Next Article in Journal
Optimal Stopping and Utility in a Simple Modelof Unemployment Insurance
Previous Article in Journal
Drivers of Old-Age Dependence and Long-Term Care Usage in Switzerland—A Structural Equation Model Approach
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Nash Bargaining Over Margin Loans to Kelly Gamblers

Department of Economics, School of Public and Global Affairs, College of Liberal Arts and Sciences, Northern Illinois University, 514 Zulauf Hall, DeKalb, IL 60115, USA
Risks 2019, 7(3), 93; https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7030093
Submission received: 26 July 2019 / Revised: 15 August 2019 / Accepted: 20 August 2019 / Published: 27 August 2019

Abstract

:
I derive practical formulas for optimal arrangements between sophisticated stock market investors (continuous-time Kelly gamblers or, more generally, CRRA investors) and the brokers who lend them cash for leveraged bets on a high Sharpe asset (i.e., the market portfolio). Rather than, say, the broker posting a monopoly price for margin loans, the gambler agrees to use a greater quantity of margin debt than he otherwise would in exchange for an interest rate that is lower than the broker would otherwise post. The gambler thereby attains a higher asymptotic capital growth rate and the broker enjoys a greater rate of intermediation profit than would be obtained under non-cooperation. If the threat point represents a complete breakdown of negotiations (resulting in zero margin loans), then we get an elegant rule of thumb: r L * = 3 / 4 r + 1 / 4 ν σ 2 / 2 , where r is the broker’s cost of funds, ν is the compound-annual growth rate of the market index, and σ is the annual volatility. We show that, regardless of the particular threat point, the gambler will negotiate to size his bets as if he himself could borrow at the broker’s call rate.

1. Introduction

Harry Markowitz’ fundamental mean–variance theory (Markowitz 1952) of investment transforms the n-dimensional portfolio hyperplane into his trademark (two-dimensional) mean–variance plane. Even better, the Markowitz bullet gives us a one-dimensional frontier of efficient portfolios that yield the greatest possible reward for any given level of risk. Given the freedom to borrow and lend cash, we need only focus on a single fund of risky assets that gives the greatest reward per unit of risk; the curvature of the Markowitz bullet is thereby replaced by the straightness of the capital market line. However, the theory ends there; the practitioner receives no further prescription than to just borrow and buy as many shares of the tangency portfolio as is permitted by his particular appetite for risk.
This lack of guidance in one-dimensional gambling problems was acutely felt by card-counter Edward O. Thorp, who required an appropriate criterion for sizing his bets in certain favorable situations (Thorp 1996) that he found at the Nevada blackjack tables (cf. his 2017 autobiography (Thorp 2017)). The correct answer (“Fortune’s Formula”, Poundstone 2010) is called the Kelly criterion, after Kelly (1956), a physicist at Bell Labs. As was the custom in statistical communication theory, Kelly started with a simple example that turned out to be typical of the whole situation. He considered a long sequence of independent bets on horse races, whereby the gambler knows the (stationary) win probabilities to more precision than the posted (even) odds. This illuminating environment led him to formulate the concept of a fixed-fraction betting scheme, whereby the gambler bets the same fraction of his wealth on each race. His famous criterion singles out the fixed-fraction betting scheme (or “Kelly bet”) that generates the highest possible asymptotic per-bet capital growth rate. In blackjack, say, the Kelly fraction is b * : = p q , where p is the chance of winning the next hand and q is the chance of losing. For instance, if you have a p : = 50.5 % chance of winning the next hand, the criterion dictates that you should bet 1 % of your net worth at even odds.
Kelly’s theory extends easily to Black and Scholes (1973) markets, whereby the asset price S t follows a geometric Brownian motion. In this environment, the gambler “bets” the fixed fraction b of his wealth on the stock over each differential time step [ t , t + d t ] . Apart from the fact that we now have a continuum of possible profit-and-loss outcomes
d S t : = S t × μ d t + σ d W t
d log S t = μ σ 2 2 d t + σ d W t ,
the correct behavior is governed by substantially the same logic (cf. Garivaltis 2018, 2019a, 2019b, 2019c; Ordentlich and Cover 1998) since the random fluctuations d W t : = ϵ × d t are identically (normally) distributed and independent across time.
It is well known (cf. Thorp 2006) that the Kelly bet for this market is
b * = μ r σ 2 = 1 2 + ν r σ 2 ,
where ν : = μ σ 2 / 2 is the expected geometric growth rate of the asset price and r is the interest rate at which the gambler can borrow and lend. If we take r : = 2.44 % (which is the one-month U.S. treasury yield as of this writing) along with some stylized parameters ( ν : = 0.09 , σ : = 0.15 ) meant to represent the behavior of the S&P 500 index, we get b * = 3.42 . That is, if the gambler himself had the opportunity to borrow at the risk-free rate, he would borrow $ 2.42 for every dollar of his own equity.
The author presently borrows from Interactive Brokers at a rate of 3.9 % compounded annually1, or 3.83 % compounded continuously, which corresponds to b = 2.8 . However, for a client that is borrowing more than $ 3 million, the rate changes to 2.7 % compounded annually, or 2.66 % compounded continuously, with a corresponding Kelly bet of 3.32 . All of this is illustrated in Table 1, which gives Interactive Brokers’ pricing schedule for U.S. dollar margin loans as of 12 March 2019.

