Blue Economy Financing Solutions for the Fisheries and Aquaculture Sectors of Caribbean Island States
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Approach
3. Finance vs. Financing Solutions
3.1. Fiscal Policy for Fisheries and Aquaculture Development
Blue Levies and Stakeholder Taxation
3.2. Compensation Mechanisms for Natural Capital
3.2.1. Biodiversity Offsetting
3.2.2. Carbon and Other Nutrient Trading Credits
3.2.3. Natural Capital as Publicly Traded Equities
3.3. Debt for Nature Swaps and Debt Buy-Backs
3.4. Blue Bonds and Other Sovereign Bonds
3.5. Blue Tokens and FinTech
3.6. Insurance
4. Generating an Enabling Environment for Financing Fisheries and Aquaculture in the Caribbean
4.1. Sustainable Blue Economy Finance Principles
4.2. Integrating Aquaculture and Fisheries into the Greater Blue Economy
4.3. Finance and Financing Coordinating Facility
4.4. Development Tools and Reporting Infrastructure
4.4.1. Screening Tool
4.4.2. Data Reporting and Infrastructure
4.4.3. Spatio-Temporal Planning Tools and Prospective Approaches
4.5. Development of Sustainable Micro, Small, and Medium-Sized Enterprises (MSMEs)
4.6. Public-Private Partnerships (PPP)
4.7. Enabling Policy Environment for Financing
- Facilitates and encourages the use of fiscal policy for sustainable development (Section 3.1)
- Supports the implementation of sustainable Blue Economy principles (Section 4.1)
- Facilitates local and international entrepreneurship
- Supports a mixed economy (with private—and state influence) and encourages free-market environmentalism.
5. Conclusions
- The identification of capacity constraints and development opportunities (in alignment with national development priorities).
- Identification of potential finance and financing mechanisms.
- Analysis of the enabling environment at the national level.
- Matching of suitable finance and financing mechanisms with previously identified financing needs in light of the current enabling environment.
- Review of identified development solutions in light of other sectors’ development prospects.
Author Contributions
Funding
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Financing Instrument | Description | Requirements |
---|---|---|
Fiscal Policy | Fiscal policy covers state spending and the state’s generation of revenues. Budgetary governance is also classified as fiscal policy, and deals with the administrative and institutional systems that control the fiscal flows of the state. Different parts of public fiscal policy can be revenue generators and liabilities at different times, at different levels of organisation. The specific application of fiscal policy thus requires an in-depth understanding of the relevant industry (fisheries and aquaculture) for optimal use as a development mechanism. | |
Environmental Taxes | The minimum definition of an environmental tax is that it increases the costs of pollution activities [19]. An environmental tax is meant to target activities that cause environmental degradation or pollution, but this does not imply that the tax has a proven effect in terms of minimising environmentally degrading or polluting activities. The actual application of an environmental tax is likely to have the effect of incentivising some activities whilst disincentivizing others. | Public awareness Monitoring of pollution among stakeholders (Pollution accounts that track equipment lost at sea for example) Identification of the locus of implementation (individual, organisational, national, regional) Incorporation into legal structure (policy-making) |
Leases, Licences, and fees | Whereas a tax is compulsory, a lease, licence or fee can be seen as a form of exchange between a public authority and a (legal) person, which grants the latter a certain right or privilege. These leases, licences and fees remain stable regardless of the incomes that the payer may generate as a result. | Public awareness. Easy-to-use infrastructure for applications, and issues. Controlled public register of licences and rights issued. Public enforcement mechanism (such as harbour officials checking permits for access to fishing grounds) |
State-owned enterprises (SOEs) and public-private partnerships (PPP) | SOEs are a form of fiscal policy, where SOEs have some clear environmental impacts beyond only service delivery. Public utilities (water and energy companies) explicitly have an environmental aspect since they usually have environmental quality or resource efficiency as key objectives. Other types of SOEs, like transportation companies, may increasingly incorporate environmental objectives. SOEs can be run with a focus on generating profits, but they can also seek to strategically increase public goods and services through their operations. SOEs can be a source of revenue when they generate profits while their inventory and equipment can be seen as capital goods. Meanwhile, SOEs can also hold liabilities in the form of debt. PPPs are a cooperative venture between the public and private sectors, built on the expertise of each partner that best meets clearly defined public needs for services or infrastructure through the transfer between partners of resources, risks and rewards. The aim of PPPs is to structure the relationship between the public and private sectors to allocate the risks to the parties best able to manage them, and to add value to public services by using private sector skills and competencies. However, it is important to make the distinction that PPPs are not incentives or subsidies given by the public sector to attract private investments. Examples applicable to fisheries and aquaculture include organisations that facilitate data recording of fish catches, vessel regulatory bodies specifying monitoring equipment used, fisheries management organisations. | Identification of public needs (at national scale) and natural resources. Transparency in decision-making, operations, and impact to build public trust. Environmental monitoring and accounting. Identification of public needs and subsequent private sector expertise. Public buy-in. Transparency among public and private partners. |
Debt and lending | An enabling environment for debt and lending presents an avenue for fisheries and aquaculture development. As fisheries and aquaculture equipment are often expensive (and become increasingly technical with the incorporation of sustainability objectives), many stakeholders globally make use of loans to develop and expand. An enabling environment such as low interest rates on loans and alternate avenues for debt repayments, may incentivise development in other sectors as well as aquaculture and fisheries. The state of national and global economies (such as recessions) needs to be considered and how this influences the borrowing of money (where in a recession, the borrowing of money is far less likely than in an economic boom/upturn). There is room for public influence (as well as regional organisations like development banks) in this regard to reduce loan and debt repayments through industry financing (subsidies). | Awareness among the industry as to the borrowing options available (through the establishment of coordinated information and development centres) Monitoring the development of the industry. |
Blue levies and stakeholder taxation | Blue levies and stakeholder taxation are similar to environmental taxation, but are not limited to disincentivising pollution. These mechanisms are rather aimed at reinvesting revenue for industry development. These levies are usually applied in different ways, at different rates and at different levels of organisation, like on importation, consumption, accommodation, service, or travel. Sectors that rely on the environments that sustain fisheries and aquaculture or on the sector itself (such as tourism, hospitality, cruise and charter, extraction, and ports and ship-building industries) could be potential targets from which the proceeds of blue levies could be directed to support fisheries and aquaculture. | Transparency Monitoring of stakeholder relationships with the environment and/or fisheries and aquaculture industry. Mechanism or institution to implement, coordinate, and reinvest proceeds according to development needs. |
Payment for Ecosystem Services (PES) Schemes | PES schemes are known by five characteristics [26]: “(1) a voluntary transaction where (2) a well-defined ecosystem service (ES, or a land-use likely to secure that service) (3) is being ‘bought’ by a (minimum one) ES buyer (4) from a (minimum one) ES provider (5) if and only if the ES provider secures ES provision (conditionality)”. PES schemes thus entail the voluntary buying and selling of ecosystem services, based on the seller protecting an ecosystem. Where PES schemes are directly linked to environmental outcomes, levies, fees or licences are not necessarily linked to environmental outcomes, but their proceeds may still be directed to benefiting fisheries and aquaculture (non-environmental benefits). Despite most PES programmes being thought of as a market-based approach, most programmes are based on compliance with government regulations [29]. However, these subsidy-PES programmes are only as good as the (government) authorities that implement them since PES requires enforcement of regulations. Subsidy based PES schemes are potentially more difficult to maintain for cash-strapped governments. A requirement for all PES schemes is accurate environmental monitoring and accounting. | |
