Next Article in Journal
Special Issue “Actuarial Mathematics and Risk Management”
Previous Article in Journal
Financial Inclusion and Sustainable Growth in North African Firms: A Dynamic-Panel-Threshold Approach
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Is Additional CEO Remuneration a Performance Driver? DAX CEOs Evidence

1
CARME—Centre of Applied Research in Management and Economics, School of Management and Technology, Polytechnic of Leiria, 2411-901 Leiria, Portugal
2
School of Management and Technology, Polytechnic of Leiria, 2411-901 Leiria, Portugal
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Risks 2023, 11(7), 133; https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11070133
Submission received: 24 May 2023 / Revised: 13 July 2023 / Accepted: 14 July 2023 / Published: 17 July 2023

Abstract

:
This study aims to understand the impact of the additional remuneration of the Chief Executive Officer (CEO) over the mean remuneration of the board of directors on firms’ financial performance. The objective is to understand if the highest compensation of the CEO is a firm performance driver. In addition to the impact of total remuneration, the different remuneration components were split and analyzed. An unbalanced panel data of listed companies in DAX–Germany over the period from 2006 until 2019 is analyzed. Using dynamic methodology to estimate the models, the results show that higher additional remuneration positively explains higher firm performance measured using both accounting and market measures. The impact is also evident when additional remuneration components are analyzed. These results support the tournament theory, since when CEOs feel rewarded, they are more efficient in increasing the firm’s performance. Moreover, the firms’ financial characteristics, as well as macroeconomic factors, are also relevant to explaining its performance.

1. Introduction

CEOs are responsible for the firm’s operation and performance. To attract, retain, and motivate the CEO of the quality required to improve the firm’s performance, his/her remuneration should be enough (Zheng 2020). When they are successful in achieving the set targets, they are rewarded in different ways, for instance through bonus payments (e.g., Atif et al. 2020). The CEO’s remuneration is viewed as a corporate governance mechanism to encourage the CEO to achieve shareholders’ aims (Oehmichen et al. 2020). However, particularly after the 2008 financial crisis, there have been some concerns about high CEO remuneration. Nonetheless, this controversy is less evident when remuneration is linked with better financial performance (Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Elsayed and Elbardan 2018).
The income of the executives in large corporations has always deserved special attention, namely when the company is involved in a scandal or when a (world) crisis occurs. For example, it is often heard that employees have to be laid off to reduce costs, or fewer dividends will be distributed, but in rare cases, the remuneration of the CEO is reduced (Sommer 2020). Even during the COVID-19 pandemic, the remuneration of the DAX CEOs decreased negligibly while the net profit of the shareholders decreased by 3.5 billion euros (Spiegel.de 2021). Due to CEOs’ responsibility, it is expected that they have a higher remuneration than other board members. But is that additional remuneration a real booster of higher performance?
According to managerial hegemony theory, CEOs, in general, have the power to determine their own contracts (Bebchuk et al. 2002). However, remuneration can be used as a mechanism to improve firms’ performance, not only as compensation for the CEO’s knowledge and effort (tournament theory) (Connelly et al. 2014), but also as an agency conflicts reduction (Jensen and Murphy 1990).
Some studies have found that CEO remuneration positively impacts firm performance (Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Akter et al. 2020; Azim et al. 2011; Elsayed and Elbardan 2018). Agency theory suggests that CEO remuneration is a way to reduce the conflict of interests between the agent and the principals by aligning their interests and reducing CEOs’ opportunistic behaviors (Jensen and Murphy 1990). When rewarded, the CEO can be motivated to increase his/her efficiency, which can lead to an increase in the firm’s performance (Doucouliagos et al. 2007). Moreover, tournament theory suggests that when CEOs feel rewarded, they try to be more efficient, which can result in an increase in the firm’s performance (Connelly et al. 2014). CEO remuneration is defined by the board, which is the body responsible not only for defining the CEO’s compensation, but also for monitoring whether its decisions are in line with the interests of the principal (Ozdemir and Upneja 2012). The question that arises is whether the definition of this remuneration, which is higher than the average remuneration of the board itself, in fact promotes financial performance.
This paper aims to understand the relationship between additional CEO remuneration and future firm performance. Most studies analyzed the impact of CEO remuneration, but according to the recent trends in CEO compensation, it is suggested that compensation can be an incentive system when there is a pay gap between the CEO and other executives (Ullah et al. 2022). In this way, it is intended to analyze if the higher remuneration of the CEO, compared with the mean remuneration of other board members, is a driver of firms’ financial performance. Moreover, we not only analyze the additional total remuneration, but we split it into its components: salary, bonus, grants, and pension. The impact of remuneration on a firm’s performance can be singular, depending on the type of remuneration, as suggested by previous researchers (e.g., Azim et al. 2011; Banker et al. 2013; Smirnova and Zavertiaeva 2017), and the CEO can have a different remuneration package when compared with the board. An unbalanced panel data of listed firms in DAX from 2006 to 2019 is analyzed. Financial performance is measured using two alternative perspectives, one accounting-based measurement (ROA—return on assets) and one market-based measurement (Tobin’s Q) (Sharma and Carney 2012).
This study makes several contributions to the literature and to the practice. First, to the best of our knowledge, it is the first study that focuses on the impact of additional remuneration on future performance. We focus on additional remuneration instead of on remuneration, as most works do. Tournament theory suggests that a person works harder when he/she can win the highest remuneration as a premium. Therefore, we analyze if CEO efficiency, and in turn the firm’s performance, increases when the additional remuneration over the average value of the board of directors is higher. Some works, such as Balafas and Florackis (2014) and Zheng (2020), have analyzed CEO abnormal remuneration, comparing firms from the same industry and size or estimating it through a model, although each firm has a specific strategy and remuneration can be different even for firms operating in the same industry. Therefore, we focus on the additional remuneration of the CEO compared with the other board members to understand the motivational effect. Furthermore, we believe that the motivational effect of additional remuneration is not immediate (contrary to what most studies consider). In this way, the analysis is conducted with the additional remuneration lagged by one year, following Balafas and Florackis (2014). Moreover, there is no consensus about the impact of remuneration on firm performance; it remains a controversial issue, so studying this theme is still relevant to contributing to its debate and explanation. The current literature has essentially been carried out in the United Kingdom, Bangladesh, Australia, and the USA (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Aslam et al. 2019, Azim et al. 2011, Banker et al. 2013). By analyzing German listed firms, we are expanding the literature review. We chose Germany since listed firms are obligated to publish information about each executive’s remuneration, and the CEO is controlled by the supervisory board, contrary to firms from the USA (Beck et al. 2020). Finally, our model includes remuneration components, as well as control variables from the group of firms’ financial characteristics, corporate governance, and macroeconomic factors to explain performance, allowing for a better understanding of firm performance.
The remaining paper is organized as follows. After the introduction, Section 2 provides a literature review of the topic and presents the research hypotheses. The research methods, namely the model and sample, are explained in Section 3, followed by the empirical results. The main conclusions are drawn in the last section.