Contribution

Taking our inspiration from this broker–client relationship (which is both real and ongoing), we formulate and solve a Nash (1950) bargaining problem between a stock broker (that can borrow cash on the money market at the broker call rate, r) and a continuous time Kelly gambler (or, more generally, a CRRA investor) to whom the broker issues margin loans at a marked-up interest rate r L > r . The present situation for U.S. retail consumers of margin loans is just this: the broker posts a price r ¯ L (presumably a monopoly price), and the Kelly gambler (i.e., the author) responds by demanding the corresponding growth-optimal quantity q ¯ of margin loans per dollar of account equity. The corresponding Kelly bet is then b ¯ : = q ¯ + 1 . These choices lead to a definite (logarithmic) capital growth rate of Γ ¯ for the gambler and a definite profit rate π ¯ for the broker.
Obviously, the principals should cooperate, if possible, and negotiate a margin loan contract b * , r L * that jointly specifies the interest rate, the client’s portfolio, and the quantity of margin loans to be issued over the differential time step t , t + d t . It would thereby be possible to convert the deadweight loss of monopoly into some agreed upon surplus values Γ * Γ ¯ and π * π ¯ . We show that, regardless of the disagreement point π ¯ , Γ ¯ , the client will negotiate to bet as if he himself had the opportunity to borrow at the broker’s cost of funds. We derive exact formulas for the efficient profit-growth frontier, the negotiated behavior b * , r L * , and the final utilities π * , Γ * obtained from Nash’s cooperation scheme. We show that the efficient frontier is a straight line (whose slope is 1 ), and therefore our bargaining problem is one of transferable utility (cf. Mas-Colell et al. 1995). We find that the Nash bargaining solution given here coincides with the Egalitarian solution, whereby all surplus value gained from cooperation is shared equally; the correct outcome π * , Γ * on the profit-growth frontier is found by intersecting it with a 45° line emanating from the threat point π ¯ , Γ ¯ .

2. Definitions and Notation

As indicated above, we consider a Black and Scholes (1973) market with a single risk asset (i.e., the S&P 500 index) whose price S t follows the geometric Brownian motion
d S t S t : = μ d t + σ d W t ,
where μ is the annual drift rate, σ is the volatility, and W t is a standard Brownian motion. We consider a broker that makes margin loans at a continuously-compounded interest rate of r L per year, and whose cost of funds (“broker call rate”) is denoted by r. The broker makes these loans to a continuous-time Kelly (1956) gambler (cf. Luenberger 1998) whose behavior is characterized by the fact that he continuously maintains some fixed level b of exposure to the risk asset. That is, the gambler continuously maintains the fraction b of his wealth in the stock; if b > 1 , then he continuously maintains a margin (debit) balance in the amount of b 1 of his wealth. For instance, if b : = 1.5 , then the gambler’s margin loan balance would be continuously adjusted so as to constitute 50 % of his wealth. We let V t ( b ) denote the gambler’s wealth process, where V 0 is some given initial wealth. The (dollar) quantity of margin loans demanded is q : = b 1 V t ( b ) . The broker’s instantaneous rate of profit per year is π b , r L : = r L r q = r L r b 1 V t ( b ) , where r L r is the net interest margin.
We assume that the client’s objective is to maximize the almost-sure continuously-compounded asymptotic growth rate of his capital, i.e., Γ : = lim t 1 / t log V t ( b ) / V 0 . As shown here (cf. Luenberger 1998), this is equivalent to maximizing the drift of log V t ( b ) . The gambler’s fortune evolves according to
d V t ( b ) V t ( b ) = b d S t S t ( b 1 ) r L d t = r L + ( μ r L ) b d t + b σ d W t .
Since the gambler’s fortune follows a geometric Brownian motion, one can apply Itô’s Lemma (cf. Wilmott 2001) to obtain the relation
d log V t ( b ) = r L + μ r L b σ 2 2 b 2 d t + b σ d W t ,
or, equivalently,
V t ( b ) = V 0 × exp r L + b μ r L σ 2 2 b 2 t + b σ W t .
Accordingly, the gambler’s asymptotic growth rate is denoted
Γ b , r L :
Γ b , r L : = r L + b μ r L σ 2 2 b 2 = lim t log V t ( b ) / V 0 t = E d log V t ( b ) d t .