Regulated markets | Cap and trade markets require resource users to hold a purchasable right to the resource they use. It sets a limit to resource use and allocates a tradable share of the resource to an asset owner. The rights to the ecosystem or ecosystem service can then be traded (if legal). Ecosystem service can then be exploited on regulated markets (for example, in the form of biodiversity or resilience credits as the measure of ecosystem service delivery). A licence is not necessarily tradable and the issuer of a licence does not necessarily set a limit to damages to an ecosystem, but it still constitutes a transaction based on compliance. | Controlled public register of licences and rights issued. National natural resources can be divided into concession areas which can then be exploited by the private sector on a rotational basis according to who owns the legal right to do so (such as the kelp-harvesting concession areas established in South Africa). Mechanism of access to acquire rights and licences and having this available to anyone. An example is an auctioning mechanism for available national rights to resource exploitation. Enforcement and monitoring of compliance and limitations of approved permits relating to shares of the natural resource (including parties involved with subletting). Requires easy-to-use mechanism. Sophisticated and sufficient legal policy framework regarding (temporary) ownership or rights to national natural resources. |
Voluntary transactions | Voluntary PES transactions can involve private and public sector actors alike. Governments, private individuals, NGOs and development organisations can all pay private actors to change practices or avoid harm to ecosystems. | Platform to identify, mediate and increase awareness of voluntary opportunities available to stakeholders. Requires monitoring of fisheries and aquaculture sectors |
Biodiversity offsetting | Biodiversity offsetting is based on counterbalancing any lost biodiversity from a development project by investing in equivalent biodiversity somewhere else, thus aiming to maintain biodiversity despite economic development (or environmentally harmful extraction processes). If developers follow the mitigation hierarchy (avoidance—minimisation—restoration—offsetts), they should try to avoid negative impacts in the first place, developers should secondly consider the minimising of impacts, thereafter restoring any negative impacts stemming from the development, and finally they can use biodiversity offsets to compensate for the unavoidable biodiversity loss stemming from development projects [33]. Thus, biodiversity offsetting is only meant to counter biodiversity loss that cannot be prevented [34]. Different levels of compensation can be mandated due to the perceived value of the affected (extracted or displaced) species or environment in question. The associated biodiversity loss that is found with unsustainable fishing practices (dredging, trawling), or new aquaculture infrastructure developments, can be offset by investing a portion of the proceeds into less damaging subsectors (domestic handline fisheries, sustenance fisheries or developing restocking programs). | Baseline levels of biodiversity at the sites that provide offsets (sufficient long term data on that area, to assess historical performance or attributes, and where this is not available data would first have to be collected). Mechanism or institution to implement, monitor and coordinate biodiversity offsetting with development needs, with the private sector. |
Carbon and nutrient trading credits | Coastal environments are likely to offer nutrient capture and sequestration services (such as blue carbon) in addition to the benefits they provide to fisheries and aquaculture [5]. Many of the ecosystems that facilitate the generation of carbon and other nutrient trading credits, also provide other co-benefits like nursery/feeding grounds for fish and wave attenuation which contribute to the reliance and longevity of infrastructure along coastlines. These services can be capitalised upon, and leveraged as pollutant offsets (on international and domestic markets) from which revenue can be generated to further support the protection, optimisation, and maintenance of the environments themselves, or be directed towards other areas of fisheries and aquaculture. The conservation and development of the coastal (mangrove) habitats may present an ideal opportunity to access nutrient trading markets (such as the carbon credit market) which can further finance the development of these key ecosystems. | Dependent on environmental monitoring and blue accounting methodologies. Nutrient credit market access (voluntary offset market vs international compliance markets) Finding buyers for credits (can be facilitated by third party organisations). Certification of methods that generate credits by reputable and internationally recognised organisations (increases buyer confidence). Local community involvement and buy-in (as pertains to conservation, and development impact). Legal policy for clear ownership rights of ecosystem service and/or associated credits |
Natural capital as publicly traded equities | The Intrinsic Exchange group (IEG) in collaboration with the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) are pioneering the creation of a new asset class: Natural Asset Companies (NACs). The purpose of such companies is to maximise the performance of the natural asset they are associated with, whether this be through ecosystem services provisioning, restorative/regenerative agricultural use, or hybrid cases integrating both. These companies are evaluated by the IEG, and then listed for trading on world platforms, enabling the conversion of natural assets into financial capital. The sustainable management of the environmental areas that underpin fisheries and aquaculture industries (such as fishing grounds and MPAs) such that the maximum amount/number of benefits are realised is thus incentivised by potentially global markets. | Standardisation of assessment of natural assets. Establishing a baseline of optimal ecosystem performance (need historical data). Awareness raising. Legal policy for clear ownership rights of ecosystem or ecosystem service. |
Debt swaps | A debt swap can be defined as a scenario where a creditor forgives debt owed to them in exchange for a commitment by the debtor to use the outstanding service payments for a particular investment [50]. The redemption of debt can thus be conducted at a discount. The service repayments can be invested into whatever project or initiative is agreeable to both parties in the transaction, such as for fisheries and aquaculture industries or environmental and social based projects. Debt swaps can present an enticing opportunity for the governments of (SIDS) countries hoping to simultaneously facilitate development and reduce the country’s historical debt. However, debt swaps are not explicitly limited to fiscal policy as any private stakeholders can engage with this mechanism assuming mutual agreement to the (legal) terms of the arrangement. | Efficient mechanism or platform for arranging debt swaps. As they are time sensitive (unresolved debt accumulating with time), such a mechanism needs to be quick and easy (this has been a problem with historical national debt swaps and needing to be ratified in parliament first, leading to reduced effectiveness). Composition of sovereign creditors need to all agree on the terms and conditions of the deal. Transparency among parties and in terms of the progress of impact (development) achieved. Involvement and buy-in of local communities for environmental development, are likely to maintain impacts achieved regardless of late repayments or other complications. Consistency in the deal from the government side, regardless of changes in political composition/structure. |
Blue (and other sovereign) Bonds | Blue bonds are “a debt instrument issued by governments, development banks or others to raise capital from impact investors to finance marine and ocean-based projects that have positive environmental, economic and climate benefits” [58]. Using blue bonds as a financing mechanism supports an enabling environment for stimulating the development of a country’s entire Blue Economy, by presenting financial capital to private actors wishing to make sustainable change, at low-risk to investors [60]. When considering a bond issuance, it is critical that the bond structure is fit for purpose (in this case the development of fisheries and aquaculture industries) ensures the highest degree of environmental and social impact, and that the issuer receives the lowest possible interest rates on repayments. Issuances of blue bonds are conducted based on a per-case basis and case specific environmental and economic returns, but generally the criteria for bonds to be considered “blue” require that the investment be used for oceanic or marine resource development. | |
Catastrophe bonds | A trigger level (like the wind speed of a hurricane) for a specific area is determined before the phenomenon occurs. If the trigger level is surpassed, the insurer pays out to the insured party. This bond differs from insurance in that it pays out before the phenomenon has struck, whereas insurance pays out afterwards [4]. Furthermore, no payout is required if the trigger level is not surpassed, but damage may still be widespread because of the phenomenon. | Transparent environmental monitoring. Widely informed and well-established environmental trigger levels. |
Environmental bonds | Environmental bonds raise capital but the return on investment (ROI) is based on the success of an environmental programme or project, as defined by pre-determined key performance indicators (KPIs). In the case of fisheries and aquaculture development, this could be achieving a maximum sustainable yield of a fish stock within a two years for example, or the protection of 20 hectares of mangroves as fish nursery grounds. | Well recorded and documented development progress (as per KPIs). Evidence of longevity/persistence of development (such that any progress does not easily get reversed upon ROI). Timelines of assessments need to be sufficiently long to allow the environment to reflect the development changes (e.g., there may be a lag period involved in a fish stock producing at sustainable max yield, if fishing of the stock has recently been suspended). Examples of specific development options within fisheries and aquaculture may be beneficial for investors to choose from. |
Use-of-proceeds bonds | A use-of-proceeds bond entails the upfront promise that proceeds will be used towards blue development (not necessarily environmental development). These bonds are at risk of “environmental non-performance” where returns as benefits of the environment do not materialise, but the economic returns do [61]. This type of bond may be particularly suitable for the development of fisheries and aquaculture infrastructure (equipment, value addition practices, workspaces, etc.), given that there is no explicit environmental benefit mandated. | Given that no specific environmental benefit is mandated, it may be beneficial to stipulate any development or acquisitions from a use-of proceeds bond that involves some measure of environmental afterthought; e.g., when developing fisheries and aquaculture infrastructure, it could be designed in a (environmentally) sustainable fashion. Transparency in use of proceeds. |
Blue tokens and Fintech | “Fintech” or financial technology, refers to the use of new technology to improve management and access of financial operations and processes. It involves the use of specialised software, algorithms (machine learning), and artificial intelligence to achieve the improved management of finances [15]. Blue tokens is a proposition where fintech and block chain technology are used to raise money for blue (fisheries and aquaculture) development projects [15]. An issuer could set an amount they would like to raise, for example US $10 million with an initial fixed repayment coupon. The initial price of each token could be set at US $10 (predetermined), with one million tokens being issued on a secure blue token market or platform. Any investor who has been approved through rigorous identity checks, like know your client (KYC) and anti money laundering (AML) checks, can then buy tokens and either hold them to maturity or trade them among other investors on the blue token platform. A Blue Economy credit rating agency (alluded to before) could also rate the issuance (initially and later annually) for development outcomes and financial viability, thereby giving investors maximum information to assist with their investment decision [15]. | Technological infrastructure (sufficient computing equipment, stable electric supply, stable internet connection, etc). Stakeholder awareness as to what is available. Digital security. Secure block chain technology and infrastructure. Blue token platform or market. Thorough identity verification (approval). Endorsement/certification would be beneficial (such as through a Blue Economy credit rating agency). |
Insurance | Insurance can create confidence for a potential project developer or investor in that it limits the risks that the project may face, potentially reducing the costs of capital investment. The role of risk management, risk pooling and risk transfer has become important for any potential development in the Caribbean, as the intensity of natural disasters like hurricanes increase [15]. Many different insurance products exist each with their own advantages and potential pitfalls. The demand of high premiums on insurance products are likely to present a barrier of entry to their use in Caribbean SIDS where finance and financing is already in short supply. | Low premiums on insurance incentivise its use in lowering risk for investors. This may be achieved with various forms of fiscal policy (i.e., government support) or regional support (such as from development banks). Awareness among project developers and industry stakeholders. Risk management to be factored into development projects. |
Financing Need | Description | Potential Solutions | Financing Instrument |
---|---|---|---|
Intra-regional trade and domestic market development | A minimal portion of exports from the three countries is traded within the region, while the bulk of exports surpass national imports. It is crucial for these countries to maintain trade with the global market but to reduce vulnerability to external disruptions by boosting intra-Caribbean trade and limiting exports. This approach will help ensure that each country’s nutritional requirements and domestic market demands are fulfilled. | There is a need to simplify the transportation of fish products across borders to promote intra-regional trade. This could be accomplished by consolidating import/export declarations and phytosanitary inspections under a single government or regional agency. Setting a zero percent preferential tariff for intra-regional trade would ensure that fish imports/exports face no restrictions. Implementing a uniform system of conformity assessment procedures for testing, inspecting, and certifying fish products for import/export across all countries would minimize confusion about trade standards and ensure that all products on the market meet legislative and food safety requirements. |
|
Value addition of fish products | The essential factor for maximising profit or gains from fish products is value addition, which also generates employment and foreign currency earnings. Countries need the technology and resources to meet processing, packaging, and marketing demands for target markets. However, this technology is often costly and needs to be imported, increasing the startup costs for developing value addition in Caribbean countries. Government planning should prioritise value addition in seafood value chains by (i) encouraging private investment in seafood value addition through zero-rating imported machinery (ii) recognising the importance of training initiatives for seafood producers to equip them with necessary skills and knowledge for various stages of the value chain (iii) studying, reassessing, and potentially redefining the seafood chain to address bottlenecks and operational challenges (iv) continuing market development and diversification, and (v) establishing information centers to provide operators at various chain nodes with the necessary information for planning and investment decision-making. | The three countries can consider producing ready-to-cook and ready-cooked meals, which are increasingly popular in developed countries. This approach would yield higher prices for their fish products compared to exporting unprocessed fish to American markets or other countries. An example is what Barbados is doing with its tuna sector: making its fishing fleet more efficient and sustainable by providing it with target-selective fishing equipment (also opens itself up to an increasing amount of fast growing markets); and processing tuna before export (e.g., boxed tuna loins). Enhancing value in the tuna sector would better support local hotels and restaurants, retaining more value on the island and reducing reliance on food imports. |
|
Improving ecosystem services delivery | Without healthy ecosystems, fishery resources provisioning declines. The coastal and marine ecosystems around Barbados, Grenada, and St. Vincent and the Grenadines are significantly degraded, severely impacting fisheries and fish catches. Mismanaged and unsustainable fishing practices, such as non-targeted bycatch, inefficient fishing gear, and overfishing, further harm ecosystem healthrazmakThere is an immense gap in the knowledge pertaining to the state of ecosystems. An effective understanding of ecosystems is needed to measure baselines and progress in this area. Evaluating ecosystem services and anthropogenic degradation of the environment, will assist in creating market-based mechanisms to pay for such services or compensate for any damages caused. | To sustain the capacity of ecosystems related to fisheries and aquaculture in providing services, it is essential to improve the valuation of these services and enhance restoration efforts. This includes well-managed fisheries, closed seasons for the recovery of natural stocks and the environment, sustainable resource extraction with appropriate fishing gear, and an ecosystem-based approach to sustainable resource management. Continuous evaluation of ecosystem services would provide a highly integrated, multi-sector management tool, combining knowledge from ecology, biology, economics, and social sciences. This valuation would be expressed in monetary terms, making it universally understandable. An example of such a tool is the Natural Capital Project’s InVEST (Integrated Valuation of Ecosystem Services and Trade-offs), which offers a suite of open-access software tools for valuing natural capital. However, substantial data is required for its effective application, and a concerted effort in data collection is recommended alongside its use. |
|
Increasing the role of MPAs as fisheries management tool | Marine protected areas (MPAs) and harvest control are incentive-based fisheries management tools that have proven effective over time. Their benefits extend beyond MPA boundaries, including increased biomass and abundance, habitat preservation, reduced mortality, and enhanced growth and reproduction. The effectiveness of MPAs is context-dependent, and it is crucial to implement rules that control and limit fishing around their periphery to realise their full potential. MPAs also present significant opportunities for the eco-tourism sector to benefit from the services they provide. The development of MPAs allows for collaboration between fisheries, tourism, government, the private sector, and donor agencies to acquire resources, expertise, and technical knowledge related to the Blue Economy, helping to address sector challenges. Adequate support structures and education about eco-tourism opportunities may be necessary to implement more MPAs. The culture and traditional fishing methods of fisherfolk can be leveraged to facilitate this transition to eco-tourism by sharing and monetising these experiences for tourists. | A thorough understanding of species distribution and their habitat relationships is crucial for the success of marine protected areas (MPAs), yet this is often insufficient in existing protected areas worldwide, undermining their effectiveness. Each MPA must have its own tailored management plan developed and implemented. Key factors for effective MPAs as management tools include sustainable fisheries management, economic prosperity, the MPA’s location, size, and habitats, its connectivity to other MPAs, and the quality of local stakeholders’ participation in its management. MPAs should serve not only conservation goals but also the improved management of existing MPAs and the creation of a network of MPAs as part of a targeted fisheries management strategy. MPAs should be designed and managed in areas that significantly contribute to fishery resources. Stakeholders in the industry can be financially incentivised to adhere to and enforce MPA regulations, but a transparent platform or mechanism should be established before this can be effectively implemented. |
|
Scaling and development of aquaculture and mariculture | The aquaculture and mariculture sectors of the three countries are underdeveloped, but present a means with significant potential to create revenue. With the collective fish stocks predominantly at or above their sustainable harvesting limits, fisheries offer decreasing capacity. Using investment directed at the development of the Blue Economy, upscaling aquaculture and mariculture offers the potential to optimise the benefits received from the development of the marine environment, create sustainable, quality employment, and offer high-value commodities for both export and the domestic market. This area also offers the potential to develop further economic opportunities up- and downstream of the mariculture and aquaculture ventures themselves, creating further livelihoods. The benefits from aquaculture development, including job creation, entrepreneurship, skills development, increased food security, and potentially circular resource use, can be realised more expediently than the transition to sustainable fisheries. | Investment should be directed towards the creation of an enabling environment in which aquaculture operations can flourish, with the required support structures in place (such as veterinary services and distribution chains) to encourage further development. Among some relevant initiatives, Earth Ocean Farms in Mexico use open sea aquaculture technology to cultivate totoaba (endangered species) and red snapper (Lutjanus purpureus) in their natural environment through cages that are introduced into deep waters with ideal conditions for their growth. Essential for further development of mariculture is the harnessing of external capabilities. Connecting with practitioners experienced in aquaculture activities would provide a valuable resource for the development of mariculture in Caribbean regions. These expert practitioners could deliver key pilot projects that would provide training and capacity building, while developing strategies that prioritise national development in aquaculture and mariculture. Cultivating these connections could provide a significant investment opportunity through international development agencies, while providing a passageway to engaging in purposeful development of mariculture in the Caribbean. Aquaculture financing could happen both at the level of individual projects and at a national level. On a project level, countries that have some aquaculture can mobilise financing for securing production and environmental quality of aquaculture. This can also be promoted through financing of research-based institutions that support aquaculture developers. On a national level, financing is needed for not only creating but, just as importantly, for ensuring that public authorities have the capacity to execute national policies. In Martinique, for example, local support for aquaculture development exists and is aided by local and international (EU) funding mechanisms. Aquaculture research institutions such as ‘Delegation Ifremer des Antilles Francaise’ (IFREMER) can facilitate collaboration projects to further the development of aquaculture on the island and in the region on a bigger scale. |
|
Development of aquaponics and integration into BE development plans | As with aquaculture and mariculture, integrating aquaponics into Blue Economy development strategies alongside fisheries and aquaculture provides a pathway to realise the sustainable intensification of fisheries, aquaculture, food and agriculture. Aquaponics reintroduces biological complexity into agricultural systems, closely guided by knowledge co-creation and sharing processes that aim to maximise synergies. Tackling the region’s high food import bill and improving food security is increasingly being explored through aquaponics. An aquaponics industry can facilitate the rearing of fish for high-value protein concurrently with a range of vegetables and other produce, which as an import substitution measure can help reduce dependence on these foreign imports. Depending on market trends, crop production can be rapidly accelerated according to the local, tourism, and export demands. However, it is important to have access to markets that are willing to pay higher prices for superior quality produce. Costs for both construction and operating of aquaponics is fairly high, and production expenses may thus not be recovered without access to high-value markets. The aquaponics initiative may not be profitable without access to, and leverage, in the markets. A great deal of aquaponic businesses have failed—typically due to poor business planning and marketing strategies, rather than production-related issues. | Community driven (potentially PPP) projects could drive development in aquaponics throughout the Caribbean. This may contribute to ensuring the nutritional needs of locals are met despite limited available resources, as well as the potential of generating revenue for community well-being (by selling to premium markets, with sufficient scale). While financing the acquisition of aquaponics infrastructure is straightforward, facilitating access to markets is arguably one of the greatest limiting factors in the development of aquaponics. Market access and transport throughout the Caribbean region are areas towards which investment can be directed as they impact the success (via scalability and long-term sustainability) of any aquaponics venture. In this regard, synergies with the tourism and hospitality (restaurants, hotels, etc.) industry can be developed ensuring a reliable supply of premium produce for local and international tourists. Investment into aquaponics research and training institutions is also advised, as these will yield important contributions such as the profitability of (the appropriate combination of) cultured species. Such centres could also facilitate training in business planning and marketing strategies, in addition to aquaponics production. An enabling environment for aquaponics development is more likely to attract foreign investment and external expertise. A unified system of conformity assessment procedures for testing, inspecting, and certifying aquaponics products for import and export would minimise confusion over trade standards and ensure that all products meet legislative and food safety requirements. |
|
Develop and integrate aquaculture with alternative and emerging industries | To achieve scalable growth in aquaculture, it is essential to invest in strengthening existing relationships with other sectors and fostering new ones. This approach opens up numerous opportunities through alternative and emerging industries related to aquaculture. There is potential to create synergies between aquaculture and the biomedical industry, where products or byproducts from aquaculture could offer additional resources for alternative biomedical applications. This can be thought of as increasing the value addition potential/capacity of the industry as a whole, whereby development in fisheries and aquaculture thus holds implications for other sectors of the Blue Economy. | For example, tilapia skin from aquaculture farms is used to treat first and second-degree burns in northern Brazil. Once considered a waste product, this skin is rich in collagen, helps protect against infection, speeds up healing, and reduces the need for pain medication. This use of tilapia skin offers a cost-effective way to integrate the aquaculture industry with the medical field, requiring no additional development beyond existing aquaculture practices to enhance food security, livelihoods, and economic growth. Species of Rhodophyta, such as Irish Sea Moss found in the Caribbean, contain unique compounds with various health benefits, making them valuable for biotechnological applications. Seaweeds also play a significant role in agriculture by increasing crop yields as fertilisers and reducing the chemical load on soils and crops. Expanding mariculture to include seaweed extracts in food processing, nutraceuticals, pharmaceuticals, and industrial applications presents significant investment opportunities within the Blue Economy, enhancing sector connectivity and income generation. This approach also addresses the issue of Sargassum seaweed influxes in the region. It is essential to establish appropriate regulations for using these algae in consumption and as fertilisers throughout the Caribbean, especially regarding processing requirements and removing potentially harmful substances from the biomass.The integration of products from aquaculture and aquaponics with emerging industries is research and time intensive. Partnerships with other sector stakeholders may thus be beneficial for developing future mutual benefit. |
|
Integrating fisheries and aquaculture into the wider BE | In the context of Blue Economy development at the national level, fisheries and aquaculture should be prioritised. They will remain the primary sources of animal protein and employment for the population, especially with growing efforts to advance aquaculture and aquaponics. Fisheries, as key observers of marine changes, must play a central role in preserving important habitats and rehabilitating degraded ones. This aligns with the Blue Economy approach, which integrates marine biodiversity with coastal habitats to develop solutions beneficial for both biodiversity and climate change mitigation and adaptation. Currently, there are limited coordination mechanisms and no overarching entity to drive Blue Economy development, resulting in a dominance of sectoral approaches. This hinders the ability of countries to effectively design and implement Blue Growth policies and to protect the environment and enhance ecosystem health through the Blue Economy concept. Additionally, there is increasing confusion about the role of the state in each country due to a lack of clear commitment signals. Therefore, structuring the Blue Economy should be the top priority, preceding all other interventions. There is also a lack of an integrated and forward-looking approach to marine ecosystems and spatiotemporal management tools. Neither country has fully adopted the large marine ecosystem approach (Caribbean LME), which would help monitor the evolution of coastal and marine ecosystems using ecological indicators such as biological productivity (particularly fish biomass), pollution (including plastics and chemicals), and ecosystem health. The absence of this approach results in less effective resource and ecosystem management. | The establishment of supra ministerial Blue Economy coordination units in each of the countries respectively will facilitate the integration of the fisheries and aquaculture sectors into the wider BE, by being able to manage its impact relative to other sectors. Such a unit will also be better suited to develop coordination mechanisms between BE sectors with fisheries and aquaculture industries resulting in cross-sectoral synergies and increased development capacity. Improved understanding and comprehension of fisheries and aquaculture value chains and challenges facilitates integration into the wider BE, by being able to identify synergies and opportunities for cooperation with other sectors, and the fisheries and aquaculture sectors and markets of other countries. The development of integrated and spatiotemporal management tools can be coordinated and integrated into fisheries and aquaculture, by a BE unit. A Blue Economy unit with a holistic approach will also facilitate and inform policy decision-making more accurately than individual sector representatives. Adoption and awareness raising of the large marine ecosystem approach among fisheries and aquaculture stakeholders can facilitate a more sustainable and efficient use of available natural resources. Awareness-raising can be facilitated by regional organisations, BE units, NGOs, or the state. |
|
Data limitation among fisheries and aquaculture and lack of policy development | Blue Economy activities and components are currently not accounted for in a unified manner. At present, data must be gathered from various sources to obtain a comprehensive view of the Blue Economy’s contributions to added value and job creation. For some sectors, such as ship maintenance, data is not even recorded. Implementing a national accounting system would facilitate the tracking of annual changes in economic sectors. Similarly, ecological aspects of the Blue Economy are not accounted for, despite the valuable ecosystem services provided by coastal areas and their role in mitigating hurricane impacts. However, with the implementation of nationally determined contributions, green and blue accounting should emerge as foundational tools for evaluating specific actions related to climate change. The lack of data results in uninformed decision making and inadequate fisheries and aquaculture policy making, negatively affecting the industry. | A national organisation for Blue Economy accounting (and environmental accounting) could regulate the accounting of BE activities. This thus ensures that the data from a wide variety of sources is verified and coordinated, meaning that it can be used to inform decision-making relating to climate-change, and industry development. Policy-making needs to be informed by available data, and where it is missing, similar examples (of other countries’ fisheries and aquaculture sectors) can be used as proxies (if appropriately similar). Where such an organisation is missing, an easy to use platform for recording data in fisheries and aquaculture is necessary. The design of the platform should be such that it encourages unambiguous data input and should use data already generated/collected by industry stakeholders. Incentivising stakeholders to encourage honest data reporting of fishing activities (such as through tax exemptions or non-government subsidies) may contribute to filling the data limitation. |
|
An enabling environment for fisheries and aquaculture investment | Banking mechanisms are inadequate, and financial markets remain underdeveloped. In this context, a transparent policy framework adhering to emerging blue finance principles (such as those from UNEP-FI) could help build investor confidence. Creating a supportive environment for sustainable financing of fisheries within the broader Blue Economy will require focused attention, particularly in relation to addressing national debt. | The recent Caribbean Blue Economic Financing Project (Caribbean BlueFin) offers a chance to strengthen the capacity of selected countries and establish an environment conducive to private sector involvement and investment in the Blue Economy. |
|
References
- Bethel, B.J.; Buravleva, Y.; Tang, D. Blue Economy and Blue Activities: Opportunities, Challenges, and Recommendations for The Bahamas. Water 2021, 13, 1399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- FAO. FishStatJ—Global Production by Production Source 1950–2019; FAO: Rome, Italy, 2022; Available online: https://www.fao.org/fishery/en/statistics/software/fishstatj (accessed on 4 April 2023).
- FAO. Fishery Country Profile; Grenada; FAO: Rome, Italy, 2019; Updated December 2019; Available online: https://www.fao.org/fishery/en/facp/grd (accessed on 23 April 2023).
- March, A.; Failler, P.; Bennett, M. Caribbean Fishery and Aquaculture Financing Needs in the Blue Economy: Identifying Opportunities and Constraints in Barbados, Grenada, and St. Vincent and the Grenadines. J. Sustain. Res. 2023, 5, e230004. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- UN. United Nations—Blue Economy: Oceans as the Next Great Economic Frontier. 2023. Available online: https://unric.org/en/blue-economy-oceans-as-the-next-great-economic-frontier/ (accessed on 3 March 2023).
- Failler, P.; Pètre, É.; Binet, T.; Maréchal, J.-P. Valuation of marine and coastal ecosystem services as a tool for conservation: The case of Martinique in the Caribbean. Ecosyst. Serv. 2015, 11, 67–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jackson, J.; Donovan, M.; Cramer, K.; Lam, V. Status and Trends of Caribbean Coral Reefs: 1970–2012. IUCN. 2014. Available online: https://portals.iucn.org/library/efiles/documents/2014-019.pdf (accessed on 20 March 2023).
- Patil, P.G.; Virdin, J.; Diez, S.M.; Roberts, J.; Singh, A. Toward A Blue Economy: A Promise for Sustainable Growth in the Caribbean; An Overview. World Bank Group. 2016. Available online: https://www.cbd.int/financial/doc/wb-blueeconomy.pdf (accessed on 20 March 2023).
- Wilson, R. Impacts of Climate Change on Mangrove Ecosystems in the Coastal and Marine Environments of Caribbean Small Island Developing States (SIDS). 2017. Available online: https://www.seatoneconsulting.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/Impacts-of-Climate-Change-on-Mangrove-Ecosystems-in-the-Coastal-and-Marine-Environments-of-Caribbean-Small-Island-Developing-States.pdf (accessed on 21 March 2023).
- OECD Data Explorer. Official Flows by Country and Region. From OECD.Stat. 2024. Available online: https://data-explorer.oecd.org/vis?df[ds]=DisseminateFinalDMZ&df[id]=DSD_DAC2%40DF_DAC2A&df[ag]=OECD.DCD.FSD&df[vs]=1.1&dq=.DPGC.206.USD.Q&lom=LASTNPERIODS&lo=5&to[TIME_PERIOD]=false (accessed on 6 February 2024).
- Lewis, F.; Saliman, A.; Peterson, E. Funding Trends 2023: Tracking the State of Global Ocean Funding. Our Shared Seas. 2023. Available online: https://oursharedseas.com/funding/ (accessed on 15 May 2023).
- Failler, P.; Andriamahefazafy, M. Madagascar Blue Economy Strategy for Fisheries and Aquaculture; Government of Madagascar: Antananarivo, Madagascar, 2022.
- Failler, P. Seychelles Blue Economy Action Plan; Department of the Blue Economy, Republic of Seychelles and United Nations Economic Commission for Africa: Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 2020; 20p. [Google Scholar]
- AU-IBAR. Africa Blue Economy Strategy—Blue Governance Framework; African Union: Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Ram, J.; Kaidou-Jeffrey, D. Financing the Blue Economy in the Wider Caribbean. In The Caribbean Blue Economy; Routledge: Abingdon, UK, 2020; pp. 210–225. [Google Scholar]
- Clegg, P.; Mahon, R.; McConney, P.; Oxenford, H.A. (Eds.) The Caribbean Blue Economy; Routledge: Abingdon, UK, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Whiteside, H. Beyond death and taxes: Fiscal studies and the fiscal state. Environ. Plan. A Econ. Space 2021, 55, 1744–1761. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vidal-Hernández, L.; de Yta-Castillo, D.; Castellanos-Basto, B.; Suárez-Castro, M.; Rivera-Arriaga, E. Fiscal Economic Instruments for the Sustainable Management of Natural Resources in Coastal Marine Areas of the Yucatan Peninsula. Sustainability 2021, 13, 11103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cepal, N. Revenue Statistics in Latin America and the Caribbean 1990-2019/Estadísticas Tributarias en América Latina y el Caribe 1990–2019. 2021. Available online: https://www.cepal.org/es/publicaciones/46811-revenue-statistics-latin-america-and-caribbean-1990-2019-estadisticas (accessed on 16 February 2024).
- Attzs, M.; Maharaj, M.; Boodhan, G. Survey and Assessment of Environmental Taxes in the Caribbean; Inter-American Development Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Ballesteros, L.V.; Matthews, J.L.; Hoeksema, B.W. Pollution and coral damage caused by derelict fishing gear on coral reefs around Koh Tao, Gulf of Thailand. Mar. Pollut. Bull. 2018, 135, 1107–1116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Unsbo, H.; Boltenstern, M.; Granberg, M.; Olshammar, M.; Karlsson, M. Quantification and Environmental Pollution Aspects of Lost Fishing Gear in the Nordic Countries; Nordic Council of Ministers: Copenhagen, Denmark, 2022. [Google Scholar]
- Nelms, S.E.; Duncan, E.M.; Patel, S.; Badola, R.; Bhola, S.; Chakma, S.; Chowdhury, G.W.; Godley, B.J.; Haque, A.B.; Johnson, J.A.; et al. Riverine plastic pollution from fisheries: Insights from the Ganges River system. Sci. Total. Environ. 2020, 756, 143305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Thompson, N. Thompson, William (1775–1833), Socialist and Economist; Oxford Dictionary of National Biography (Online ed.); Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons—The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2015; ISBN 9781107569782. Available online: https://www.cambridge.org/us/universitypress/subjects/politics-international-relations/political-theory/governing-commons-evolution-institutions-collective-action-1?format=PB&isbn=9781107569782 (accessed on 15 May 2023).
- Wunder, S. Payments for Environmental Services: Some Nuts and Bolts; CIFOR Occasional Paper No. 42; CIFOR: Bogor, Indonesia, 2005; Available online: https://montagneinrete.it/wp-content/uploads/2024/03/op-42-wunder-on-payments_1495540914-1.pdf (accessed on 23 April 2023).
- Engel, S.; Pagiola, S.; Wunder, S. Designing payments for environmental services in theory and practice: An overview of the issues. Ecol. Econ. 2008, 65, 663–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van Hecken, G.; Bastiaensen, J.; Huybrechs, F. What’s in a name? Epistemic perspectives and Payments for Ecosystem Services policies in Nicaragua. Geoforum 2015, 63, 55–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Salzman, J.; Bennett, G.; Carroll, N.; Goldstein, A.; Jenkins, M. The global status and trends of Payments for Ecosystem Services. Nat. Sustain. 2018, 1, 136–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trends, F. Payments for Ecosystem Services: Getting Started in Marine and Coastal Ecosystems. A Primer. 2010, pp. 4–5, Electronic Source. Available online: https://www.forest-trends.org/wp-content/uploads/imported/marine-coastal-pes-getting-started_2010-pdf.pdf (accessed on 15 May 2023).
- Newell, R.; Sanchirico, J.; Kerr, S. An Empirical Analysis of New Zealand’s ITQ Markets. In Proceedings of the IIFET 2002 Conference, Wellington, New Zealand, 19–22 August 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Robertson, M.M. The neoliberalization of ecosystem services: Wetland mitigation banking and problems in environmental governance. Geoforum 2004, 35, 361–373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- BBOP. The Mitigation Hierarchy—Business and Biodiversity Offsets Programme. 2023. Available online: https://www.forest-trends.org/bbop/bbop-key-concepts/mitigation-hierarchy/ (accessed on 11 April 2023).
- Ten Kate, K.; Bishop, J.; Bayon, R. Biodiversity Offsets: Views, Experience, and the Business Case; IUCN & Insight Investment: Gland, Switzelrand, 2004; Online Report; Available online: https://www.iucn.org/sites/default/files/import/downloads/bdoffsets.pdf (accessed on 20 May 2023).
- Dempsey, J. Enterprising Nature: Economics, Markets, and Finance in Global Biodiversity Politics; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Ripple, W.J.; Estes, J.A.; Schmitz, O.J.; Constant, V.; Kaylor, M.J.; Lenz, A.; Motley, J.L.; Self, K.E.; Taylor, D.S.; Wolf, C. What is a trophic cascade? Trends Ecol. Evol. 2016, 31, 842–849. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Blair, J.M.; Collins, S.L.; Knapp, A.K. Ecosystems as functional units in nature. Nat. Resour. Env’t. 1999, 14, 150. [Google Scholar]
- Jax, K. Ecological Units: Definitions and Application. Q. Rev. Biol. 2006, 81, 237–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Niner, H.J.; Randalls, S. Good enough for governance? Audit and marine biodiversity offsetting in Australia. Geoforum 2021, 120, 38–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Resilient Islands. Valuing the Benefits of Mangroves and Coral Reefs in the Caribbean. Coastal Resilience. 2024. Available online: https://media.coastalresilience.org/Resilient_Islands/BenefitsOfMangrovesAndCorals_TechReport.pdf (accessed on 16 April 2024).
- UNEP-WCMC. WorldFish Centre, WRI, TNC. Global Distribution of Warm-Water Coral Reefs. 2024. Available online: https://doi.org/10.34892/t2wk-5t34 (accessed on 12 February 2024).
- UNEP-WCMC. Short FT. Global Distribution of Seagrasses (Version 7.1). 2024. Available online: https://doi.org/10.34892/x6r3-d211 (accessed on 12 February 2024).
- Chami, R.; Cosimano, T.F.; Fullenkamp, C.; Oztosun, S. Nature’s Solution to Climate Change: A strategy to protect whales can limit greenhouse gases and global warming. Financ. Dev. 2019, 56. Available online: https://www.actu-environnement.com/media/pdf/news-34050-article-finances-developpement.pdf (accessed on 17 April 2023).
- Howard, J.; Hoyt, S.; Isensee, K.; Telszewski, M.; Pidgeon, E. Coastal Blue Carbon: Methods for Assessing Carbon Stocks and Emissions Factors in Mangroves, Tidal Salt Marshes, and Seagrasses; IUCN: Gland, Switzerland, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Bumpus, A.G. The Matter of Carbon: Understanding the Materiality of tCO2e in Carbon Offsets. Antipode 2011, 43, 612–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trading Economics. EU Carbon Permits—Trading Economics. 2023. Available online: https://tradingeconomics.com/commodity/carbon (accessed on 12 April 2023).
- Vandana, S. Voluntary Carbon Market—S&P Global; Agnihotri, A., Ed.; S&P Global: New York, NY, USA, 2022; Available online: https://www.spglobal.com/commodity-insights/en/market-insights/latest-news/energy-transition/010622-voluntary-carbon-market-rally-set-to-stretch-into-2022-on-demand-optimism (accessed on 13 February 2023).
- Fleischman, F.; Basant, S.; Fischer, H.; Gupta, D.; Lopez, G.G.; Kashwan, P.; Powers, J.S.; Ramprasad, V.; Rana, P.; Rastogi, A.; et al. How politics shapes the outcomes of forest carbon finance. Curr. Opin. Environ. Sustain. 2021, 51, 7–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- IEG. Intrinsic Exchange Group. 2023. Available online: https://www.intrinsicexchange.com/home-1 (accessed on 12 February 2023).
- OECD. Lessons Learnt from Experience with Debt-for-Environment Swaps in Economies in Transition; OECD: Paris, France, 2007; p. 39. [Google Scholar]
- The Commonwealth. Case Study: Innovative Financing—Debt for Conservation Swap, Seychelles’ Conservation and Climate Adaptation Trust and the Blue Bonds Plan, Seychelles (On-Going). 2020. Available online: https://thecommonwealth.org/case-study/case-study-innovative-financing-debt-conservation-swap-seychelles-conservation-and (accessed on 14 September 2022).
- Fuller, F.; Zamarioli, L.; Kretschmer, B.; Thomas, A.; De Marez, L. Debt for climate swaps: Caribbean outlook. In Impact: Science Based Implementation of 1.5 C Compatible Action for LDCs and SIDS; Climate Analytics: Berlin, Germany, 2018; pp. 1–18. Available online: https://ca1-clm.edcdn.com/assets/debt_for_climate_swap_impact_briefing.pdf (accessed on 27 September 2022).
- Bigger, P.; Christiansen, J.; Dempsey, J.; DiSilvestro, D.; Irvine-Broque, A.; Nelson, S.; Rojas-Marchini, F.; Schuldt, A.; Shapiro-Garza, E. Beyond the Gap: Placing Biodiversity Finance in the Global Economy; Third World Network: Penang, Malaysia, 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Victurine, R.; Meyers, D.; Bohorquez, J.; Box, S.; Blythe, J.; Callow, M.; Jupiter, S.; Schweigart, K.; Walsh, M.; Bieri, T. Conservation Finance for Coral Reefs. Vibrant Oceans Initiative Whitepaper; Wildlife Conservation Society: New York, NY, USA, 2022; p. 10. Available online: https://doi.org/10.19121/2022.Report.43864 (accessed on 18 September 2022).
- McGowan, J.; Weary, R.; Carriere, L.; Game, E.T.; Smith, J.L.; Garvey, M.; Possingham, H.P. Prioritizing debt conversion opportunities for marine conservation. Conserv. Biol. 2020, 34, 1065–1075. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Munevar, D. Making Sense of Belize’s Blue Bond Proposal. EURODAD: European Network of Debt and Development. 2021. Available online: https://www.eurodad.org/making_sense_of_belizes_blue_bond_proposal (accessed on 20 February 2022).
- Perry, K.K. From the plantation to the deep blue sea: Naturalising debt, ordinary disasters, and postplantation ecologies in the Caribbean. Geogr. J. 2022, 189, 562–574. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- World Bank. Sovereign Blue Bond Issuance: Frequently Asked Questions. 2018. Available online: https://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2018/10/29/sovereign-blue-bond-issuance-frequently-asked-questions (accessed on 27 August 2022).
- Winters, R. The Nature Conservancy Announces Its Third Global Debt Conversion in Barbados. The Nature Conservancy. 2022. Available online: https://www.nature.org/en-us/newsroom/tnc-announces-barbados-blue-bonds-debt-conversion/#:~:text=The%20Blue%20Bonds%20strategy%20combines,of%20their%20communities%20and%20economies (accessed on 26 September 2022).
- Sumaila, U.R.; Walsh, M.; Hoareau, K.; Cox, A.; Teh, L.; Abdallah, P.; Akpalu, W.; Anna, Z.; Benzaken, D.; Crona, B.; et al. Financing a sustainable ocean economy. Nat. Commun. 2021, 12, 3259. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- March, A.; Failler, P.; Bennett, M. Challenges when designing blue bond financing for Small Island Developing States. ICES J. Mar. Sci. 2023, 80, 2244–2251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Adams, D.M.; Benzaken, D.; McCarron, B.; Taylor, L.; Thiele, T.; Tok, X. Analysis & Development of a Pacific Ocean Bond; Asia Research & Engagement: Singapore, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Mehta, A.; Tirumala, R.D.; Andrich, M.L. Financing the Ocean Back to Health in Southeast Asia: Approaches for Mainstreaming Blue Finance; Asian Development Bank: Metro Manila, Philippines, 2021. [Google Scholar]
- Christiansen, J. Securing the sea: Ecosystem-based adaptation and the biopolitics of insuring nature’s rents. J. Political Ecol. 2021, 28, 337–357. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cisneros-Montemayor, A.M.; Moreno-Báez, M.; Reygondeau, G.; Cheung, W.W.L.; Crosman, K.M.; González-Espinosa, P.C.; Lam, V.W.Y.; Oyinlola, M.A.; Singh, G.G.; Swartz, W.; et al. Enabling conditions for an equitable and sustainable blue economy. Nature 2021, 591, 396–401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Quak, E. How Losing Concessional Finance Affects Small Island Developing States (SIDS); K4D Helpdesk Report No 626; Institute of Development Studies: Brighton, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Bishop, M.; Argudin Violante, C.; Bouhia, R.; Carter, G.; Corbett, J.; Lindsay, C.; Scobie, M.; Wilkinson, E. Just Transitions in Small Island Developing States (SIDS); Electronic Source; British Academy: London, UK, 2021. [Google Scholar]
- UNEPFI. The Principles—Sustainable Blue Finance. United Nations Environment Programme Finance Initiative. 2018. Available online: https://www.unepfi.org/blue-finance/the-principles/ (accessed on 23 September 2023).
- Thiele, T.; Gerber, L.R. Innovative financing for the high seas. Aquat. Conserv. Mar. Freshw. Ecosyst. 2017, 27, 89–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gbigbi, T.M.; Achoja, F.O. Cooperative Financing and the Growth of Catfish Aquaculture Value Chain in Nigeria. Croat. J. Fish. 2019, 77, 263–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Syddall, V.M.; Fisher, K.; Thrush, S. Collaboration a solution for small island developing states to address food security and economic development in the face of climate change. Ocean Coast. Manag. 2022, 221, 106132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- UNCTAD. Barbados Bets on Tuna to Boost the Value of Fish Exports. 2020. Available online: https://unctad.org/news/barbados-bets-tuna-boost-value-fish-exports (accessed on 16 February 2024).
- OECS Member States. Organization of Eastern Caribbean States. 2024. Available online: https://www.oecs.org/en/who-we-are/member-states (accessed on 6 February 2024).
- OECD. Beyond GDP—Measuring What Counts for Economic and Social Performance; Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD): Paris, France, 2018; Available online: https://www.oecd.org/social/beyond-gdp-9789264307292-en.htm (accessed on 16 May 2023).
- International Oceanographic Commission. Marine Spatial Planning. 2022. Available online: https://www.ioc.unesco.org/en/marine-spatial-planning (accessed on 18 May 2023).
- ADB. Financing the Blue Economy: Investments in Sustainable Blue Small-Medium Enterprises and Projects in Asia and the Pacific; Asian Development Bank (ADB): Metro Manila, Philippines, 2022; ISBN 978-92-9269-603-0. Available online: https://doi.org/10.22617/TCS220281-2 (accessed on 17 September 2022).
- ADB. SME BlueImpact Asia: Financing Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises that Dominate the Blue Economy. Online Webinar. Asian Development Bank (ADB) Knowledge Events. 2022. Available online: https://events.development.asia/learning-events/sme-blueimpact-asia-financing-small-and-medium-sized-enterprises-dominate-blue (accessed on 16 February 2024).
- Abalobi. Home Page. 2023. Available online: https://abalobi.org (accessed on 16 February 2024).
- Weirowski, F.; Hall, S.J. Public-Private Partnerships for Fisheries and Aquaculture: Getting Started; WorldFish Center Manual Number 1875; The WorldFish Center: Penang, Malaysia, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Allam, Z.; Jones, D. Climate Change and Economic Resilience through Urban and Cultural Heritage: The Case of Emerging Small Island Developing States Economies. Economies 2019, 7, 62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Anderson, T.L.; Leal, D.R. Free Market Environmentalism; Palgrave Macmillan: New York, NY, USA, 2001; ISBN 978-0-312-23503-1. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Coates, R. What is Free-Market Environmentalism? Lean Liberty. 2023. Available online: https://www.learnliberty.org/blog/what-is-free-market-environmentalism/ (accessed on 2 February 2024).
Country | 2016 | 2017 | 2018 | 2019 | 2020 | 2021 | 2022 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Grenada | 6.41 | 1.09 | 0.65 | 1.65 | 3.42 | 3.30 | 2.26 |
St. Vincent and the Grenadines (SVG) | 2.99 | 4.30 | 0.63 | 10.92 | 3.75 | 5.91 | 9.12 |
Montserrat | 44.13 | 41.76 | 39.04 | 36.36 | 47.19 | 37.37 | 42.74 |
Haiti | 744.43 | 712.668 | 635.033 | 463.29 | 483.40 | 434.89 | 450.21 |
Caribbean (total) | 367.91 | 1254.48 | 1221.13 | 748.764 | 984.413 | 1292.16 | 1104.86 |
Type of Arrangement | Description |
---|---|
Environmental taxes | An environmental tax is meant to target activities that cause environmental degradation or pollution, but this does not imply that the tax has a proven effect in terms of minimising environmentally degrading or polluting activities. Rather, the minimum definition of an environmental tax is that it increases the costs of pollution activities [19]. Nonetheless, the actual application of an environmental tax is likely to have the effect of incentivising some activities whilst disincentivizing others. |
Leases, licences and fees | Whereas a tax is compulsory, a lease, licence or fee can be seen as a form of exchange between a public authority and a (legal) person, which grants the latter a certain right or privilege. Another difference between this category of public fiscal revenues and taxes is that these leases, licences and fees remain stable regardless of the incomes that the payer may generate as a result. |
State-owned enterprises (SOEs) | SOEs are rarely thought of as part of fiscal policies. Nonetheless, they are and many of the types of companies that have historically been state-owned around the world have some clear environmental impacts. Public utilities companies such as water companies and energy companies quite explicitly have an environmental aspect since they usually have environmental quality or resource efficiency as key objectives. Other types of SOEs, like transportation companies, may increasingly incorporate environmental objectives. SOEs can be run with a focus on generating profits, but they can also seek to strategically increase public goods and services through their operations. SOEs can be a source of revenue when they generate profits while their inventory and equipment can be seen as capital goods. Meanwhile, SOEs can also hold liabilities in the form of debt. |
Debt and lending | Debt can be an income for public entities as well as a cost and liability. Lending from development banks under national control, lending from sovereign wealth funds and debt in the form of deferred taxes (with potential interest added) are examples of the state as creditor and debt as a source of public incomes. By contrast, sovereign debt is a continuous source of public expenditures. Lending practices, both when the state is the creditor and debtor, can be explicitly targeted towards the objectives of sustainable aquaculture and fisheries development. (see Section 3.3) |
Public finance support (government subsidies) | Public finance such as grant funding or philanthropic contributions (while not directly a financing mechanism as previously defined) can be used as a financing mechanism to garner private investment. This can be performed in the form of government subsidies, where public finance is directed towards development mechanisms or initiatives that also require further private funding to be implemented. The total cost of the fiscal contribution from the private sector is lowered, thus incentivising private investment in an industry (fisheries and aquaculture). This mechanism can thus facilitate affordability of industry (aquaculture and fisheries) development for the private sector. |
PES Type | Elaboration | Examples |
---|---|---|
Regulated markets | Cap and trade markets require resource users to hold a purchasable right to the resource they use. It sets a limit to resource use and allocates a tradable share of the resource to an asset owner. A licence is not necessarily tradable and the issuer of a licence does not necessarily set a limit to damages to an ecosystem, but it still constitutes a transaction based on compliance. | Fishing can in different ways be governed through mechanisms that can reasonably be seen as PES. On the most simple level, recreational fishers are in some jurisdictions required to pay for fees or hold annually paid licences. Another example are individual transferable quotas (ITQs) that are used to allocate annual fishing rights within an exclusive economic zone (like quota’s per fishing ground). ITQs can then be traded and leased amongst fishers. By using the regulated ITQ marketplace, a sustainable fishery and ecosystem services market can be achieved [31], through the trading of rights to exploit the fish provisioning service of an ecosystem within identified sustainable harvesting limits. The rights to a proportion of the total fish population (fishing quota) has to be identified beforehand and the total harvestable quota must be within the sustainable harvesting limits of the ecosystem, for this mechanism to be effective. Government mandated fees related to ecosystem services can likewise be seen as a form of PES based on compliance. This can for example be tourist fees associated with entering (marine) protected areas, that in this case are of importance to fisheries and aquaculture. |
Voluntary transactions | Voluntary PES transactions can involve private and public sector actors alike. Governments, private individuals, NGOs and development organisations can all pay private actors to change practices or avoid harm to ecosystems. | The Marine Legacy Fund of Tanzania is an example of voluntary PES. It is a revolving fund whose original sources of revenue as well as its spending can be seen as forms of PES. It gains revenue from tourist fees, fossil fuel taxation and fishing licences. However, the fund uses this revenue to finance the protection of coastal habitats and important marine sectors. Whereas its sources of revenue are based on compliance, its spending can be seen as voluntary PES. This kind of structure can be applied to countries individually, or regionally, due to shared fish stocks (or other shared resource use). |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Bennett, M.; March, A.; Failler, P. Blue Economy Financing Solutions for the Fisheries and Aquaculture Sectors of Caribbean Island States. Fishes 2024, 9, 305. https://doi.org/10.3390/fishes9080305
Bennett M, March A, Failler P. Blue Economy Financing Solutions for the Fisheries and Aquaculture Sectors of Caribbean Island States. Fishes. 2024; 9(8):305. https://doi.org/10.3390/fishes9080305
Chicago/Turabian StyleBennett, Michael, Antaya March, and Pierre Failler. 2024. "Blue Economy Financing Solutions for the Fisheries and Aquaculture Sectors of Caribbean Island States" Fishes 9, no. 8: 305. https://doi.org/10.3390/fishes9080305
APA StyleBennett, M., March, A., & Failler, P. (2024). Blue Economy Financing Solutions for the Fisheries and Aquaculture Sectors of Caribbean Island States. Fishes, 9(8), 305. https://doi.org/10.3390/fishes9080305