2. Literature Review

The relationship between remuneration and performance has been addressed in the literature and it is usually explained based on different theoretical supports: (i) agency theory; (ii) the managerial hegemony perspective; (iii) tournament theory; and (iv) stewardship theory.
Agency theory states that the separation between ownership and control may cause conflicts of interest. CEOs have more information about the company and can use it to satisfy personal objectives, expropriating the firm’s wealth (Jensen and Meckling 1976). One way to overcome these conflicts is through increased monitoring of CEOs’ decisions (Fama and Jensen 1983). Another way is by increasing the CEO’s remuneration (Jensen and Murphy 1990). When certain targets of firm performance are achieved, CEOs will be compensated, so they have the additional incentive to increase performance to earn more money. This theory suggests a positive connection between compensation and firm performance when perfect contracts are established (Azim et al. 2011).
The managerial hegemony perspective suggests that the CEO has enough power to influence their own remuneration package. Therefore, incentives may not be linked with higher performance (Bebchuk et al. 2002).
Tournament theory does not focus on the link between compensation and performance but wants to justify high CEO remuneration. Tournament theory suggests that CEOs are more motivated to increase performance when they need to work harder and remuneration depends on the firm’s performance, rather than on absolute levels of output (Connelly et al. 2014). This suggests that to promote an increase in the CEO’s efficiency and the firm’s performance, his/her remuneration should also increase, i.e., remuneration should be aligned with firm performance.
Finally, stewardship theory has a different perspective on CEOs’ behavior. This theory argues that CEOs are professional and want to do their best on the job without the need for an inner motivation (Donaldson and Davis 1991). This theory does not defend the financial or personal motivations of CEOs (Afrifa and Adesina 2018). Therefore, the firm’s performance depends on how CEOs can effectively decide. Based on this theory, CEOs do not need superior remuneration, but instead, they need a structure that helps them to effectively make the best decisions to increase the firm’s performance.
Based on the previous theories, when the CEO is motivated to perform at their best with financial incentives, the incentives between the CEO and the principals are aligned, and agency problems are reduced. Moreover, the CEO tends to employ his/her skills to achieve the firm’s goals, which in turn has a positive effect on remuneration and performance (Jensen and Murphy 1990; Connelly et al. 2014). From this perspective, the agents’ motivation is mainly financial, to satisfy self-interests, contrary to the suggestion by stewardship theory that CEOs draw intrinsic satisfaction from doing a job well. Although this may happen only when a CEO feels that his/her work is being valued, following tournament theory, it means that this may occur when there is a remuneration gap that justifies the CEO to increase his/her work effort (Lin and Lu 2009).
Previous researchers have not found a unique impact of CEO remuneration on firm performance. Akter et al. (2020) found that higher remuneration is not enough to increase the firm’s performance. Focusing on textile companies listed on the stock exchange in Bangladesh (Dhake Stock Exchange), they found a significant negative link between the two dependent variables, ROA and ROE (return on equity), and the total compensation, which can be explained due to the illiquid capital market in Bangladesh and the lack of share-based remuneration.
Banker et al. (2013), analyzing US firms from 1993 to 2006, found the opposite effect: salary and total remuneration are positively related to ROE. Similar conclusions were found by Chen and Huang (2010), who also analyze firms from the USA. Smirnova and Zavertiaeva (2017), analyzing listed firms from Great Britain, Germany, France, Switzerland, Italy, Spain, and the Netherlands from 2009 to 2013, found that total remuneration positively impacts ROA and bonus remuneration positively impacts the Sharpe index. Elsayed and Elbardan (2018), analyzing FTSE 350 firms (UK) over the period from 2010 to 2014, also found a positive impact of CEO remuneration on firm performance.
Other authors found mixed results, depending on the type of remuneration and firm performance measure. Azim et al. (2011), when analyzing listed firms from Australia during the years 2007–2008, found a negative impact on CEO salary and the accounting variable ROI (return on investment), but a positive impact on other remunerations, mainly bonuses and options and the market-based performance measure EPS (earnings per share). Also, Aslam et al. (2019), when analyzing listed firms in Pakistan from 2009 to 2016, found that cash-based remuneration negatively impacts Tobin’s Q and EPS, but non-cash compensation is positively related to firms’ performance.
Nonetheless, Afrifa and Adesina (2018) found evidence of a non-linear relationship between performance and remuneration. Higher remuneration leads to an increase in firm performance only to a certain point. After the breakpoint is reached, an increase in remuneration reduces the performance of the company. It was a new approach that the authors followed, as previous studies mostly assumed a linear relationship.
Our study does not focus on remuneration, but on additional CEO remuneration compared with the mean of the board remuneration (remuneration gap). The analysis differs from the approach of Balafas and Florackis (2014), who analyzed abnormal CEO remuneration compared to companies in the same sector. We also differ from Zheng (2020), who estimates the difference between the remuneration provided and the expected remuneration considering a set of characteristics. The intention is to verify whether the board, by setting a remuneration (and the respective components) above the average of those who have the role of setting and monitoring the CEO, causes a motivating effect and is reflected in a superior financial performance. This is because, in accordance with tournament theory, a large compensation gap may be a company performance promotor (Wang et al. 2021). When the gap pay scheme is structured in a way that encourages competition, this may lead to a greater effort to improve performance to justify this difference. Additionally, as a motivating driver (Ullah et al. 2022) and in line with Balafas and Florackis (2014), it is believed that the effect does not have immediate repercussions. Therefore, considering the literature above, it is expected that an increase in CEO additional remuneration in the previous year leads to higher levels of current financial performance. Thus, the following hypothesis is established:
Hypothesis 1.
There is a positive impact of the CEO’s additional remuneration from the previous year on the current firm’s performance.
Moreover, as shown before, the type of remuneration can cause a singular impact on firms’ performance. Total remuneration can be divided into different components, such as the base salary, bonus, grants, pension, and other benefits (Smirnova and Zavertiaeva 2017). Regarding the base salary, it is a remuneration component that is contractually fixed. Bonuses, on another side, are a variable remuneration component that can incentivize the CEO to achieve the firm’s targets (Atif et al. 2020). Therefore, the bonus component is the main driver for a significant pay-performance relationship, and it may drive the inner motivation of the CEO (Smirnova and Zavertiaeva 2017). Moreover, firms sometimes pay grants, pension benefits, and/or offer one-time payments as a premium for managers’ efforts. According to Beck et al. (2020), all firms listed in DAX use a base salary to pay executives. Most of them use a variable short-term component (90% in 2018), and several use stock options (70%) and pensions (80%).
Considering tournament theory, better-paid executives tend to achieve more improvements in firm performance and reduce agency conflicts. Hence, we also analyze the impact of each type of remuneration on firms’ performance. Based on the literature review and the hypothesis mentioned above, the proposed conceptual research model is as follows (Figure 1):