3. Nash Bargaining

In what follows, we assume that at every instant t, the broker and the Kelly gambler will Nash bargain (Nash 1950) over the margin loan arrangement b , r L , which simultaneously specifies the quantity of margin loans q = b 1 V t and the interest rate r L that will be charged by the broker over the differential time step t , t + d t . We let π ¯ , Γ ¯ : = π b ¯ , r ¯ L , Γ b ¯ , r ¯ L denote the threat point, meaning that a breakdown in negotiations will lead to the broker charging r ¯ L and to the gambler betting the fraction b ¯ of his wealth on the stock over t , t + d t . Non-cooperation would thereby lead to a profit rate of π ¯ = π b ¯ , r ¯ L for the broker and a growth rate of Γ ¯ = Γ b ¯ , r ¯ L for the gambler.
Example 1.
Rather than cooperate, the broker posts a take-it-or-leave-it price r L r , and the client chooses the corresponding Kelly bet (or log-optimal portfolio)
b * r L : = μ r L σ 2 = arg max b 1 Γ b , r L ,
where we must assume that μ σ 2 r L r in order to guarantee that the client will take a margin loan. This means that the risk asset must be sufficiently favorable (high drift and low volatility) in relation to the cost of funds, and also the interest rate r L must be sufficiently low that the client does not choose b = 1 . The quantity of margin loans (per dollar of client equity) is
q = μ r L σ 2 1 ,
the broker’s instantaneous rate of profit per unit time is
π ¯ = μ r L σ 2 1 r L r ,
and, after simplification, the gambler’s asymptotic capital growth rate is
Γ ¯ = r L + 1 2 μ r L σ 2 .
Example 2.
After a complete breakdown of negotiations, the broker does not even offer the client a margin loan (say, r L : = , or the client refuses to take a loan). Thus, the client just buys and holds the stock ( b = 1 , q = 0 , π ¯ = 0 ), achieving an asymptotic growth rate of Γ ¯ = μ σ 2 / 2 .
Note that the total non-cooperation of Example 2 is not a credible threat (e.g., it is not subgame-perfect), because, if the broker posts a reasonable price (as in Example 1), then the investor will optimally choose to borrow to the extent possible.
Naturally, a negotiated contract has the potential to make both parties better off: the client will agree to use more margin debt in exchange for a lower interest rate. The contract will be arranged just so; the gambler achieves a higher asymptotic growth rate on account of the lower r L and the broker achieves a higher rate of profit on account of the increased b.
The Nash product (cf. Nash 1950) is equal to
N b , r L : = π b , r L π ¯ × Γ b , r L Γ ¯ ,
and the Nash bargaining solution is equal to
b * , r L * : = arg max b 1 , r L r N b , r L .
Note that, since π , is directly proportional to V t ( b ) , any Nash bargain that is struck for the duration of the differential time step t , t + d t will be independent of the client’s wealth level V t ( b ) ; the negotiated behavior b * , r L * depends only on the GBM parameters μ , σ , the broker’s cost of funds (r), and the threat point π ¯ , Γ ¯ 2.
We should stress the fact that, although the client’s welfare is measured in terms of his asymptotic almost sure capital growth rate (which is equal to his instantaneous expected compound-growth rate), the broker’s welfare is measured by its instantaneous rate of intermediation profit per dollar of client equity. Because this profit amounts to a fixed percentage of the client’s wealth (e.g., the net interest margin times the client’s debt-to-equity ratio), the asymptotic growth rate of the broker’s fee income is in fact equal to client’s long run capital growth rate, Γ .
The first-order condition N / r L = 0 simplifies to
Γ b , r L Γ ¯ = π b , r L π ¯ ,
e.g., the asymptotic growth rate that the gambler gains from cooperation must be equal to the rate of profit (per dollar of client equity) that the broker gains relative to the threat point. Taking the other first-order condition N / b = 0 and using (15) to simplify, we get
Proposition 1.
Under Nash bargaining, regardless of the threat point, the Kelly gambler will bet the fraction
b * = μ r σ 2 ,
e.g., he will negotiate to bet as if he himself could borrow at the broker’s call rate, r.
Note that the negotiated bet size b * = μ r / σ 2 amounts to a special case of the usual Merton strategy b : = ( μ r ) / ( γ σ 2 ) (cf. Merton 1969, 1990) that obtains for an investor with CRRA utility
u ( x ) : = x 1 γ 1 / 1 γ if γ > 0 and γ 1 log x if γ = 1 ,
where γ x · u ( x ) / u ( x ) denotes the investor’s (constant) coefficient of relative risk aversion. Substituting this value of b into Equation (15), solving, and simplifying, we get
Theorem 1.
The negotiated interest rate under Nash bargaining is given by the formula
r L * = r 2 + μ 2 r 2 2 σ 2 Γ ¯ π ¯ 4 μ σ 2 r .
Example 3.
Under total non-cooperation ( π ¯ = 0 and Γ ¯ = μ σ 2 / 2 ), after factoring and simplifying, we get
r L * = μ + 3 r σ 2 4 = 3 4 r + 1 4 ν σ 2 2 ,
where ν : = μ σ 2 / 2 is the asymptotic growth rate of the asset price S t . The broker’s rate of profit is
π = μ σ 2 r 2 σ 2 .
Example 4.
For the parameters σ : = 15 , r : = 3 % , ν : = 9 % , μ : = ν + σ 2 / 2 , the continuous-time Kelly rule is b * = 3.17 . The negotiated interest rate is r L * = 4.2 % , the net interest margin is 1.2 % , and the gambler achieves an asymptotic continuously-compounded growth rate of Γ * = 12 % per year. The broker earns instantaneous margin loan profits at a rate of π * = 2.6 % of the client’s equity per year.

