *** | ||||
Aladi*BIT Index | 0.023 (0.017) | ||||
ISDS concluded | −0.008 (0.023) | −0.007 (0.029) | |||
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
No. Observations | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 | 2230 |
Individual country−year fixed effect | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Country−pair fixed effect | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Panel A: PPML | Panel B: Hausman−Taylor | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (1) | (2) | (3) | |
Yi,t (log) | 0.564 (0.062) *** | 0.537 (0.071 *** | |||
Yj,t (log) | 0.792 (0.069) *** | 0.805 (0.042 *** | |||
0.901 (0.489) ** | 0.875 (0.425) ** | ||||
Distance (log) | −0.503 (0.257) ** | −0.498 (0.250) ** | −0.485 (0.248) ** | ||
Adjacency | 0.273 (0.081) *** | 0.253 (0.073) *** | 0.261 (0.062) *** | ||
Mercosur | 0.123 (0.032) *** | 0.118 (0.026) *** | 0.153 (0.070) *** | 0.145 (0.062) *** | 0.169 (0.073) *** |
ALADI | 0.031 (0.016) * | 0.026 (0.014) * | 0.056 (0.028) * | 0.048 (0.025) ** | 0.052 (0.026) ** |
BITs | 0.047 (0.024) ** | 0.039 (0.020) ** | 0.063 (0.032) ** | 0.072 (0.035) ** | |
BIT index | 0.041 (0.022) * | 0.046 (0.021) * | |||
Mercosur_LEAD5 | 0.072 (0.048) | ||||
ALADI_ LEAD5 | 0.015 (0.032) | ||||
BITs_ LEAD5 | 0.029 (0.054) | ||||
Mercosur_LAG5 | 0.126 (0.011) *** | ||||
ALADI_ LAG5 | 0.038 (0.020) * | ||||
BITs_ LAG5 | 0.046 (0.021) ** | ||||
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
No. Observations | 1896 | 1896 | 1670 | 1670 | 1670 |
Adj. R2 | 0.426 | 0.443 | 0.521 | ||
Sigma_u | 0.729 | 0.931 | 0.834 | ||
Sigma_e | 1.317 | 1.320 | 1.320 | ||
Rho (fraction of variance due to u_i) | 0.234 | 0.332 | 0.285 | ||
F−stat overidentification restriction | 1.345 (0.426) | 1.421 (0.432) | 1.415 (0.447) |
Middle Income Countries | Middle-Low Income Countries | |||||||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |||||||||
Mercosur | 0.106 | 0.097 | 0.115 | 0.119 | 0.092 | 0.101 | 0.095 | 0.087 | ||||||||
(0.016) | *** | (0.023) | *** | (0.020) | *** | (0.016) | *** | (0.024) | *** | (0.013) | *** | (0.021) | *** | (0.025) | *** | |
Aladi | 0.036 | 0.042 | 0.031 | 0.028 | 0.030 | 0.019 | 0.022 | 0.015 | ||||||||
(0.020) | * | (0.021) | * | (0.025) | (0.015) | * | (0.016) | * | (0.011) | * | (0.012) | * | (0.018) | |||
BITs | 0.039 | 0.036 | 0.041 | 0.032 | 0.027 | 0.037 | ||||||||||
(0.022) | * | (0.020) | * | (0.022) | * | (0.045) | (0.038) | (0.042) | ||||||||
BIT Index | 0.043 | 0.029 | ||||||||||||||
(0.020) | ** | (0.015) | * | |||||||||||||
BIT Index < 0.68 | 0.023 | 0.028 | 0.019 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 0.018 | ||||||||||
(0.011) | * | (0.012) | * | (0.011) | * | (0.018) | (0.029) | (0.027) | ||||||||
BIT Index 0.68 | 0.042 | 0.045 | 0.047 | 0.036 | 0.039 | 0.042 | ||||||||||
(0.021) | ** | (0.020) | ** | (0.021) | ** | (0.019) | * | (0.021) | * | (0.019) | ** | |||||
Mercosur * BIT Index | 0.055 | 0.057 | ||||||||||||||
(0.027) | ** | (0.025) | ** | |||||||||||||
Mercosur * BIT Index 0.68 | 0.057 | 0.059 | 0.055 | 0.042 | 0.040 | 0.036 | ||||||||||
(0.019) | *** | (0.012) | *** | (0.010) | *** | (0.011) | *** | (0.013) | *** | (0.015) | *** | |||||
Aladi*BIT Index | 0.017 | 0.018 | 0.014 | 0.021 | 0.019 | 0.023 | ||||||||||
(0.030) | (0.037) | (0.026) | (0.010) | * | (0.009) | * | (0.011) | * | ||||||||
ISDS concluded | −0.018 | −0.012 | -0.015 | −0.006 | −0.009 | −0.011 | ||||||||||
(0.047) | (0.052) | (0.061) | (0.039) | (0.042) | (0.058) | |||||||||||
Mercosur_LAG5 | 0.084 | 0.093 | 0.090 | 0.092 | ||||||||||||
(0.012) | *** | (0.024) | *** | (0.022) | *** | (0.031) | *** | |||||||||
Aladi_LAG5 | 0.023 | 0.016 | 0.014 | 0.012 | ||||||||||||
(0.008) | * | (0.009) | * | (0.007) | * | (0.006) | * | |||||||||
BITs_LAG5 | 0.039 | 0.030 | ||||||||||||||
(0.020) | ** | (0.014) | ** | |||||||||||||
Controls | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | ||||||||
Adj-R2 | 0.439 | 0.520 | 0.561 | 0.536 | 0.410 | 0.421 | 0.438 | 0.446 | ||||||||
Wald Test | 32.15 | 31.29 | 31.42 | 27.31 | 28.22 | 31..05 | 27.31 | 32.91 | ||||||||
Observations | 1160 | 1160 | 1042 | 1042 | 960 | 960 | 852 | 852 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Bengoa, M.; Sanchez-Robles, B.; Shachmurove, Y. Do Trade and Investment Agreements Promote Foreign Direct Investment within Latin America? Evidence from a Structural Gravity Model. Mathematics 2020, 8, 1882. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8111882
Bengoa M, Sanchez-Robles B, Shachmurove Y. Do Trade and Investment Agreements Promote Foreign Direct Investment within Latin America? Evidence from a Structural Gravity Model. Mathematics. 2020; 8(11):1882. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8111882
Chicago/Turabian StyleBengoa, Marta, Blanca Sanchez-Robles, and Yochanan Shachmurove. 2020. "Do Trade and Investment Agreements Promote Foreign Direct Investment within Latin America? Evidence from a Structural Gravity Model" Mathematics 8, no. 11: 1882. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8111882
APA StyleBengoa, M., Sanchez-Robles, B., & Shachmurove, Y. (2020). Do Trade and Investment Agreements Promote Foreign Direct Investment within Latin America? Evidence from a Structural Gravity Model. Mathematics, 8(11), 1882. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8111882