3. Research Methods

3.1. Model

A dynamic panel data model is used to test the hypothesis formulated, i.e., the impact of CEO additional remuneration on firms’ future performance. Performance tends to be persistent, and its current values can be influenced by past ones, as suggested by Aslam et al. (2019) and Banker et al. (2013), among others. The following regression models are analyzed:
P e r f i , t = α × P e r f i , t 1 + β × A d d i t i o n a l   R e m i , t 1 + γ × C o n t r o l   V a r i a b l e s + ε i , t
where i is the firm analyzed, t is the year studied, and ε i , t is the disturbance term.
The GMM (generalized method of moments) approach can be used to obtain consistent and unbiased estimators, overcoming endogeneity, simultaneity, and heteroscedasticity problems (Arellano and Bond 1991; Arellano and Bover 1995). We applied a two-step estimation with equations in level, and to validate the adopted specifications, we analyzed the Sargan test of overidentifying restrictions, the Wald test, and the autocorrelation of first- (AR(1)) and second-order (AR(2)) errors.
We decided to focus on additional remuneration instead of remuneration since based on tournament theory, when CEOs receive higher salaries they are more motivated to improve their efficiency, which in turn can affect the firm’s performance improvements. Moreover, as the gap pay scheme is structured to encourage competition, that can lead to improved financial performance. Additional remuneration refers to the previous period (Balafas and Florackis 2014). The additional remuneration is measured through the difference between the CEO remuneration and the mean remuneration of the board.
Moreover, we divided remuneration into its components, as previous results show that results may depend on the type of remuneration used. Thus, total remuneration is subdivided into fixed salary, bonuses (one-year and multi-year bonuses), grants, and pensions. There are also some other remunerations, including one-time payments, but the number of observations is scarce, so we decided to not include it as a singular variable, but it is included in total remuneration (Beck et al. 2020). Following other researchers, the natural logarithm of the additional remuneration was used to standardize the data (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Aslam et al. 2019).
There is no universal measure of performance. Therefore, in this work, firm performance was measured using two perspectives: accounting-based and market-based perspectives, as in several previous works (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Aslam et al. 2019; Azim et al. 2011; Elsayed and Elbardan 2018). Using both perspectives, we can detect singularities caught by each one and have an overall picture of financial performance. Moreover, accounting ratios are more relevant to managers to support their decisions, while market measures are more relevant to investors to measure shareholders’ wealth.
From the accounting-based perspective, the ROA is used as it is one of the most traditional ratios used in this area (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Azim et al. 2011; Doucouliagos et al. 2007; Smirnova and Zavertiaeva 2017). It was calculated using earnings before interests and taxes (EBIT) divided by total assets. Tobin’s Q (TQ) was selected as a market-based measure. Tobin’s Q is an estimator that indicates whether a market or business is under or overvalued (Elsayed and Elbardan 2018). It was calculated by dividing the market value by the book value (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Azim et al. 2011).
As in previous research, control variables were also included, divided into financial control, corporate governance, and macroeconomic variables. Financial variable controls tend to measure firms’ specific characteristics, such as firm size, firm age, asset turnover, sales growth, and debt. Corporate governance control variables help to reduce problems related to the lack of accountability, transparency, and disclosure (Aslam et al. 2019). Board size and board time were included. Finally, GDP growth and inflation rates were introduced to measure macroeconomic effects. Each control variable was analyzed as follows.
Firm size was measured as the natural logarithm of total assets (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Akter et al. 2020; Aslam et al. 2019; Azim et al. 2011). Beck et al. (2020) argue that German executive compensation levels depend on the firm’s size. Large-size firms usually are more diversified and have more resources. These firms are more likely to benefit from economies of scale and higher operating and financing efficiency, which can reduce the firm’s uncertainties and boost its performance. However, smaller firms can more easily recognize growth opportunities since communication is easier. Large-size firms usually have more communication problems due to conflicts of interest, which can delay decision-making and damage the firm’s performance. Afrifa and Adesina (2018) and Aslam et al. (2019) found a positive impact on size and firm performance, while Akter et al. (2020) found the same effect on ROE but the opposite effect on ROA.
Firm age was measured as the natural logarithm of age—the firm’s year of working activity (e.g., Afrifa and Adesina 2018; Akter et al. 2020). Older firms have more knowledge and experience about the market and a higher ability to lead in unexpected situations. Therefore, these firms can be more efficient, which can enhance performance. However, older firms may be stuck in older practices and can lack technology and innovation, causing a negative impact on the firm’s value. Akter et al. (2020) found a negative impact of age on ROA, while Afrifa and Adesina (2018) and Aslam et al. (2019) found the opposite effect.
Asset turnover was measured as the ratio of total sales over total assets and shows the firm’s efficiency in managing its assets. The higher the ratio, the more efficient the firm is in generating revenues, which in turn positively impacts the firm’s performance. Akter et al. (2020) found a positive impact of assets turnover on ROA.
Sales growth was the annual growth of sales (e.g., Smirnova and Zavertiaeva 2017). Higher sales growth can cause a positive impact on performance but can be also a synonym for excessive risk-taking strategies that increase a firm’s uncertainty, causing a negative impact on performance.
Debt was measured as the ratio of total debt divided by total assets. The firm’s financial leverage can have an impact on the firm’s reputation, as it indicates how much of the total firm assets are carried out by debt (Smirnova and Zavertiaeva 2017). On one side, the more debt firms have, the higher their financial costs due to debt covenants. This may decrease their profits and deteriorate their performance. On another side, more indebted firms can invest more, increasing their activity and the probability of more earnings in the future. Moreover, debt is also an external mechanism to monitor CEOs to avoid opportunistic behaviors, since they have less free cash flow and more pressure to manage the firm’s resources more efficiently. Therefore, debt has a dubious impact on firm performance. Akter et al. (2020) found a negative impact of debt on ROA, while Afrifa and Adesina (2018) found no impact.
Board size was measured as the natural logarithm of total board members (e.g., Aslam et al. 2019). The board is responsible for monitoring CEOs and protecting shareholders’ interests. Larger boards usually attract more resources and can easily control CEOs’ opportunism. However, larger boards also have more communication problems, which can enhance conflicts of interest between the principals and managers.
Board time was the number of years the board is in activity. Handschumacher-Knors (2022) argue that executive compensation depends on the length of service. Moreover, Smirnova and Zavertiaeva (2017) suggest that the years at the firm indicate experience. The longer the period the board has been working, the greater their experience, which can enhance the firm’s performance.
GDP was measured as the annual growth of GDP (e.g., Aslam et al. 2019). When GDP grows, the economy is in a solvent position, which causes a positive impact on the firm’s performance, while when GDP decreases, the country’s economy declines, causing a negative impact on firms’ growth.
Inflation rate was the country’s inflation rate (e.g., Aslam et al. 2019). When inflation increases, all prices are more expensive, so usually the firm’s performance decreases due to sales decreases.