Utility Possibility Frontier

In this subsection, we derive the utility possibility frontier, e.g., we calculate the maximum possible growth rate Γ that is (cooperatively) achievable for a given profit rate π . Solving for r L in terms of π , we get
r L = r + π b 1 .
Substituting this expression into the formula for Γ , we get, after simplification,
Γ = r + μ r b σ 2 2 b 2 π .
Maximizing with respect to b, we obtain b * = μ r / σ 2 . Substituting back into Equation (23) and simplifying, we get the (linear) equation of the efficient growth-profit frontier:
Γ = r + 1 2 μ r σ 2 π .
Juxtaposing Equation (23) with the egalitarian condition Γ Γ ¯ = π π ¯ , we obtain the fact that the final utilities under Nash bargaining are
π * = r Γ ¯ π ¯ 2 + 1 4 μ r σ 2
and
Γ * = r + Γ ¯ π ¯ 2 + 1 4 μ r σ 2 .

4. Monopoly Threat Point

Remembering that we have normalized the gambler’s fortune to $ 1 , the broker faces the demand curve
q r L = b r L 1 = μ σ 2 1 1 σ 2 × r L .
The corresponding inverse demand (or marginal value) curve is r L ( q ) = μ σ 2 σ 2 q , and the marginal revenue curve is MR ( q ) = μ σ 2 2 σ 2 q . The instantaneous price elasticity of demand for margin loans is
ϵ d ( q ) = r L q × d q d r L = μ σ 2 σ 2 q 1 .
Equating the broker’s marginal revenue to the marginal cost r of funding, we obtain the monopoly quantity
q M = μ σ 2 r 2 σ 2 .
Substituting this quantity into the inverse demand curve, we get the familiar monopoly midpoint pricing rule:
r M = μ σ 2 + r 2 .
That is, the monopoly price of margin loans is equal to the average of the choke point μ σ 2 and the broker call rate r. Thus, under the monopoly threat point, the continuous-time Kelly gambler will bet the fraction
b M = q M + 1 = μ + σ 2 r 2 σ 2
of wealth on the risk asset over t , t + d t . Given its net interest margin of r M r = μ σ 2 r / 2 , the broker’s instantaneous rate of intermediation profit per dollar of client equity is
π M = r M r q M = μ σ r 2 σ 2 ,
and the gambler’s asymptotic capital growth rate under the monopoly market structure is
Γ M = Γ b M , r M = μ σ 2 + r 2 + 1 8 μ + σ 2 r σ 2 .
Consumer surplus flows to the Kelly gambler at a continuous rate of
CS = 1 8 μ σ 2 r σ 2
per unit time. From the symmetry of the monopoly midpoint, the deadweight loss per unit time is equal to the consumer surplus:
DWL = CS = 1 8 μ σ 2 r σ 2 .
Example 5.
For the parameters ν : = 0.09 , σ : = 0.15 , μ : = ν + σ 2 / 2 , r : = 0.03 , the monopoly price of margin debt is r M = 5.44 % , and the gambler correspondingly would demand q M = 1.083 dollars of margin loans per dollar of his account equity, for a total bet of b M = 2.0833 . The gambler thereby achieves an asymptotic capital growth rate of Γ ¯ = 10.32 % and the broker earns intermediation profits at annual rate of π ¯ = 2.64 % of client equity. This monopoly behavior is illustrated in Figure 1.
Under cooperation (relative to this threat point), the gambler ups his bet to b * = 3.17 and the broker lowers his interest rate to r L * = 4.52 % . This raises the gambler’s growth rate to 10.98 % and it raises the broker’s profit rate to 3.3 % . Thus, the annual rate of deadweight loss (in the amount of 1.32 % of account equity) has been converted to surplus value and shared equally between the counterparties: Γ Γ ¯ = π π ¯ = 0.66 % . This cooperative behavior is illustrated in Figure 2.

