Delay Effect and Subadditivity. Proposal of a New Discount Function: The Asymmetric Exponential Discounting
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Subadditivity
- (i)
- is subadditive.
- (ii)
- For every t, and a and b greater than zero, if ~ and ~ then .
- (iii)
- For every t, a, and b greater than zero, there exists x, y, and z such that , but .
3. Delay Effect
3.1. Stationary Case
- is subadditive of the second order.
- is convex.
- The instantaneous discount rate, , is strictly decreasing.
3.2. Dynamic Case
4. Proposal of a New Discounting Function: The Asymmetric Exponential Discounting
- Superadditivity of the second order:.
- Subadditivity of the second order: .
5. Conclusions
- By comparing the discount ratios corresponding to two delayed intervals of the same length. This case gives rise to the concept of the subadditivity of the second order.
- By comparing the value of the discount function with the discount ratio corresponding to a delayed interval with the same amplitude. This is a condition weaker than the former one and gives rise to the concept of subadditivity.
- By comparing the values of the discount function in two intervals with the same amplitude. This situation gives rise to a contractive discount function.
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Samuelson, P.A. A note on measurement of utility. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1937, 4, 155–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thaler, R. Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Econ. Lett. 1981, 8, 201–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cruz Rambaud, S.; Muñoz Torrecillas, M.J. An analysis of the anomalies in traditional discounting models. Int. J. Psychol. Psychol. Ther. 2004, 4, 105–128. [Google Scholar]
- Ainslie, G. Specious reward: A behavioral theory of impulsiveness and impulse control. Psychol. Bull. 1975, 82, 463–496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Loewenstein, G.; Prelec, D. Anomalies in intertemporal choice: Evidence and an interpretation. Q. J. Econ. 1992, 107, 573–597. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Benzion, U.; Rapoport, A.; Yagil, J. Discount rates inferred from decisions: An experimental study. Manag. Sci. 1989, 35, 270–284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Christensen-Szalanski, J.J. Discount functions and the measurement of patients’ values: Women’s decisions during childbirth. Med. Decis. Mak. 1984, 4, 47–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scholten, M.; Read, D. Interval effects: Superadditivity and subadditivity in intertemporal choice. Work. Pap. Lond. Sch. Econ. Political Sci. 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Scholten, M.; Read, D. Discounting by intervals: A generalized model of intertemporal choice. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 1424–1436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scholten, M.; Read, D. The psychology of intertemporal tradeoffs. Psychol. Rev. 2010, 117, 925. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cruz Rambaud, S.; Muñoz Torrecillas, M.J. Delay and interval effects with subadditive discounting functions. In Preferences and Decisions: Models and Applications; Greco, S., Marques Pereira, R.A., Squillante, M., Yager, R.R., Eds.; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2010; pp. 85–110. [Google Scholar]
- Cruz Rambaud, S.; Muñoz Torrecillas, M.J. Some characterizations of (strongly) subadditive discounting functions. Appl. Math. Comput. 2014, 243, 368–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chapman, G.B. Temporal discounting and utility for health and money. J. Exp. Psychol. Learn. Mem. Cogn. 1996, 22, 771–791. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Lazaro, A.; Barberan, R.; Rubio, E. Private and social time preferences for health and money: An empirical estimation. Health Econ. 2001, 10, 351–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Van der Pol, M.; Cairns, J. Valuing future private and social benefits: The discounted utility model versus hyperbolic discounting models. J. Econ. Psychol. 2000, 21, 191–205. [Google Scholar]
- Kirby, K.N.; Maraković, N.N. Modeling myopic decisions: Evidence for hyperbolic delay-discounting within subjects and amounts. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 1995, 64, 22–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Reynolds, B. Do high rates of cigarette consumption increase delay discounting? A cross-sectional comparison of adolescent smokers and young-adult smokers and nonsmokers. Behav. Process. 2004, 67, 545–549. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Harrison, G.W.; Lau, M.I.; Rutström, E.E. Individual discount rates and smoking: Evidence from a field experiment in Denmark. J. Health Econ. 2010, 29, 708–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Stea, J.N.; Hodgins, D.C.; Lambert, M.J. Relations between delay discounting and low to moderate gambling, cannabis, and alcohol problems among university students. Behav. Process. 2011, 88, 202–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scharff, R.L. Obesity and hyperbolic discounting: Evidence and implications. J. Consum. Policy 2009, 32, 3–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ikeda, S.; Kang, M.I.; Ohtake, F. Hyperbolic discounting, the sign effect, and the body mass index. J. Health Econ. 2010, 29, 268–284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Prelec, D. Decreasing impatience: A criterion for non-stationary time preference and “hyperbolic” discounting. Scand. J. Econ. 2004, 106, 511–532. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Takahashi, T.; Oono, H.; Radford, M.H. Empirical estimation of consistency parameter in intertemporal choice based on Tsallis’ statistics. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Its Appl. 2007, 381, 338–342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cruz Rambaud, S.; Muñoz Torrecillas, M.J. Measuring impatience in intertemporal choice. PLoS ONE 2016, 11, e0149256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Bickel, W.K.; Jarmolowicz, D.P.; Mueller, E.T.; Koffarnus, M.N.; Gatchalian, K.M. Excessive discounting of delayed reinforcers as a trans-disease process contributing to addiction and other disease-related vulnerabilities: Emerging evidence. Pharmacol. Ther. 2012, 134, 287–297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Takahashi, T. Time-estimation error following Weber–Fechner law may explain subadditive time-discounting. Med. Hypotheses 2006, 67, 1372–1374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Mazur, J.E. An adjusting procedure for studying delayed reinforcement. In Quantitative Analyses of Behavior; Commons, M.L., Mazur, J.E., Nevin, J.A., Rachlin, H., Eds.; The effect of delay and of intervening events on reinforcement value; Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc.: Mahwah, NJ, USA, 1987; Volume 5, pp. 55–73. [Google Scholar]
- Cruz Rambaud, S.; Muñoz Torrecillas, M.J.; Takahashi, T. Observed and normative discount functions in addiction and other diseases. Front. Pharmacol. 2017, 8, 416. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Read, D. Is time-discounting hyperbolic or subadditive? J. Risk Uncertain. 2001, 23, 5–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baron, J. Can we use human judgments to determine the discount rate? Risk Anal. 2000, 20, 861–868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Pender, J.L. Discount rates and credit markets: Theory and evidence from rural India. J. Dev. Econ. 1996, 50, 257–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Read, D.; Roelofsma, P.H. Subadditive versus hyperbolic discounting: A comparison of choice and matching. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 2003, 91, 140–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Prelec, D.; Loewenstein, G. Decision making over time and under uncertainty: A common approach. Manag. Sci. 1991, 37, 770–786. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barlow, R.E.; Proschan, F. Mathematical Theory of Reliability; SIAM: Philadelphia, PA, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
- Aven, T.; Jensen, U. Stochastic Models in Reliability; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Cruz Rambaud, S. A new argument in favor of hyperbolic discounting in very long term project appraisal. Int. J. Theor. Appl. Financ. 2014, 17, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Values of β | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Values of α | SUB2 | Generalized exponential discounting | ? | |
SUB2 | Exponential discounting | RSUB2 | ||
? | Generalized exponential discounting | RSUB2 |
α | 0.5 | 1 | 2 | 0.5 | 1 | 2 |
β | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 2 | 2 | 2 |
Result | −0.004 | −0.006 | ? | ? | 0.400 | 6.400 |
SUB2 | SUB2 | ? | ? | RSUB2 | RSUB2 |
α | 0.5 | 1 | 2 | 0.5 | 1 | 2 |
β | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 2 | 2 | 2 |
Result | ∞ | - | 0 | ∞ | - | 0 |
SUB | - | SUB | SUB | - | SUB |
α | 0.5 | 1 | 2 | 0.5 | 1 | 2 | 2 |
β | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 2 | 2 | 2 | 1 |
Result | −0.008 | −0.010 | −0.015 | 0.283 | 0.400 | 0.800 | 0 |
EXP | EXP | EXP | CONTR | CONTR | CONTR | - |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Cruz Rambaud, S.; Ortiz Fernández, P. Delay Effect and Subadditivity. Proposal of a New Discount Function: The Asymmetric Exponential Discounting. Mathematics 2020, 8, 367. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8030367
Cruz Rambaud S, Ortiz Fernández P. Delay Effect and Subadditivity. Proposal of a New Discount Function: The Asymmetric Exponential Discounting. Mathematics. 2020; 8(3):367. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8030367
Chicago/Turabian StyleCruz Rambaud, Salvador, and Piedad Ortiz Fernández. 2020. "Delay Effect and Subadditivity. Proposal of a New Discount Function: The Asymmetric Exponential Discounting" Mathematics 8, no. 3: 367. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8030367
APA StyleCruz Rambaud, S., & Ortiz Fernández, P. (2020). Delay Effect and Subadditivity. Proposal of a New Discount Function: The Asymmetric Exponential Discounting. Mathematics, 8(3), 367. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8030367