3.2. Sample

This work analyses the relationship between the additional CEO remuneration and firm performance of DAX listed firms. Germany is a founding member of the EU (European Union), being the main contributor to the EU budget, and delegating 96 of the 705 members of the European Parliament (European Union 2020). For German listed firms, information about the different remuneration components is available and explained in the same way, as these firms are obliged to publish this kind of information. Additionally, German listed firms, contrary to USA firms, have high ownership concentration, with a dominant shareholder, and CEOs are controlled by the supervisory board (Beck et al. 2020; Handschumacher-Knors 2022).
Due to the data remuneration availability, listed firms are analyzed. Moreover, by analyzing listed firms, performance can be evaluated through accounting and market perspectives. Therefore, an overall picture of firms’ performance can be drawn by understanding both past and expected value created.
The data on German CEO remuneration were collected from the database of Professor Beck and his colleagues from the Technical University Munich (Germany) (Beck et al. 2020). The firms’ accounting and market data were obtained from Thomson Reuters Datastream, and macroeconomic data were obtained from Eurostat.
Due to their specific accounting practices, financial firms such as banks and insurance companies were excluded from our sample, following Azim et al. (2011), Afrifa and Adesina (2018), and Handschumacher-Knors (2022), for example. In addition, the real estate management firms were neglected because their business—renting and selling properties—is not comparable to the other ones.
After taking this into account, the sample is an unbalanced panel data of 41 German listed firms in DAX between 2006 and 2019. The year 2006 was chosen due to data availability and because it was when listed firms were required to disclose information about compensation and distinguish several compensation components. The year 2019 was the last year with available data on remuneration (Beck et al. 2020).

4. Results

Figure 2 shows the evolution of the mean value of the additional remuneration per type and year.
Handschumacher-Knors (2022) found that the higher component of remuneration of the board members of German listed firms is the variable component bonus. Analyzing Figure 2, we see that CEOs receive, on average, higher remuneration, especially the component bonus, compared with other board members. Moreover, additional remuneration (mainly in terms of bonuses) decreased from 2007 to 2009, the years of the international financial crisis of 2007/2008 (with the peak in 2018).
Table 1 provides the main descriptive statistics, namely the mean, median, standard variation, minimum, and maximum of the variables used.
Firm performance (ROA and TQ) is, in mean, positive, suggesting the firm’s ability to generate earnings (ROA—mean value 6.1%) and a positive investor perception about the firm’s value compared to its book value (TQ—mean value 1.4). However, both measures present a high range, meaning that not all firms perform in the same way, especially regarding the TQ measure, which varies from undervalued firms (minimum value −24.8) to overvalued (maximum value 12.1).
Regarding the additional remuneration (DSalary, DBonus, DGrants, DPension, DTotal), the mean values are positive, which means that CEOs earn more than the average remuneration of the board members in all components. In contrast, for pensions some firms pay less to CEOs compared to other board members (the minimum value is negative). This fact shows the relevance of analyzing not only the total remuneration but also each component, as the compensation package of the CEO can be singular compared to the other board members. Moreover, the remuneration descriptive statistics corroborate the analysis performed in Figure 2.
Concerning control variables, size, measured as the natural logarithm of total assets, has a mean of 17.9, while age, measured as the natural logarithm of age, is on average 4.1. Assets turnover is 0.65 on average, and sales growth is positive, suggesting that the firms in the sample present growth opportunities. On average, 24% of the firm’s assets are financed through debt, meaning that the business is mainly operated by equity. The board size, measured as the natural logarithm of board members, is on average 1.9, and the board remains active for around 8.5 years. GDP growth is on average positive over the period analyzed, as is the inflation rate, suggesting that the German economy grew from 2006 until 2019.
Table 2 displays the correlation matrix among the variables as well as the VIF (variance inflation factor) analysis.
ROA and TQ are positively correlated, which is expected since they are both performance measures, albeit from different perspectives. Moreover, all types of additional remuneration considered are positively related to TQ, but only the additional bonus is positively correlated with ROA, which suggests that additional remuneration impacts firms’ performance. For additional total remuneration, the correlation with performance measures is not statistically significant, which calls for the need to explore different types of remuneration instead of total remuneration. The control variables are not always statistically correlated to both performance measures, suggesting that the way performance is evaluated (accounting- or market-based) caused an impact on the results. Moreover, none of the variables are highly correlated, nor have high VIF values (variance inflation factor).
Table 3 and Table 4 show the results obtained with the application of Equation (1) for the different types of remuneration and performance (ROA and Tobin’s Q).
Analyzing the results presented in Table 3 and Table 4, the Sargan test presents p-values greater than 5%, showing that the instruments are valid; the Wald test has a p-value of less than 5%, meaning that the joint significance and the coefficients are significantly distributed; and the AR(2) reveals that there is no second-order correlation problem in the model.
Over time, firms maintain similar performance, which means that the ROA and TQ performances of the previous year (ROAt−1 and TQt−1) explain current performances (ROAt and TQt), as is proposed by Aslam et al. (2019) and Banker et al. (2013).
Moreover, the fact that additional salary, grants, and total remuneration lagged one year positively explains firm performance measured by ROA, while when it is measured by TQ, all additional remuneration components, as well as total additional remuneration, are statistically and positively significant. The results suggest that an increase in CEO remuneration over the mean value of the board’s remuneration contributes to increasing the firm’s performance. This result corroborates Hypothesis 1 and is in line with tournament theory. The CEO is more motivated to increase performance when there is more competition, and he/she feels that his/her hard work is compensated. Banker et al. (2013), Chen and Huang (2010), Smirnova and Zavertiaeva (2017), and Elsayed and Elbardan (2018), among others, found that an increase in CEO remuneration increases firm performance. Here we go a step further by showing that when remuneration is higher than the average remuneration of the board members, the firm performance increases, so remuneration is not only an incentive to monitor managers, as suggested by agency theory, but it is also a motivation to increase the CEO’s efficiency.1 The difference between the two measures of performance relates to bonus and pension, two performance-related elements of remuneration (Zheng 2020). Therefore, our results suggest that these components of remuneration do not contribute to increasing the firm’s earnings, and in turn return on assets, while they do impact the market-to-book value.
Regarding the control variables, the firm’s size is not always statistically significant, but when it is, it has a positive impact on the firm’s performance (measured by both ROA and TQ). The results suggest that large-size firms have better performances because these firms are usually more diversified, can benefit from economies of scale, and because a larger size can reduce uncertainties which can damage the firm’s performance. Similar results were found by Afrifa and Adesina (2018) and Aslam et al. (2019). Older firms have more knowledge about the market and more experience, and so show better performance. Our results corroborate those of Afrifa and Adesina (2018) and Aslam et al. (2019). More efficient firms with greater asset turnover show better performance since these firms are more efficient in generating revenue and it positively impacts the firm’s earnings, returns, and value. Akter et al. (2020) also found a positive impact of asset turnover on ROA. Companies with the highest growth exhibit higher performance. When annual sales increase, firms can increase their market share and its earnings, returns, and values. This result is in line with that of Smirnova and Zavertiaeva (2017). The firm’s leverage is not always relevant to explain the firm’s performance, but when it is statistically significant, it causes a positive impact on firm performance. Debt is an external mechanism to monitor CEOs’ opportunistic behaviors, so it can enhance performance by aligning interests between the principal and CEOs. Even if on one side more leveraged firms have more financial costs which decrease the firm profits, its positive effect is more prominent in this sample.
Concerning the board size, it is only relevant to explain performance when it is measured by TQ. Larger boards can attract more resources and are more efficient in controlling CEOs’ opportunistic behaviors, which leads to better performance. The board time positively influences ROA, suggesting that the higher the number of years the board has been active, the greater their experience, which leads to an increase in ROA.
Finally, the macroeconomic variables GDP growth and inflation rate positively impact firm performance. In moments of economic development, firms can increase their activity and performance. Even if prices increase, which can cause a negative impact on sales, as the economy is growing, the firm’s activity also increases, contributing to an increase in firms’ return and value.