5. Several Risk Assets

In this section, we proceed to extend our main techniques and results to the general stock market with n correlated risk assets ( i : = 1 , 2 , , n ) in geometric Brownian motion. Let S i t denote the price of stock i at time t, where
d S i t S i t : = μ i d t + σ i d W i t .
μ i is the drift of stock i, σ i is its volatility, and the W i t i = 1 n are correlated unit Brownian motions. On that score, we let ρ i j : = Corr d W i t , d W j t , and we let
σ i j : = ρ i j σ i σ j = Cov d S i t S i t , d S j t S j t / d t
denote the covariance of instantaneous returns per unit time. In what follows, we let μ : = μ 1 , , μ n denote the drift vector of the stock market, and we assume that the covariance matrix Σ : = σ i j n × n is invertible. In this generality, a continuously-rebalanced portfolio (or fixed-fraction betting scheme) is defined by a vector b : = b 1 , , b n R n of portfolio weights, where the intention is to continuously execute rebalancing trades so as to maintain the fixed fraction b i of wealth in stock i at all times. As usual, we let V t ( b ) denote the gambler’s fortune at time t; the instantaneous quantity of margin loans demanded therefore amounts to
q = i = 1 n b i 1 V t ( b ) = 1 b 1 V t ( b ) ,
or just q = 1 b 1 per dollar of client equity, where 1 : = 1 , , 1 is an n × 1 vector of ones. The broker’s instantaneous rate of intermediation profit is now π = 1 b 1 r L r per dollar of client equity. The evolution of the gambler’s fortune is now governed by the stochastic differential equation
d V t ( b ) V t ( b ) : = i = 1 n b i d S i t S i t 1 b 1 r L d t = r L + μ r L 1 b d t + i = 1 n b i σ i d W i t .
Applying Itô’s Lemma for several diffusion processes (cf. Wilmott 1998), we obtain the fact that
d log V t ( b ) = r L + μ r L 1 b 1 2 b Σ b d t + i = 1 n b i σ i d W i t ,
which, upon integration, yields
V t ( b ) = V 0 × exp r L + μ r L 1 b 1 2 b Σ b t + i = 1 n b i σ i W i t .
In this connection, the gambler’s continuously-compounded asymptotic capital growth rate is now
Γ b , r L : = r L + μ r L 1 b 1 2 b Σ b = lim t log V t ( b ) / V 0 t = E d log V t ( b ) d t .
Proceeding as before, the correct behavior is obtained by optimizing the Nash product N b , r L :
b * , r L * : = arg max 1 b 1 , r L r π π ¯ Γ Γ ¯ .
Using the product rule to calculate N / r L , we obtain
1 1 b π π ¯ + Γ Γ ¯ 1 b 1 = 0 .
Assuming interiority ( 1 b > 1 ) , we cancel the common factor q = 1 b 1 and again obtain the egalitarian condition Γ Γ ¯ = π π ¯ . Using the product rule to calculate the gradient b N of the Nash product with respect to b, we get the (vector) condition
π π ¯ μ r L 1 Σ b + Γ ¯ Γ r L r 1 = 0 .
Assuming that there are gains to be had from cooperation (meaning that π π ¯ and Γ Γ ¯ are both positive numbers), we cancel this common factor and simplify to obtain
b * = Σ 1 μ r 1 .
As expected, this is precisely the behavior of a continuous time Kelly gambler (cf. with Luenberger 1998) who is permitted to borrow cash at the broker’s call rate, r. Using this fact in conjunction with the egalitarian condition and the defining expressions for Γ and π , one calculates the negotiated interest rate to be
r L * = r 2 + μ Σ 1 μ r 2 · 1 Σ 1 1 2 Γ ¯ π ¯ 4 1 Σ 1 μ r 1 1 ,
which is in perfect accord with Equation (18).
Taking our cue from the univariate case, we can derive the (linear) efficient Γ π frontier in just the same way. For a given rate π of intermediation profit, we solve for r L and obtain
r L = r + π 1 b 1 .
Substituting this expression into the definition of Γ , one has, after simplification,
Γ = r + μ r 1 b 1 2 b Σ b π .
Maximizing b out of this expression, we obtain b * = Σ 1 μ r 1 ; the general equation of the efficient frontier is
Γ = r + 1 2 μ r 1 Σ 1 μ r 1 π .
The final utility vector Γ * , π * that obtains from Nash bargaining therefore lies at the intersection of the efficient frontier in Equation (49) and the line Γ = Γ ¯ π ¯ + π , which expresses the egalitarian division of surplus value. Solving these simultaneous equations, we get
Γ * = r + Γ ¯ π ¯ 2 + 1 4 μ r 1 Σ 1 μ r 1
and
π * = r Γ ¯ π ¯ 2 + 1 4 μ r 1 Σ 1 μ r 1 .

5.1. Monopoly Disagreement Point

If negotiations break down and the broker simply posts a price r L , then the gambler will react with the corresponding Kelly rule, namely, b ( r L ) = Σ 1 μ r L 1 . Thus, the broker faces the instantaneous demand curve
q ( r L ) = 1 b ( r L ) 1 = 1 Σ 1 μ 1 1 Σ 1 1 r L .
The instantaneous elasticity of demand for margin loans is therefore given by
ϵ d ( q ) = 1 Σ 1 μ 1 q 1 .
The inverse demand (or marginal value) curve is
r L = MV ( q ) = 1 Σ 1 μ 1 1 Σ 1 1 1 1 Σ 1 1 × q ,
which induces the marginal revenue curve
MR ( q ) = 1 Σ 1 μ 1 1 Σ 1 1 2 1 Σ 1 1 × q .
Intersecting marginal revenue with marginal cost (which is MC ( q ) : r ), we get the monopoly quantity
q M = 1 Σ 1 μ 1 r · 1 Σ 1 1 2 .
Reading off the inverse demand curve, the monopoly interest rate is now
r M = 1 2 1 Σ 1 μ 1 1 Σ 1 1 + r .
Exact formulas for all remaining quantities of interest, such as the consumer surplus, the deadweight loss, and the profit and growth rates that would obtain under the monopoly threat point, all follow in the obvious way from the monopoly price and quantity given above, just as they did in the univariate case.

5.2. General Solution for CRRA Utility

To close the paper, we indicate briefly how our results can be (easily) extended for the benefit of arbitrary CRRA investors, e.g., those whose preferences over terminal wealth can be represented by the isoelastic utility function u ( x ) : = x 1 γ , where γ > 0 is the agent’s (constant) coefficient of relative risk aversion.
Applying Itô’s Lemma, one can calculate that (for γ 1 ) the continuously rebalanced portfolio b : = b 1 , , b n R n generates the the following law of motion for the investor’s utility V t ( b ) 1 γ :
1 γ 1 d V t ( b ) 1 γ V t ( b ) 1 γ = r L + ( μ r L 1 ) b γ 2 b Σ b d t + i = 1 n b i σ i d W i t .
Thus, the “growth rate” Γ now takes the form
Γ b , r L : = r L + μ r L 1 b γ 2 b Σ b = 1 γ 1 E t d V t ( b ) 1 γ V t ( b ) 1 γ / d t ,
e.g., Γ b , r L is directly proportional to the expected percent change in (power) utility per unit time over the differential time step t , t + d t .
De facto, then, the only formal change in the model is that the covariance matrix Σ has been replaced by γ Σ ; in the univariate case this means, e.g., that the variance σ 2 must everywhere be replaced by γ σ 2 . Thus, the investor negotiates to use the continuously-rebalanced portfolio b * = 1 / γ Σ 1 μ r 1 , where r is the broker’s cost of funds. The equilibrium interest rate now amounts to
r L * = r 2 + μ Σ 1 μ r 2 · 1 Σ 1 1 2 γ Γ ¯ π ¯ 4 1 Σ 1 μ r 1 γ .
The efficient frontier in the π , Γ -plane is now given by the equation
Γ = r + 1 2 γ μ r 1 Σ 1 μ r 1 π ,
so that phenomenon of transferable utility is preserved for general CRRA investors.
In parting, we note that the stock market parameters μ , Σ must be assumed to be sufficiently favorable (and the penalty parameters r , γ must be sufficiently low) that the investor is at least willing to borrow money at the broker’s own cost of funds; this means that the deep parameters μ , Σ , r , γ must satisfy the inequality
1 Σ 1 μ r 1 > γ .

6. Summary and Conclusions

This paper studies negotiated margin loan contracts between continuous time Kelly gamblers (more generally, CRRA investors) and the brokers who lend them cash to make large bets on high-growth assets or portfolios. On account of the continuous sample path of asset prices, the broker bears no risk of default, as it can in principle liquidate the client’s assets at the very instant his account equity is equal to zero. In the Black–Scholes market consisting of several correlated stocks in geometric Brownian motion, the gambler’s fortune itself follows a geometric Brownian motion, and therefore remains positive until the hereafter. A margin loan quantity of q : = 1 b 1 per dollar of client equity is made for the duration of the differential time step t , t + d t , after which interest is debited and the size of the loan is readjusted on account of the observed fluctuation d V t ( b ) of the gambler’s bankroll.
All potential cooperation between these counterparties rests on the fact that the market admits assets (or continuously-rebalanced portfolios of said assets) whose asymptotic growth rate is significantly higher than the broker’s call rate, r. The broker, who charges margin interest at a continuous rate of r L > r , seeks an arrangement whereby his instantaneous rate of intermediation profit, namely π : = 1 b 1 r L r per dollar of client equity, is as high as possible. The Kelly gambler, who is notoriously far sighted (cf. MacLean et al. 2011), is willing to stomach any level of volatility, value-at-risk, or maximum drawdown in exchange for the highest possible asymptotic capital growth rate, here denoted Γ : = r L + μ r L 1 b b Σ b / 2 . In an evolutionary sense, the broker must treat his Kelly gamblers with kid gloves, for they will hold asymptotically 100 % of the equity on deposit, and (on account of their fixed leverage ratio) they will shoulder 100 % of all margin debt in the limit.
If the broker and the Kelly gambler fail to come to terms (that would simultaneously specify the interest rate, the portfolio, and the quantity of margin loans), then there are two obvious ways the disagreement could play out. In the worst scenario, the Kelly gambler borrows no cash at all (or the broker does not lend him any); the broker’s intermediation profit is zero and the client makes do with optimizing his growth rate over the set of unlevered continuously-rebalanced portfolios (e.g., he is constrained by the condition 1 b = 1 ). The second possibility is the one that seems to actually obtain in this world: the broker just posts a monopoly price r M , and the gambler then demands the corresponding monopoly quantity q M of margin loans as dictated by his instantaneous demand curve.
Following Nash’s (1950) theory of axiomatic bargaining, we maximized the Nash product N : = π π ¯ × Γ Γ ¯ over the profit-growth plane of points π , Γ π ¯ , Γ ¯ ; the factors of this product are the respective surplus values extracted by the counterparies from cooperation as opposed to disagreement, which only yields meager levels π ¯ , Γ ¯ of utility. We found that, regardless of the threat point π ¯ , Γ ¯ , the gambler will negotiate to bet as if he himself could borrow money at the broker’s (low) cost of funds. On account of the egalitarian (first-order) condition Γ Γ ¯ = π π ¯ , the surplus value from cooperation will in any event be divided evenly between the counterparties. We used this fact to derive exact formulas for the negotiated interest rate r L * and the final utilities π * , Γ * that obtain from cooperation. Finally, we derived an expression for the efficient frontier in the profit-growth plane: it is a straight line (whose slope is 1 ), meaning that our particular bargaining problem enjoys the special property of transferable utility (cf. Myerson 1997). Geometrically, the negotiated outcome π * , Γ * is the result of intersecting the efficient frontier with a 45° line emanating from the threat point π ¯ , Γ ¯ .

Funding

This work was supported by the Open Access Publishing Fund at Northern Illinois University, which is administered by the University Libraries and funded by the College of Liberal Arts and Sciences, Research and Innovation Partnerships (RIPS), and the University Libraries.

Acknowledgments

I thank Omri Tal, Nero Tulip, and several anonymous referees for helpful comments, discussions, and suggestions that improved the paper.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares that he has no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Black, Fischer, and Myron Scholes. 1973. The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy 81: 637–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Garivaltis, Alex. 2018. Game-Theoretic Optimal Portfolios in Continuous Time. Economic Theory Bulletin, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Garivaltis, Alex. 2019a. Game-Theoretic Optimal Portfolios for Jump Diffusions. Games 10: 8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Garivaltis, Alex. 2019b. Exact Replication of the Best Rebalancing Rule in Hindsight. The Journal of Derivatives 26: 35–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Garivaltis, Alex. 2019c. Cover’s Rebalancing Option with Discrete Hindsight Optimization. Working Paper. DeKalb, IL, USA: Northern Illinois University. [Google Scholar]
  6. Kelly, John L. 1956. A New Interpretation of Information Rate. Bell System Technical Journal 35: 917–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Luenberger, David G. 1998. Investment Science. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  8. MacLean, Leonard C., Edward O. Thorp, and William T. Ziemba. 2011. The Kelly Capital Growth Investment Criterion: Theory and Practice. Hackensack: World Scientific. [Google Scholar]
  9. Markowitz, Harry. 1952. Portfolio Selection. The Journal of Finance 7: 77–91. [Google Scholar]
  10. Mas-Colell, Andreu, Michael Dennis Whinston, and Jerry R. Green. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  11. Merton, Robert C. 1969. Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case. The Review of Economics and Statistics 51: 247–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Merton, Robert C. 1990. Continuous Time Finance. Cambridge: Basil Blackwell. [Google Scholar]
  13. Myerson, Roger B. 1997. Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
  14. Nash, John F. 1950. The Bargaining Problem. Econometrica 18: 155–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ordentlich, Erik, and Thomas M. Cover. 1998. The Cost of Achieving the Best Portfolio in Hindsight. Mathematics of Operations Research 23: 960–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Poundstone, William. 2010. Fortune’s Formula: The Untold Story of the Scientific Betting System that Beat the Casinos and Wall Street. New York: Hill and Wang. [Google Scholar]
  17. Thorp, Edward O. 1966. Beat the Dealer: A Winning Strategy for the Game of Twenty One. New York: Random House. [Google Scholar]
  18. Thorp, Edward O. 2006. The Kelly Criterion in Blackjack, Sports Betting, and the Stock Market. In Handbook of Asset and Liability Management. Amsterdam: North-Holland, Volume 2. [Google Scholar]
  19. Thorp, Edward O. 2017. A Man for all Markets: From Las Vegas to Wall Street, How I Beat the Dealer and the Market. New York: Random House. [Google Scholar]
  20. Wilmott, Paul. 1998. Derivatives: The Theory and Practice of Financial Engineering. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. [Google Scholar]
  21. Wilmott, Paul. 2001. Paul Wilmott Introduces Quantitative Finance. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons. [Google Scholar]
1
This was on 12 March 2019. The rate has dropped since then, to 3.62% as of 13 August 2019.
2
The principals are assumed to re-negotiate the margin loan contract after every differential tick d t of the market clock. However, the Nash bargaining solution never actually changes, on account of the fact that the Nash product is directly proportional to the client’s wealth V t ( b ) .
Figure 1. Kelly gambler’s instantaneous demand for margin loans per dollar of account equity, ν : = 0.09 , σ : = 0.15 , μ : = ν + σ 2 / 2 , r : = 0.03 .
Figure 1. Kelly gambler’s instantaneous demand for margin loans per dollar of account equity, ν : = 0.09 , σ : = 0.15 , μ : = ν + σ 2 / 2 , r : = 0.03 .
Risks 07 00093 g001
Figure 2. Gains from cooperation under Nash bargaining, ν : = 0.09 , σ : = 0.15 , μ : = ν + σ 2 / 2 , r : = 0.03 .
Figure 2. Gains from cooperation under Nash bargaining, ν : = 0.09 , σ : = 0.15 , μ : = ν + σ 2 / 2 , r : = 0.03 .
Risks 07 00093 g002
Table 1. Margin loan interest rates (for U.S. dollars) at Interactive Brokers, 12 March 2019.
Table 1. Margin loan interest rates (for U.S. dollars) at Interactive Brokers, 12 March 2019.
TierInterest Rate log ( 1 + Interest Rate ) Kelly Bet, b
0–100,0003.9%3.83%2.8
100,000.01–1,000,0003.4%3.34%3.01
1,000,000.01–3,000,0002.9%2.86%3.23
3,000,000.01–200,000,0002.7%2.66%3.32

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Garivaltis, A. Nash Bargaining Over Margin Loans to Kelly Gamblers. Risks 2019, 7, 93. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7030093

AMA Style

Garivaltis A. Nash Bargaining Over Margin Loans to Kelly Gamblers. Risks. 2019; 7(3):93. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7030093

Chicago/Turabian Style

Garivaltis, Alex. 2019. "Nash Bargaining Over Margin Loans to Kelly Gamblers" Risks 7, no. 3: 93. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7030093

APA Style

Garivaltis, A. (2019). Nash Bargaining Over Margin Loans to Kelly Gamblers. Risks, 7(3), 93. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks7030093

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop