Causal Economic Machine Learning (CEML): “Human AI”
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Theory
2.1. Causal Economics Theory
2.2. A Real World Example
2.3. Reducing Causal Economics to Expected Utility Theory
2.4. Reducing Causal Economics to Behavioral Economics
2.5. Causal Economics and Artificial Intelligence
2.5.1. The Principle of Causal Coupling
Microeconomics
Macroeconomics
2.6. The Neuroscience Underpinning Causal Economics
2.7. The Psychology Underpinning Causal Economics
2.8. Decision-Making in Artificial Intelligence
2.9. Machine Learning
2.10. Causal Inference
2.10.1. Natural Experiments
2.10.2. Causal Machine Learning (CML)
2.10.3. Causal Economic Machine Learning (CEML)
CEML as an Evolution of Human AI
Implementation of CEML
- Label the data in line with the CE framework, capturing current and future costs and benefits, both certain and uncertain.
- Utilize Sequential Least Squares Programming (SLSQP) for constrained non-linear optimization of Equations (1)–(3) and (8).
- Apply the S-Learner machine learning algorithm.
- Expected utility theory and behavioral economics theory have led to causal economic theory.
- Causal inference (natural experiments, structural causal models) and machine learning have led to causal machine learning.
- Causal economic theory and causal machine learning have led to causal economic machine learning.
Challenges to the Implementation of CEML
- Limited data sets. This challenge exists due to the large number of parameters involved in the equations of CEML and in particular the inclusion of a number of psychological inputs. CEML studies can require extensive up-front work in preparing and labeling data sets.
- Risk of combinatorial explosion. The complexity of the CEML optimization presents a risk of slowing down computation and impacting solvability [14].
- Implications. The concept of causal coupling that is built into the functional forms of CEML can produce implications in applications that represent significant upheaval of the status quo in areas such as tax policy. The following section lays out potential applications that largely represent ideal scenarios, so policymakers evaluating these possibilities must appreciate the difficult reality of driving major change in the real world against vested interests.
3. Applications and Discussion
3.1. Decision Making
3.2. Macroeconomic/Social Outcomes
- Free interaction and exchange (free markets) with corrections for externalities
- Significant levels of direct democracy
- Government by legislation prioritized over bureaucracy
- Widespread compensation for results in the private and public sector
- Use-based taxation driven by flat and use-based taxes with relief for those in need
- Social risk/cost sharing programs for exposures/projects that would be catastrophic/prohibitive to individuals
3.2.1. Private Sector Application
3.2.2. Public Sector Applications
3.2.3. Healthcare Applications
4. Conclusions
- Expected utility theory and behavioral economics theory have led to causal economic theory.
- Causal inference (natural experiments and structural causal models) and machine learning have led to causal machine learning.
- Causal economic theory and causal machine learning have led to causal economic machine learning.
- Labelling the data in line with the structure of the causal economic framework (certain and uncertain costs, upfront and in the future, as well as current and future benefits).
- Optimizing the non-linear response functions for utility, Equation (1), and the two constraints. Equations (2) and (3) using SLSQP (Sequential Least Squares Programming).
- Applying the S-Learner meta-learner machine learning algorithm to fit the model.
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Gabriel, I.; Ghazavi, V. The challenge of value alignment: From fairer algorithms to AI safety. arXiv 2021, arXiv:2101.06060. [Google Scholar]
- Chaturvedi, S.; Patvardhan, C.; Lakshmi, C.V. AI Value Alignment Problem: The Clear and Present Danger. In Proceedings of the 2023 6th International Conference on Information Systems and Computer Networks (ISCON), Mathura, India, 3–4 March 2023; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2023; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
- Sejnowski, T.J. The Deep Learning Revolution; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Naudé, W. 2023. “Artificial Intelligence and the Economics of Decision-Making.” 2023. IZA Discussion Paper No. 16000. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=4389118 (accessed on 24 June 2024).
- Jenkins, P.; Farag, A.; Jenkins, J.S.; Yao, H. Causal Machine Learning. Preprints 2021, 35, 7917–7925. [Google Scholar]
- Green, S.L. Rational choice theory: An overview. In Baylor University Faculty Development Seminar on Rational Choice Theory; Baylor University: Waco, TX, USA, 2002; pp. 1–72. [Google Scholar]
- Dillon, S.M. Descriptive decision making: Comparing theory with practice. In Proceedings of the 33rd ORSNZ Conference, Auckland, New Zealand, 31 August–1 September 1998; University of Auckland: Auckland, New Zealand, 1998. [Google Scholar]
- Tversky, A. A critique of expected utility theory: Descriptive and normative considerations. Erkenntnis 1975, 9, 163–173. [Google Scholar]
- Yaqub, M.Z.; Saz, G.; Hussain, D. A meta analysis of the empirical evidence on expected utility theory. Eur. J. Econ. Financ. Adm. Sci. 2009, 15, 117–133. [Google Scholar]
- Dhami, S.S. The Foundations of Behavioral Economic Analysis; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Simon, H.A. Bounded rationality. In Utility and Probability; Palgrave Macmillan: London, UK, 1990; pp. 15–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tversky, A.; Kahneman, D. Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. J. Risk Uncertain. 1992, 5, 297–323. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Şimşek, Ö. Bounded rationality for artificial intelligence. In Routledge Handbook of Bounded Rationality; Routledge: London, UK, 2020; pp. 338–348. [Google Scholar]
- Russell, S.J.; Norvig, P. Artificial Intelligence: A Modern Approach; Pearson: London, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Bellman, R. A Markovian decision process. J. Math. Mech. 1957, 6, 679–684. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Howard, R.A. Dynamic Programming and Markov Processes; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1960. [Google Scholar]
- Kaelbling, L.P.; Littman, M.L.; Moore, A.W. Reinforcement learning: A survey. J. Artif. Intell. Res. 1996, 4, 237–285. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Samuelson, P.A. A note on measurement of utility. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1937, 4, 155–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- O’Donoghue, T.; Rabin, M. Doing it now or later. Am. Econ. Rev. 1999, 89, 103–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Horton, A. Causal Economics: A new pluralist framework for behavioral economics that advances theoretical and applied foundations. Heliyon 2019, 5, e01342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Imbens, G.W.; Angrist, J.D. Testing of local average treatment Journal of the Econometric. Identification and estimation effects. Econom. Soc. 1994, 5, 467–475. [Google Scholar]
- Rubin, D.B. Causal inference using potential outcomes: Design, modeling, decisions. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 2005, 100, 322–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Imbens, G.W.; Rubin, D.B. Causal Inference in Statistics, Social, and Biomedical Sciences; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Huber, M. Causal Analysis: Impact Evaluation and Causal Machine Learning with Applications in R; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2023. [Google Scholar]
- Arti, S.; Hidayah, I.; Kusumawardhani, S.S. Research trend of causal machine learning method: A literature review. IJID (Int. J. Inform. Dev.) 2020, 9, 111–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mishra, S. Decision-making under risk: Integrating perspectives from biology, economics, and psychology. Personal. Soc. Psychol. Rev. 2014, 18, 280–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mongin, P. Expected Utility Theory. In The Handbook of Economic Methodology; Devis, J.B., Hands, D.W., Mäki, U., Eds.; Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, UK, 1998; pp. 342–350. [Google Scholar]
- Wakker, P.; Tversky, A. An axiomatization of cumulative prospect theory. J. Risk Uncertain. 1993, 7, 147–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vahabi, M. The soft budget constraint: A theoretical clarification. Rech. Économiques Louvain/Louvain Econ. Rev. 2001, 67, 157–195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Brink, P.J.; Ferguson, K. The decision to lose weight. West. J. Nurs. Res. 1998, 20, 84–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Savage, L.J. The Foundations of Statistics; Wiley: New York, NY, USA, 1954. [Google Scholar]
- Schoemaker, P.J.H. The expected utility model: Its variants, purposes, evidence and limitations. J. Econ. Lit. 1982, 20, 529–563. [Google Scholar]
- Fishburn, P.C. The Foundations of Expected Utility; Springer Science & Business Media: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2013; Volume 31. [Google Scholar]
- Isaac, A.G. The Structure of Neoclassical Consumer Theory; No. 9805003; University Library of Munich: Munich, Germany, 1998. [Google Scholar]
- Thaler, R. Some empirical evidence on dynamic inconsistency. Econ. Lett. 1981, 8, 201–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pannu, A. Artificial intelligence and its application in different areas. Artif. Intell. 2015, 4, 79–84. [Google Scholar]
- Day, R.H. Adaptive processes and economic theory. In Adaptive Economic Models; Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1975; pp. 1–38. [Google Scholar]
- Baumol, W. The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Stiglitz, J.E. The Invisible Hand and Modern Welfare Economics; Blackwell: Oxford, UK; Cambridge, MA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
- Ledyard, J.O. Market failure. In Allocation, Information and Markets; Palgrave Macmillan UK: London, UK, 1989; pp. 185–190. [Google Scholar]
- Kurniawan, I.T.; Seymour, B.; Talmi, D.; Yoshida, W.; Chater, N.; Dolan, R.J. Choosing to make an effort: The role of striatum in signaling physical effort of a chosen action. J. Neurophysiol. 2010, 104, 313–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Talmi, D.; Dayan, P.; Kiebel, S.J.; Frith, C.D.; Dolan, R.J. How humans integrate the prospects of pain and reward during choice. J. Neurosci. 2009, 29, 14617–14626. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kennerley, S.W.; Dahmubed, A.F.; Lara, A.H.; Wallis, J.D. Neurons in the frontal lobe encode the value of multiple decision variables. J. Cogn. Neurosci. 2009, 21, 1162–1178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Croxson, P.L.; Walton, M.E.; O’Reilly, J.X.; Behrens, T.E.; Rushworth, M.F. Effort-based cost–benefit valuation and the human brain. J. Neurosci. 2009, 29, 4531–4541. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Floresco, S.B.; Ghods-Sharifi, S. Amygdala-prefrontal cortical circuitry regulates effort-based decision making. Cereb. Cortex 2007, 17, 251–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Rudebeck, P.H.; Behrens, T.E.; Kennerley, S.W.; Baxter, M.G.; Buckley, M.J.; Walton, M.E.; Rushworth, M.F.S. Frontal cortex subregions play distinct roles in choices between actions and stimuli. J. Neurosci. 2008, 28, 13775–13785. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Botvinick, M.M.; Huffstetler, S.; McGuire, J.T. Effort discounting in human nucleus accumbens. Cogn. Affect. Behav. Neurosci. 2009, 9, 16–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Seymour, B.; Daw, N.; Dayan, P.; Singer, T.; Dolan, R. Differential encoding of losses and gains in the human striatum. J. Neurosci. 2007, 27, 4826–4831. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kable, J.W.; Glimcher, P.W. The neurobiology of decision: Consensus and controversy. Neuron 2009, 63, 733–745. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McClure, S.M.; Ericson, K.M.; Laibson, D.I.; Loewenstein, G.; Cohen, J.D. Time discounting for primary rewards. J. Neurosci. 2007, 27, 5796–5804. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pine, A.; Seymour, B.; Roiser, J.P.; Bossaerts, P.; Friston, K.J.; Curran, H.V.; Dolan, R.J. Encoding of marginal utility across time in the human brain. J. Neurosci. 2009, 29, 9575–9581. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Newell, B.R.; Lagnado, D.A.; Shanks, D.R. Straight Choices: The Psychology of Decision Making; Psychology Press: London, UK, 2022. [Google Scholar]
- Camerer, C. Behavioral economics: Reunifying psychology and economics. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1999, 96, 10575–10577. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hollon, S.D.; Beck, A.T. Cognitive and cognitive-behavioral therapies. Bergin Garfield’s Handb. Psychother. Behav. Chang. 2013, 6, 393–442. [Google Scholar]
- Ertel, W. Introduction to Artificial Intelligence; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Cimatti, A.; Pistore, M.; Traverso, P. Automated planning. In Foundations of Artificial Intelligence; Elsevier: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 2008; Volume 3, pp. 841–867. [Google Scholar]
- Garcia, F.; Rachelson, E. Markov decision processes. In Markov Decision Processes in Artificial Intelligence; Wiley Online Library: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2013; pp. 1–38. [Google Scholar]
- Suppes, P. The role of subjective probability and utility in decision-making. In Studies in the Methodology and Foundations of Science: Selected Papers from 1951 to 1969; Springer: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 1969; pp. 87–104. [Google Scholar]
- Domingos, P. The Master Algorithm: How the Quest for the Ultimate Learning Machine Will Remake Our World; Basic Books: New York, NY, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Poole, D.I.; Goebel, R.G.; Mackworth, A.K. Computational Intelligence; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1998; Volume 1. [Google Scholar]
- Chintalapati, S.; Pandey, S.K. Artificial intelligence in marketing: A systematic literature review. Int. J. Mark. Res. 2022, 64, 38–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Haq, M.A.; Ahmed, A.; Khan, I.; Gyani, J.; Mohamed, A.; Attia, E.-A.; Mangan, P.; Pandi, D. Analysis of environmental factors using AI and ML methods. Sci. Rep. 2022, 12, 13267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Haq, M.A. DBoTPM: A deep neural network-based botnet prediction model. Electronics 2023, 12, 1159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barto, A.G.; Sutton, R.S.; Watkins, C.J.C.H. Learning and Sequential Decision Making; University of Massachusetts: Amherst, MA, USA, 1989; Volume 89. [Google Scholar]
- Chialvo, D.R.; Bak, P. Learning from mistakes. Neuroscience 1999, 90, 1137–1148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Turing, A.M. Mind. Mind 1950, 59, 433–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jayabharathi, S.; Ilango, V. A Brief Revolution of Evolution and Resurgence on Machine Learning. In Proceedings of the 2021 Asian Conference on Innovation in Technology (ASIANCON), Pune, India, 27–29 August 2021; IEEE: Piscataway, NJ, USA, 2021; pp. 1–5. [Google Scholar]
- Bera, S.; Bali, S.K.; Kaur, R. Resurgence of artificial intelligence in healthcare: A survey. In AIP Conference Proceedings; AIP Publishing: Melville, NY, USA, 2023; Volume 2705. [Google Scholar]
- Luger, G.F.; Stubblefield, W.A. Artificial Intelligence and the Design of Expert Systems; Benjamin-Cummings Publishing Co., Inc.: San Francisco, CA, USA, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Ng, A.Y.; Russell, S. Algorithms for inverse reinforcement learning. In Icml; 2000; Volume 1, p. 2. Available online: https://www.datascienceassn.org/sites/default/files/Algorithms%20for%20Inverse%20Reinforcement%20Learning.pdf (accessed on 24 June 2024).
- LeCun, Y.; Bengio, Y.; Hinton, G. Deep learning. Nature 2015, 521, 436–444. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- O’Sullivan, R. Optimising Non-Linear Treatment Effects in Pricing and Promotions. Towards Data Science. 24 May 2024. Available online: https://towardsdatascience.com/optimising-non-linear-treatment-effects-in-pricing-and-promotions-011ce140d180 (accessed on 24 June 2024).
- Lechner, M. Causal Machine Learning and its use for public policy. Swiss J. Econ. Stat. 2023, 159, 8. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sanchez, P.; Voisey, J.P.; Xia, T.; Watson, H.I.; O’neil, A.Q.; Tsaftaris, S.A. Causal machine learning for healthcare and precision medicine. R. Soc. Open Sci. 2022, 9, 220638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hull, P.; Kolesár, M.; Walters, C. Labor by design: Contributions of David Card, Joshua Angrist, and Guido Imbens. Scand. J. Econ. 2022, 124, 603–645. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baker, S.G.; Lindeman, K.S. The paired availability design: A proposal for evaluating epidural analgesia during labor. Stat. Med. 1994, 13, 2269–2278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- VanderWeele, T.J. Commentary: On causes, causal inference, and potential outcomes. Int. J. Epidemiol. 2016, 45, 1809–1816. [Google Scholar] [PubMed]
- Angrist, J.D.; Imbens, G.W. Two-stage least squares estimation of average causal effects in models with variable treatment intensity. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1995, 90, 431–442. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- DiNardo, J. Natural experiments and quasi-natural experiments. In Microeconometrics; Palgrave Macmillan UK: London, UK, 2010; pp. 139–153. [Google Scholar]
- Holland, P.W. Statistics and causal inference. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1986, 81, 945–960. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rubin, D.B. Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized and nonrandomized studies. J. Educ. Psychol. 1974, 66, 688. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kane, L.T.; Fang, T.; Galetta, M.S.; Goyal, D.K.; Nicholson, K.J.; Kepler, C.K.; Vaccaro, A.R.; Schroeder, G.D. Propensity score matching: A statistical method. Clin. Spine Surg. 2020, 33, 120–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Hull, I. Machine Learning for Economics and Finance in Tensorflow 2; Apress: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2021. [Google Scholar]
- Pearl, J. Causal inference. In Proceedings of the Causality: Objectives and Assessment, Whistler, BC, Canada, 12 December 2010; pp. 39–58. [Google Scholar]
- Sekhon, J. The neyman—Rubin model of causal inference and estimation via matching methods. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Methodology; Oxford Academic: Oxford, UK, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Pearl, J. The seven tools of causal inference, with reflections on machine learning. Commun. ACM 2019, 62, 54–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Athey, S. The impact of machine learning on economics. In The Economics of Artificial Intelligence: An Agenda; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2018; pp. 507–547. [Google Scholar]
- Cui, P.; Shen, Z.; Li, S.; Yao, L.; Li, Y.; Chu, Z.; Gao, J. Causal inference meets machine learning. In Proceedings of the 26th ACM SIGKDD International Conference on Knowledge Discovery & Data Mining, Virtual Event, 6–10 July 2020; pp. 3527–3528. [Google Scholar]
- Athey, S.; Imbens, G.W. Machine learning methods that economists should know about. Annu. Rev. Econ. 2019, 11, 685–725. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Athey, S.; Wager, S. Estimating treatment effects with causal forests: An application. Obs. Stud. 2019, 5, 37–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Strittmatter, A. What is the value added by using causal machine learning methods in a welfare experiment evaluation? Labour Econ. 2023, 84, 102412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Crown, W.H. Real-world evidence, causal inference, and machine learning. Value Health 2019, 22, 587–592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Naimi, A.I.; Whitcomb, B.W. Defining and identifying average treatment effects. Am. J. Epidemiol. 2023, 192, 685–687. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Richens, J.G.; Lee, C.M.; Johri, S. Improving the accuracy of medical diagnosis with causal machine learning. Nat. Commun. 2020, 11, 3923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kreif, N.; DiazOrdaz, K.; Moreno-Serra, R.; Mirelman, A.; Hidayat, T.; Suhrcke, M. Estimating heterogeneous policy impacts using causal machine learning: A case study of health insurance reform in Indonesia. Health Serv. Outcomes Res. Methodol. 2022, 22, 192–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Künzel, S.R.; Sekhon, J.S.; Bickel, P.J.; Yu, B. Metalearners for estimating heterogeneous treatment effects using machine learning. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. 2019, 116, 4156–4165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Balzer, L.B.; Westling, T. Invited commentary: Demystifying statistical inference when using machine learning in causal research. Am. J. Epidemiol. 2023, 192, 1545–1549. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kaddour, J.; Lynch, A.; Liu, Q.; Kusner, M.J.; Silva, R. Causal machine learning: A survey and open problems. arXiv 2022, arXiv:2206.15475. [Google Scholar]
- Brand, J.E.; Zhou, X.; Xie, Y. Recent developments in causal inference and machine learning. Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2023, 49, 81–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Statistical Odds and Ends. T-Learners, S-Learners and X-Learners. Available online: https://statisticaloddsandends.wordpress.com/2022/05/20/t-learners-s-learners-and-x-learners/ (accessed on 20 May 2022).
- Rezek, I.; Leslie, D.S.; Reece, S.; Roberts, S.J.; Rogers, A.; Dash, R.K.; Jennings, N.R. On similarities between inference in game theory and machine learning. J. Artif. Intell. Res. 2008, 33, 259–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xu, L. Machine learning and causal analyses for modeling financial and economic data. In Applied Informatics; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2018; Volume 5, p. 11. [Google Scholar]
- Coulombe, P.G. How is machine learning useful for macroeconomic forecasting? J. Appl. Econom. 2022, 37, 920–964. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jung, J.-K.; Patnam, M.; Ter-Martirosyan, A. An Algorithmic Crystal Ball: Forecasts-Based on Machine Learning; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Knauft, B.M. Sociality versus self-interest in human evolution. Behav. Brain Sci. 1989, 12, 712–713. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, L.; Sun, B. Machine learning and AI in marketing–Connecting computing power to human insights. Int. J. Res. Mark. 2020, 37, 481–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zheng, S.; Trott, A.; Srinivasa, S.; Naik, N.; Gruesbeck, M.; Parkes, D.C.; Socher, R. The ai economist: Improving equality and productivity with ai-driven tax policies. arXiv 2020, arXiv:2004.13332. [Google Scholar]
- Khosla, S.; White, R.; Medina, J.; Ouwens, M.; Emmas, C.; Koder, T.; Male, G.; Leonard, S. Real world evidence (RWE)—A disruptive innovation or the quiet evolution of medical evidence generation? F1000Research 2018, 7, 111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kline, A.; Wang, H.; Li, Y.; Dennis, S.; Hutch, M.; Xu, Z.; Wang, F.; Cheng, F.; Luo, Y. Multimodal machine learning in precision health: A scoping review. NPJ Digit. Med. 2022, 5, 171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, R.; Yin, C.; Yang, S.; Qian, B.; Zhang, P. Marrying medical domain knowledge with deep learning on electronic health records: A deep visual analytics approach. J. Med. Internet Res. 2020, 22, e20645. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Schulam, P.; Saria, S. Reliable Decision Support using Counterfactual Models. arXiv 2017, arXiv:1703.10651. [Google Scholar]
- Kuzmanovic, M. Advances in Causal Machine Learning for Health Management. Ph.D. Thesis, ETH Zurich, Zürich, Switzerland, 2022. [Google Scholar]
- Prosperi, M.; Guo, Y.; Sperrin, M.; Koopman, J.S.; Min, J.S.; He, X.; Rich, S.; Wang, M.; Buchan, I.E.; Bian, J. Causal inference and counterfactual prediction in machine learning for actionable healthcare. Nat. Mach. Intell. 2020, 2, 369–375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, L. Causal Machine Learning for Reliable Real-World Evidence Generation in Healthcare; Columbia University: New York, NY, USA, 2023. [Google Scholar]
- Marafino, B.J.; Schuler, A.; Liu, V.X.; Escobar, G.J.; Baiocchi, M. Predicting preventable hospital readmissions with causal machine learning. Health Serv. Res. 2020, 55, 993–1002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Gerring, J. Social Science Methodology: A Unified Framework; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
Generation | 1st Generation (Rational AI) | 2nd Generation (Behavioral AI) | 3rd Generation (Casual AI) | 4th Generation (Human AI) |
Comparative Synopsis | Relies on 100% human rationality, which is proven to be unrealistic. | Lacks real predictive power based on associations not causation and relies on slightly improved models of human behavior that incorporate biases. | Benefits from powerful causal inference statistical methods, but relies on unrealistic models of human behavior. | Benefits from powerful causal inference statistical methods and relies on realistic models of human behavior. |
Model of Human Behavior | Expected Utility. | Behavioral Economics. | Behavioral Economics. | Causal Economics. |
Model of Artificial Behavior | Artificial Intelligence. | Machine Learning. | Natural Experiments and Causal Machine Learning. | Causal Economic Machine Learning. |
Methods and Tools | Linear optimization. | Non-linear optimization using methods such as SLSQP, deployed through standard (non-causal) machine learning tools such as SciPy (1.7.0) in Python. | Non-linear optimization using methods such as SLSQP, deployed via causal machine learning meta-learners (such as S-learner, 0.15.1) in tools such as EconML in Python. | Non-linear objective and constraint functions enforcing cost to benefit causation. Deployed via non-linear SLSQP (1.14.1) (Ex. SciPy) and S-Learner (Ex. EconML). |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Horton, A. Causal Economic Machine Learning (CEML): “Human AI”. AI 2024, 5, 1893-1917. https://doi.org/10.3390/ai5040094
Horton A. Causal Economic Machine Learning (CEML): “Human AI”. AI. 2024; 5(4):1893-1917. https://doi.org/10.3390/ai5040094
Chicago/Turabian StyleHorton, Andrew. 2024. "Causal Economic Machine Learning (CEML): “Human AI”" AI 5, no. 4: 1893-1917. https://doi.org/10.3390/ai5040094
APA StyleHorton, A. (2024). Causal Economic Machine Learning (CEML): “Human AI”. AI, 5(4), 1893-1917. https://doi.org/10.3390/ai5040094