5. Conclusions

This paper aimed to understand the impact of CEO additional remuneration on firm performance. Previous works found that remuneration impacts performance as it is an incentive to control CEOs’ opportunism and reduce agency problems. Based on tournament theory, this study attempted to analyze if the difference between CEO remuneration and the mean of the board members’ remuneration can be a performance driver. We wanted to analyze if the higher CEO remunerations (and their components) are justified by their follow-up with higher levels of performance, i.e., whether the wage gap has a motivating effect and allows for increased performance.
Based on secondary data from 2006 to 2019 from companies listed in Germany, our results prove that the additional variables of remuneration contribute to increasing the firm’s financial performance. Even if CEO remuneration is a controversial issue, our results show that a higher remuneration gap contributes to maximizing the firm’s value and thus that CEOs are being compensated for their effort. This result is consistent with all remuneration components and analyzing performance from a historical perspective (accounting measure ROA) and a forecast perspective (market measure TQ). Moreover, our work shows that performance-related remuneration components (bonus and pension) impact the forecast perspective of financial performance, but not the historical perspective (ROA). Firms’ performance also increases with firm size, age, asset turnover, growth, debt, board size, board time, and macroeconomic factors.
This study contributes to the literature in several ways. First, it is the first work, as far as we are aware, that analyzes the impact of additional remuneration on firm performance. Therefore, it contributes to enriching the themes of remuneration and performance. Studies that analyze the impact of remuneration on firm performance do not achieve a consensus. We approached this theme in a different way, i.e., we analyzed if the remuneration gap is justifiable with a performance increase. Moreover, not only the total remuneration was analyzed but also its components, and two perspectives of performance were taken into account, allowing an overall picture of the relationship between remuneration and financial performance. Finally, there are few studies that focus on the impact of remuneration on performance, so this work expands the literature review.
Results are also relevant to practice. CEOs can justify their high remuneration as a motivational effect, investors can understand the impact of higher CEO remuneration on firm performance, and shareholders can comprehend how they can reduce the conflicts of interest between CEOs and the principal and the benefits of establishing perfect remuneration contracts. Creditors and other stakeholders can understand which factors contribute to increasing firms’ performance.
For future work, this analysis can be expanded to other companies and countries. Our results are specific to the largest firms in Germany and cannot be extrapolated to other firms. Moreover, even if we have tested a non-linear relationship between remuneration and performance and did not find any relevant conclusion, analyzing other samples or sample periods could be useful, as after a time CEOs may not feel motivated to continue to increase the firm performance even if remuneration also increases. Tournament theory suggests that CEOs are only incentivized to increase performance until ‘winning the tournament’. Industry effects of macroeconomic impacts such as the financial crisis of 2007/2008 or the COVID-19 can have an impact on results and can also be included in the analysis to verify if they cause some impact. Finally, other corporate governance variables, such as gender diversity, can also explain performance. Some works found that female presence on the board, as an executive or other board member, impacts the firm’s risk, capital structure, and other factors. Moreover, Handschumacher-Knors (2022) found that women who are board members of German listed companies receive, on average, lower compensation than men, but are still underrepresented on the boards. Therefore, the female additional remuneration gap impact on firm performance should also be addressed.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; methodology, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; software, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; validation, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; formal analysis, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; investigation, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; resources, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; data curation, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; writing—original draft preparation, M.C. and I.L.; writing—review and editing, M.C. and I.L.; visualization, M.C., I.L. and R.M.; supervision, I.L.; project administration, M.C. and I.L.; funding acquisition, M.C. and I.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by National Funds of the FCT—Portuguese Foundation for Science and Technology within the project [UIDB/04928/2020].

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Data on German CEO remuneration were collected from the database of Professor Beck and his colleagues from the Technical University Munich (Germany) (Beck et al. 2020), firms’ accounting and market data were obtained from Thomson Reuters Datastream, and macroeconomic data were obtained from Eurostat.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Variable descriptions.
Table A1. Variable descriptions.
VariablesNotationCalculation
PerformanceROAtEBITt/Total Assetst
TQtMarket Valuet/Book Valuet
ROAt−1EBITt−1/Total Assetst−1
TQt−1Market Valuet−1/Book Valuet−1
RemunerationDSalarytLn(CEO’s salaryt- mean board salaryt)
DBonustLn(CEO’s bonust- mean board bonust)
DGrantstLn(CEO’s grantst- mean board grantst)
DPensiontLn(CEO’s pensiont- mean board pensiont)
DTotaltLn(CEO’s total remunerationt- mean board total remunerationt)
DSalaryt−1Ln(CEO’s salaryt−1- mean board salaryt−1)
DBonust−1Ln(CEO’s bonust−1- mean board bonust−1)
DGrantst−1Ln(CEO’s grantst−1- mean board grantst−1)
DPensiont−1Ln(CEO’s pensiont−1- mean board pensiont−1)
DTotalt−1Ln(CEO’s total remunerationt−1- mean board total remunerationt−1)
Financial SizeLn(total asset)
AgeLn(firm’s year of working activity)
TurnoverTotal sales/Total assets
Growth(Salest- Salest−1)/Salest−1
DebtTotal debt/Total assets
Corporate governance Board SizeLn(total board members)
Board TimeNumber of years the board is in activity
Macroeconomic GDPAnnual growth of GDP
INFInflation rate

Note

1
A non-linear relationship between CEO additional remuneration and performance was also tested, but the results suggested a linear relationship.

References

  1. Afrifa, Godfred Adjappong, and Oluseyi Oluseun Adesina. 2018. How does directors’ remuneration affect SMEs’ performance? Review of Accounting and Finance 17: 238–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Akter, Sharmin, Md Ali, Md Abedin, and Balal Hossain. 2020. Directors’ remuneration and performance: Evidence from the textile sector of Bangladesh. Journal of Asian Finance, Economics and Business 7: 265–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Arellano, Manuel, and Olympia Bover. 1995. Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Aslam, Ejaz, Razali Haron, and Muhammad Naveed Tahir. 2019. How director remuneration impacts firm performance: An empirical analysis of executive director remuneration in Pakistan. Borsa Istanbul Review 19: 186–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Atif, Muhammad, Allen Huang, and Benjamin Liu. 2020. The effect of say on pay on CEO compensation and spill-over effect on corporate cash holdings: Evidence from Australia. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 64: 101105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Azim, Mohammad Istiaq, Joyce Mei, and Samina Rahman. 2011. Executive’s remuneration and company performance: An evaluation. Corporate Board: Role, Duties & Composition 7: 16–31. [Google Scholar]
  8. Balafas, Nikolaos, and Chris Florackis. 2014. CEO compensation and future shareholder returns: Evidence from the London Stock Exchange. Journal of Empirical Finance 27: 97–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Banker, Rajiv D., Masako N. Darrough, Rong Huang, and Jose M. Plehn-Dujowich. 2013. The relation between CEO compensation and past performance. The Accounting Review 88: 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bebchuk, Lucian A., Jesse Fried, and David Walker. 2002. Managerial Power and Rent Extraction in the Design of Executive Compensation. NBER Working Paper 9068. Cambridge: NBER, July. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Beck, Daniel, Gunther Friedl, and Peter Schäfer. 2020. Executive compensation in Germany. Journal of Business Economics 90: 787–824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Chen, Carl R., and Ying Sophie Huang. 2010. Simultaneous estimation of executive compensation and firm performance in the banking industry. Advances in Quantitative Analysis of Finance and Accounting 8: 101–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Connelly, Brian L., Laszlo Tihanyi, T. Russell Crook, and K. Ashley Gangloff. 2014. Tournament theory: Thirty years of contests and competitions. Journal of Management 40: 16–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Donaldson, Lex, and James H. Davis. 1991. Stewardship theory or agency theory: CEO governance and shareholder returns. Australian Journal of Management 16: 49–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Doucouliagos, Hristos, Janto Haman, and Saeed Askary. 2007. Directors’ remuneration and performance in Australian banking. Corporate Governance: An International Review 15: 1363–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Elsayed, Nader, and Hany Elbardan. 2018. Investigating the associations between executive compensation and firm performance: Agency theory or tournament theory. Journal of Applied Accounting Research 19: 245–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. European Union. 2020. Germany. Available online: https://europa.eu/european-union/about-eu/countries/member-countries/germany_en (accessed on 8 December 2022).
  18. Fama, Eugene F., and Michael C. Jensen. 1983. Separation of ownership and control. The Journal of Law and Economics 26: 301–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Handschumacher-Knors, Franziska. 2022. Does a gender pay gap exist on executive boards? An empirical multilevel analysis of executive board compensation in German listed companies. Journal of Business Economics 93: 325–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Jensen, Michael C., and Kevin J. Murphy. 1990. Performance pay and top-management incentives. Journal of Political Economy 98: 225–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Jensen, Michael C., and William H. Meckling. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Lin, Bing-Xuan, and Rui Lu. 2009. Managerial power, compensation gap and firm performance—Evidence from Chinese public listed companies. Global Finance Journal 20: 153–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Oehmichen, Jana, Laura Jacobey, and Michael Wolff. 2020. Have we made ourselves (too) clear? Performance effects of the incentive explicitness in CEO compensation. Long Range Planning 53: 101893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Ozdemir, Ozgur, and Arun Upneja. 2012. Board structure and CEO compensation: Evidence from US lodging industry. International Journal of Hospitality Management 31: 856–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Sharma, Pramodita, and Michael Carney. 2012. Value creation and performance in private family firms: Measurement and methodological issues. Family Business Review 25: 233–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Smirnova, Aleksandra S., and Marina A. Zavertiaeva. 2017. Which came first, CEO compensation or firm performance? The causality dilemma in European companies. Research in International Business and Finance 42: 658–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Sommer, U. 2020. Umbau der Wirtschaft: Dax-konzerne Streichen mehr jobs als in der Finanzkrise. Available online: https://www.handelsblatt.com/unternehmen/management/pandemie-folgen-umbau-der-wirtschaft-dax-konzerne-streichen-mehr-jobs-als-in-der-finanzkrise/26227244.html?ticket=ST-137070-pfdfjdveqeu4mMUo1dbd-ap6 (accessed on 22 September 2021).
  28. Spiegel.de. 2021. Das verdienen die Dax-manager. Available online: https://www.spiegel.de/wirtschaft/unternehmen/dax-manager-einkommens-ranking-offenbart-starkes-gehaltsgefaelle-unter-den-bossen-a-be0d62de-92fd-4562-9385-aeb0c5f1d420 (accessed on 1 August 2021).
  29. Ullah, Sajid, Farman Ullah Khan, Laura-Mariana Cismaș, Muhammad Usman, and Andra Miculescu. 2022. Do tournament incentives matter for CEOs to be environmentally responsible? Evidence from Chinese listed companies. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 19: 470. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  30. Wang, Chaohui, Su Zhang, Subhan Ullah, Raza Ullah, and Farid Ullah. 2021. Executive compensation and corporate performance of energy companies around the world. Energy Strategy Reviews 38: 100749. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Zheng, Junxia. 2020. Earnings Management, Earnings Benchmarks, and Directors’ Remuneration: UK Evidence. Doctoral dissertation, Newcastle University, Tyne and Wear, UK. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Conceptual research model.
Figure 1. Conceptual research model.
Risks 11 00133 g001
Figure 2. Evolution of mean value of additional remuneration.
Figure 2. Evolution of mean value of additional remuneration.
Risks 11 00133 g002
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
VariablesNMeanMedianStd. DeviationMinimumMaximum
ROAt4206.1375.8755.213−6.65635.752
TQt4221.4030.7402.346−24.82712.110
DSalaryt−13876.1446.2030.6781.2047.802
DBonust−1 3876.0896.5891.9830.0009.826
DGrantst−13874.7865.9662.6640.0008.519
DPensiont−1 3873.9395.0422.693−0.0067.444
DTotalt−13877.1007.5371.8330.0009.860
Sizet 38717.86917.7361.44014.35521.509
Aget4224.1694.6051.0231.0995.861
Turnovert4230.6500.6260.3970.0101.689
Growtht4220.0440.0450.141−0.6840.775
Debtt42323.95022.20715.1100.27784.387
Board Sizet4221.9011.9460.3280.6932.639
Board Timet 4238.5068.0004.7390.00027.000
GDPt4231.5391.5002.345−5.7004.200
INFt4231.5321.7000.7780.2002.800
Notes: Variables are described in Appendix A Table A1.
Table 2. Correlation matrix.
Table 2. Correlation matrix.
VariablesROAtTQtDSalaryt−1Dbonust−1Dgrantst−1Dpensiont−1Dtotalt−1SizetAgetTurnovertGrowthtDebttBoard
Sizet
Board TimetGDPtINFtVIF
ROA
VIF
TQ
ROAt1.000
TQt0.221 **1.000
Dsalt−1−0.0510.122 *1.000 1.6181.623
Dbont−10.199 **0.111 *0.361 **1.000 1.6791.679
Dgrant−1−0.0170.119 *0.279 **0.181 **1.000 1.3571.359
Dpenst−1−0.0280.103 *0.236 **0.0700.285 **1.000 1.3501.351
Dtotalt−1−0.030−0.049−0.0110.028−0.096−0.0241.000 2.2942.295
Sizet0.115 *0.0830.544 **0.607 **0.377 **0.325 **0.0711.000 2.9512.942
Aget−0.554 **−0.0130.211 **-0.0880.229 **0.042−0.0540.0211.000 1.1491.151
Turnt0.019−0.254 **−0.081−0.008−0.0670.1010.0320.0430.152 **1.000 1.9121.910
Growt ht0.476 **0.0930.0180.177 **−0.0460.0250.0010.099−0.627 **−0.0901.000 1.1991.200
Debtt0.260 **0.157 **0.0120.112 *−0.016−0.094−0.0590.029−0.075−0.0900.0421.000 1.1501.149
Board Sizet−0.0880.0590.0530.004−0.016−0.145 **−0.159 **−0.0390.183 **−0.140 **−0.0900.201 **1.000 1.5921.592
Board Timet−0.134 **0.0620.201 **0.0310.172 **0.056−0.0300.0360.556 **0.144 **−0.213 **−0.0100.135 **1.000 1.1071.107
GDPt0.0930.052−0.0540.0700.053-0.0660.0030.036−0.022−0.104 *0.012−0.0460.0470.0431.000 1.3251.325
INFt0.125 *0.0150.0300.0440.0510.005−0.0420.0020.023−0.018−0.0030.300 **0.0100.035−0.0391.0001.2801.280
Notes: Variables are described in Appendix A Table A1. *, ** Significant at the 10% and 5% levels, respectively.
Table 3. Model results (ROA).
Table 3. Model results (ROA).
VariablesModel 1
ROA|Salary
Model 2
ROA|Bonus
Model 3
ROA|Grants
Model 4
ROA|Pension
Model 5
ROA|Total
Constt0.3120.17070.3020.2630.220
ROAt−10.000 ***0.000 ***0.001 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
DSalaryt−10.002 ***
DBonust−1 0.154
DGrantst−1 0.036 **
DPensiont−1 0.586
DTotalt−1 0.002 ***
Sizet0.072 *0.090 *0.1040.1540.106
Aget0.000 ***0.002 ***0.003 ***0.009 ***0.000 ***
Turnovert0.039 **0.002 ***0.001 ***0.001 ***0.024 **
Growtht0.009 ***0.000 ***0.014 **0.000 ***0.005 ***
Debtt0.5340.6020.070 *0.014 **0.768
Board Sizet0.8550.8030.4090.9720.901
Board Timet0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
GDPt0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
INFt0.003 ***0.4890.1700.080 *0.004 ***
Sargan27.73825.95419.48529.95626.781
Wald2460.85 ***10,623.6 ***837.625 ***850.998 ***4046.86 ***
AR(1)−2.704 ***−2.671 ***−2.458 **−2.349 **−2.548 **
AR(2)0.0910.1130.432−0.2670.091
Notes: Variables are described in Appendix A Table A1. *, **, *** Significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Table 4. Model results (Tobin’s Q).
Table 4. Model results (Tobin’s Q).
VariablesModel 6
TQ|Salary
Model 7
TQ|Bonus
Model 8
TQ|Grants
Model 9
TQ|Pension
Model 10
TQ|Total
Const0.9750.8930.5180.6690.902
TQt−10.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
DSalaryt−10.000 ***
DBonust−1 0.010 **
DGrantst−1 0.000 ***
DPensiont−1 0.000 ***
DTotalt−1 0.000 ***
Sizet0.6690.3320.3890.1040.263
Aget0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
Turnovert0.000 ***0.000 ***0.001 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
Growtht0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
Debtt0.3910.2350.0385 **0.8350.206
Board Sizet0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***0.000 ***
Board Timet0.2890.3180.9400.7190.505
GDPt0.024 **0.000 ***0.000 ***0.084 *0.000 ***
INFt0.000 ***0.000 ***0.001 ***0.047 **0.001 ***
Sargan19.50421.10423.66218.61419.856
Wald34,297.3 ***31,486.9 ***17,167.5 ***29,821.9 ***20,389.3 ***
AR(1)−1.038−1.041−1.050−1.006−1.044
AR(2)−1.149−1.247−1.315−1.094−1.195
Notes: Variables are described in Appendix A Table A1. *, **, *** Significant at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Costa, M.; Lisboa, I.; Marzinzik, R. Is Additional CEO Remuneration a Performance Driver? DAX CEOs Evidence. Risks 2023, 11, 133. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11070133

AMA Style

Costa M, Lisboa I, Marzinzik R. Is Additional CEO Remuneration a Performance Driver? DAX CEOs Evidence. Risks. 2023; 11(7):133. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11070133

Chicago/Turabian Style

Costa, Magali, Inês Lisboa, and René Marzinzik. 2023. "Is Additional CEO Remuneration a Performance Driver? DAX CEOs Evidence" Risks 11, no. 7: 133. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11070133

APA Style

Costa, M., Lisboa, I., & Marzinzik, R. (2023). Is Additional CEO Remuneration a Performance Driver? DAX CEOs Evidence. Risks, 11(7), 133. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks11070133

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop