1. Introduction
Reinsurance can be seen as a risk transfer that may help to reduce the risk exposure of the insurer and, hence, to stabilize the business. More precisely, the insurer transfers some part of risk to a reinsurance company at the expense of paying the corresponding reinsurance premium, which reduces the potential risk. Thanks to this tool, catastrophic risk, such as climate risks, initially hardly insurable, may become insurable by transferring risks (see, e.g.,
Charpentier 2008). Naturally, the reinsurance premiums increase as the risk transferred to a reinsurer increases. In this context, how to deal with the trade-off between the risk retained and the premium paid to the reinsurer becomes a major issue for an insurer.
The study of the optimal reinsurance problems can be traced back to the seminal papers of
Borch (
1960) and
Arrow (
1963). Calculating the reinsurance premium by using the expected value principle,
Borch (
1960) showed that the stop-loss reinsurance is optimal when the objective is to minimize the variance of the insurer’s retained loss. Choosing the same premium principle as
Borch (
1960),
Arrow (
1963) considered the optimal reinsurance problem by maximizing expected utility of the terminal wealth of a risk-averse insurer. The results also showed that the stop-loss reinsurance is optimal.
Kaluszka (
2001) extended Borch’s result by applying the mean-variance premium principle. Arrow’s result has been considered under other premium principles, see
Young (
1999) and
Kaluszka (
2005). For different purposes, the optimal reinsurance problem has been studied under more intricate optimization criteria and/or more general premium principles, see
Albrecher et al. (
2017) for a survey, and some examples. When the reinsurance premium is calculated according to the maximal possible claims principle,
Kaluszka and Okolewski (
2008) showed that the limited stop-loss and the truncated stop-loss are the optimal reinsurance contracts by maximizing the expected utility.
Guerra and Centeno (
2010) considered the optimal forms of reinsurance when the insurer seeks to maximize the adjustment coefficient of the retained risk. Using the maximization of the expected utility of terminal wealth,
Zhang and Siu (
2012) and
Liang and Bayraktar (
2014) studied the optimal reinsurance and investment strategies with different market assumptions.
In the fields of finance and insurance, Value-at-Risk (
) and Tail-Value-at-Risk (
) are the most popular risk measures due to their merits and good properties. For this reason, many optimal reinsurance problems under the
and/or the
have been studied in the literature. For instance, under the expected value premium principle,
Cai and Tan (
2007) provided the optimal retention of a stop-loss reinsurance by minimizing the
and the
of the insurer’s total risk exposure.
Cai et al. (
2008) derived the optimal reinsurance within a class of increasing convex loss functions.
Cheung (
2010) extended the
-minimization reinsurance model in
Cai et al. (
2008) by considering Wang’s premium principle.
Lu et al. (
2016) considered the optimal reinsurance problem under the optimality criteria of
and
risk measures when constraints for the reinsurer’s risk exposure are presented. Further extensions of the optimal reinsurance problems can be found in
Balbás et al. (
2009),
Tan et al. (
2011), and
Chi and Tan (
2011,
2013).
Let
X denote the amount of loss initially assumed by an insurer in a given time period. Usually,
X is assumed to be a non-negative random variable defined on the probability space
with continuous distribution function
. We further assume that
is strictly increasing on
but with a possible jump at 0 with
.
and
are used to denote the survival function and the density function of
X, respectively. Given a confidence level
, the
and the
of the risk
X are defined as
and
respectively. For a continuous loss distribution, there are many alternative names of
, such as Expected Shortfall (
), Conditional Tail Expectation (
), Average
(
), and Conditional
(
). We refer to
Acerbi and Tasche (
2002) and
Rockafellar and Uryasev (
2013) for the relationships between the various notions. It is well known that
is simple and easier to interpret, but it is, in general, not subadditive and, hence, not coherent in the sense of
Artzner et al. (
1999). Another major drawback of
is that it only takes into account the probability of a big loss, not the size of the loss, i.e., it completely ignores the tail loss beyond the reference
. As a result, the same
s may occur when dealing with different extreme losses, and moreover,
may underestimate the losses in practice, especially when heavy-tailed losses are incorrectly modeled with light-tailed distributions, such as the normal distribution. By comparison with
,
defines a more conservative risk measure that is always subadditive. Since it is interpreted as the arithmetic average of
over all levels
, capital reserves based on
are always larger than those based on
. Further discussions about the comparative advantages of
and
, we refer to
Embrechts and Hofert (
2014),
McNeil et al. (
2015), and references therein.
As a generalization of
, the spectral risk measure has received attention in recent years. In fact, the spectral risk measure is a weighted average of
with the weight function depending on the user’s risk-aversion, so that it could help us to link the risk measure to the user’s attitude towards risk ((
Acerbi 2002) and
Dowd et al. (
2008)). Another interesting generalization of
is the Lambda Value-at-Risk, which considers the dependence between the level
and the amount of the loss (see, e.g.,
Frittelli et al. 2014;
Bellini and Peri 2022). Recall that, in the risk-management community, there is an ongoing debate on the advantages and disadvantages of
and
. However, there is no evidence for global advantage of one risk measure against the other, and the size of capital reserves may be significantly different depending on which risk measure is used. To provide a risk assessment between that offered by
and
, and capture more information about various attitudes towards risk, in this paper, we extend
and
to a more general family of risk measures, denoted by
, which is a linear combination of
and
. Obviously,
includes
and
as special cases and allows us to consider
and
simultaneously.
As shown in the literature, once the optimization criteria and the premium principle are determined, the optimal reinsurance problem becomes a purely mathematical problem, which makes the analysis easier. The expected value principle is one of the most popular premium principles both due to its transparency and simplicity (see, e.g.,
Albrecher et al. 2017), so that we assume that the reinsurance premium is calculated by this premium principle in this paper. To determine the amount of risk retained (or the premium paid to the reinsurer), the insurer has to make a choice among all feasible reinsurance treaties, and a reasonable criterion for the insurer is naturally to choose the reinsurance form which makes its total risk to be as small as possible. To this end, we revisit the optimal reinsurance problem by using the new risk measure
to quantify the total risk exposure of the insurer.
Recently, attention has been paid to controlling reinsurer’s risk since the insurer may be under a heavy financial burden with no limit on coverage. Throughout the paper, we will consider two types of constraints proposed by
Cummins and Mahul (
2004) and
Zhou et al. (
2010). The first type due to
Cummins and Mahul (
2004) has the ceded losses constrained to be less than the upper limit. The second type is that the reinsurer’s loss after the payments is limited to be less than a certain predetermined level. As mentioned above, the motivation behind these two classes of upper limits on coverage arises from providing the insurer with limited liability with respect to the indemnity schedule. Instead of constraining the risk of the reinsurer,
Boonen et al. (
2016) established lower and upper bounds of the reinsurance premium which ensure the benefits of reinsurance to both insurers and reinsurers. More recently, their work has been generalized by
Boonen et al. (
2021) to the case where an insurer could use more than one reinsurer to reinsure its risk, i.e., the case where there is competition among multiple reinsurers. With similar constraints,
Balbás et al. (
2022) showed that the optimal reinsurance problem may be very complex if the expected profits of both insurers and reinsurers are required to be non-decreasing when the reinsurance contract is signed. Here, we focus on the two types of constraints discussed in
Cummins and Mahul (
2004) and
Zhou et al. (
2010).
Many researchers have discussed the existence of optimal reinsurance contracts. However, closed-form expressions of the optimal risk transferred to the reinsurer and the resulting total risk of the insurer have not been provided. Furthermore, the study of the optimal reinsurance problems under the
and the
is generally discussed separately, which ignores the situation where one may consider both
and
simultaneously. Thus, inspired by
Lu et al. (
2016), we derive the optimal transferred risk in closed-form, but the most important distinction is that we seek to deal with the optimal reinsurance problem under the
, while
Lu et al. (
2016) considered this problem under the
and the
separately. To sum up, the main contributions of the present paper are as follows. First, we introduce a new family of risk measures
to capture more information about various attitudes towards risk and to enable us to consider
and
simultaneously. Second, by minimizing
of the insurer’s total risk and using the expected value principle, we identify optimal reinsurance contracts when the reinsurer’s risk exposure is constrained. It appears that the two-layer reinsurance is always an optimal reinsurance policy which shows the stability of optimality results when switching from
and
to
. Moreover, we show that the solutions of optimal reinsurance model in
Lu et al. (
2016) can be unified and generalized by using the
. In addition, the optimal quantity of ceded losses depends on the confidence level
, the weight coefficient
, the safety loading
, the tolerance level
L (or
K), as well as the relations between them. For the insurer, our results provide explicit expressions of the optimal reinsurance contract which may help to foster the intuition and comprehension of the consequences of setting up a reinsurance contract.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In
Section 2, we give some preliminaries, define a new family of risk measures, and describe the setup of the proposed reinsurance models.
Section 3 states the main results and is structured as follows.
Section 3.1 studies the optimal reinsurance problem under the new risk measures optimality criterion by considering the first type of constraint.
Section 3.2 studies the same problem in
Section 3.1 with the second type of constraint.
Section 4 illustrates the results in
Section 3 by numerical examples and also compares them with the results in
Lu et al. (
2016).
Section 5 concludes our study. All proofs are given in the
Appendix A.
5. Conclusions
It is well known that
and
are the most popular risk measures and both of them have been widely used in the literature (see, e.g.,
Cai and Tan 2007;
Cai et al. 2008;
Lu et al. 2016). However, these two risk measures were generally considered separately. By noticing that
and the size of capital reserves may be significantly different based on
and
, we have proposed a new family of risk measures named
which is a linear combination of
and
. This new risk measure considers
and
simultaneously and helps us to obtain a risk assessment by
. A major issue in a reinsurance contract is to guarantee a balance between the ceded risk and the contract premium. From the perspective of the insurer, the problem is how to choose a ceded loss function such that the total losses are as small as possible (or the total benefits are as large as possible). To this end, we have revisited the optimal reinsurance problem by minimizing the
of the total risk of the insurer when the reinsurer’s risk exposure has an upper limit.
In this paper, the optimal reinsurance problem has been studied between one insurer and one reinsurer. However, as introduced by
Boonen et al. (
2021), the setting with one insurer and multiple reinsurers may be more realistic in practice. This inspires our future work to consider the case with multiple reinsurers.
The most important results are presented in Theorems 1 and 2, which provide the solutions of our optimal reinsurance model. It is shown that the two-layer reinsurance is always the optimal reinsurance strategy under two types of constraints. Furthermore, we have found that the minimums of of an insurer’s total risks are larger than those of and smaller than those of . The same holds for deductibles. In numerical illustrations, we have noted significant differences in the size of capital reserves depending on adopted weight coefficients, and moreover, higher capital reserves are obtained for larger weight coefficients.
By introducing the weighted coefficient , the new risk measure may help financial institutions, such as insurance companies, to quantify risk based on different situations since the weight coefficient reflects the user’s attitude towards risk. More precisely, the larger means the higher sensitivity to the severity of losses exceeding . Most importantly, if a insurer intends to transfer some part of risk to one reinsurance, our work may provide a way to determine the size of the transferred risk.