Next Article in Journal
Does Non-Food Cultivation of Cropland Increase Farmers’ Income?
Next Article in Special Issue
Livelihood Capital Effects on Famers’ Strategy Choices in Flood-Prone Areas—A Study in Rural China
Previous Article in Journal
Effects of Water and Fertilizer Management Practices on Methane Emissions from Paddy Soils: Synthesis and Perspective
Previous Article in Special Issue
Effect of Climate Change on CO2 Flux in Temperate Grassland, Subtropical Artificial Coniferous Forest and Tropical Rain Forest Ecosystems
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

How Government Size Expansion Can Affect Green Innovation—An Empirical Analysis of Data on Cross-Country Green Patent Filings

1
School of Economics and Finance, Xi’an Jiaotong University, Xian 710061, China
2
School of International Economics and Trade, Lanzhou University of Finance and Economics, Lanzhou 730020, China
3
School of Business Administration, Shandong University of Finance and Economics, Jinan 250014, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19(12), 7328; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph19127328
Submission received: 17 April 2022 / Revised: 9 June 2022 / Accepted: 9 June 2022 / Published: 15 June 2022

Abstract

:
The expansion of government size will have dual effects on a country’s green innovation. An appropriately sized government size increases marginal productivity and stimulates the development of green innovation by increasing government expenditure. On the contrary, an excessively sized government creates a huge administrative agency, which not only increases the tax burden but also damages social welfare by excessive intervention. Therefore, the effect of government size on green innovation is not linear. In order to prove this proposition, this study examines the impact of government size on green innovation in 166 countries between 1995 and 2018, using a two-way fixed effects model. The results reveal an inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and the level of green innovation, indicating that optimal government size may maximize a country’s green innovation output. The results further suggest that this inverted U-shaped relationship is mainly influenced by environmental regulations and financial support. Finally, our heterogeneity analysis demonstrates that the inverted U-shaped relationship is more pronounced for countries with high organizational inertia and more R&D expenditure than for those with low organizational inertia and less R&D expenditure. This finding makes up for the research gap between government size and green innovation and provides a reference for countries to formulate the optimal government size to improve the level of green innovation.

1. Introduction

Throughout the 20th century, global economic development occurred at the expense of the natural environment. By putting quantity and output value first, the extensive economic growth model of high pollution, high emission, and high consumption ran counter to the sustainable development of society. Decades ago, the Club of Rome in its “Limits to Growth” report warned that “The current economic development model has brought devastating disasters to the world and to humanity itself” [1]. To alleviate the tension between economic development and environmental protection, countries around the world must adopt a green economic development model, characterized by harmony between people and nature.
In the 24th Conference of the Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change in 2018, green technology, green innovation, and implementing the Paris Agreement [2] were put forward as ways to push forward and support the development of a global green economy. In light of this and the ongoing economic shifts from extensive to intensive development, green innovation is at the top of the agenda for all countries.
However, due to its close connection to a multitude of industries, green innovation is highly integrated, flexible, competitive, and risky. Consequently, its development goals may be difficult to achieve if it relies on the market mechanism to maintain the market status quo over the long term. By acting as a “visible hand” to enhance the equilibrium effect of the market mechanism, governments can effectively offset the negative externalities caused by market failures and guide the development of green innovation. Research has shown that factors including government subsidies [3] and legislative constraints [4]. However, no research has touched upon the influence of government size on green innovation.
The term “government size” could be traced back to the French Revolution in 1789. At this time, individuals who supported the king stood on the right side of the parliament while those who supported the revolution stood on the left. The aggregation of the right and that of the left shaped the initial concept of government size [5]. Following the global economic crisis of the 1930s, to address the market failures caused by the overly free market, monetarists (represented by Keynes) emphasized the need for government intervention in the economy and advocated for a larger government and high fiscal deficit to stimulate the economy and maintain prosperity [6]. As a result of economic growth, the political significance of government size faded, while its economic influence became increasingly prominent.
Government size is closely related to a country’s administrative efficiency, economic growth, and social stability. The expansion of government size is based on the principle of economic and social benefits, with the goal of achieving Pareto optimality and optimizing the rational allocation of resources. Furthermore, the expansion of government size is inevitable because of the independence of administrative power, the expansion of social needs, and the expansion of government functions. There are generally three measures of government expansion: the proportion of government consumption in GDP [7], the proportion of government officials in the employed population [8], and the number of administrative agencies [9].
A moderate expansion of government size could better compensate for market failures [10] and guide resources such as funds and talents towards areas in urgent need of development [11], especially in areas with high investment costs and high-risk factors such as green technology innovation [12]. For example, financial support and strengthening of legislative protection could guide more resources to flow to the field of green technology innovation [13,14]. However, the excessive expansion of government size, beyond the critical value, and excessive intervention will inevitably damage social welfare and cause abnormal economic development [15,16], which is similar to the planned economic system.
As the role of government size on a country’s economic development is uncertain, and the impact of government size on green innovation—an indispensable aspect of economic development—is worthy of an in-depth discussion within the academic community. Studies on this topic are vital to support governments, not only to play their role of “providing green technology support and formulating regulations and policies” in green innovation but also to address market failures by forming market-based mechanisms of their own. The latter is particularly important in contexts where the market, or the “invisible hand”, plays a decisive role, while the government, the “visible hand”, leads the way and coordinates with the market. To address this gap, this study draws on cross-country data and empirical analysis to examine the following three research questions. Does government expansion significantly improve a country’s level of green innovation? If so, what are the underlying mechanisms? Will the influence of government size on green innovation vary in response to differences in organizational inertia and the amount of R&D expenditure between countries?
This study makes the following key contributions to the literature. First, this study adopts a different research perspective from previous studies. With regard to government, this study explores the relationship between government size and green innovation by using transnational data—a topic not previously covered in the literature—and is thus both novel and innovative. In addition, while studies on this topic have contended that with the continuous expansion of government size, the level of green innovation in a country presents a nonlinear trend of rising first and then declining, i.e., an inverted U-shaped relationship, we propose that an inverted U-shaped relationship (i.e., the existence of an optimal size of government) is more realistic, in line with objective laws and people’s cognition. Such in-depth research on how government size affects green innovation has both theoretical significance and practical value. Second, the research methods employed in this study expand on those of the literature. Namely, this study uses a two-way fixed effects model to empirically analyze the relationship between government size and green innovation. This model is both scientific and rigorous, enhancing the reliability of the conclusions. In addition, to address endogeneity, the robustness of the benchmark results is tested using Driscoll and Kraay standard errors and systematic GMM estimation. Other methods include the substitution of explained variables, the addition of control variables, the Poisson test, and the negative binomial test. Third, our heterogeneity analysis differs from that of previous studies. Compared with countries with low organizational inertia and less R&D expenditure, the inverted U-shaped relationship is more pronounced for countries with high organizational inertia and more R&D expenditure. This study provides additional evidence for the impact of government size on green innovation and addresses gaps in the literature.
The rest of the study is arranged as follows. The Literature Review section analyzes the theoretical perspectives and formulates our hypothesis. The Data and Methods section introduces the data, variables, and estimation methods, while the subsequent section presents the findings of the empirical analysis. The study concludes with the overall research results and presents policy recommendations.

2. Literature Review

2.1. Factors That Influence Green Innovation

A country’s green innovation is affected by several factors, which can be summarized by the following three aspects: market, society, and enterprise. From the perspective of the market, the profit that a country’s green innovation makes is determined by market costs [17], market risks [18], market supply [19], and other factors. This means that the green innovation capability of a country improves as the market mechanisms of competition, price, and supply and demand become more developed [20]. With regard to society, factors including the ethics of the social environment and interest groups’ awareness of environmental protection [21] provide positive externalities and create a social environment supportive of green production, a green lifestyle, and green innovation. Such factors may provide a country with a comparative advantage when competing in international markets. When it comes to enterprises, the maturity of the green supply chain [22], financial status, and other factors can motivate enterprises to promote green innovation.
However, some studies have found that factors such as excessive resource investment, information asymmetry, and insufficient R&D expenses will largely inhibit the improvement in green innovation output. For example, redundant resources could provide enterprises with the ability to resist external environmental pressures, but excessive resource input will lead to a waste of resources and will reduce the efficiency of green innovation [23]. The intensification of market information asymmetry hinders the information communication mechanism, thereby reducing the commercialization efficiency of green scientific and technological achievements [24] and inhibiting the output of green innovation. In addition, high R&D expenses and financing constraints are the key economic problems faced by enterprises in green technology innovation [25]. The shortage of funds limits the green innovation behavior of enterprises.

2.2. Government and Green Innovation

Research has offered varying opinions on how governments influence green innovation, but these can largely be divided into two opposing views. First, the government can remedy market failures and promote the efficiency of green innovation in a country, and second, government intervention violates the laws of market competition, price, and supply and demand, inhibiting a country’s green innovation output in the long term. Considering this, the following sections elaborate on the impact of government subsidies and environmental legislation on a country’s green innovation.
First is the impact of government subsidies on green innovation. In the market economy, enterprises lack the motivation to work on green innovation due to its externalities. Therefore, to improve green innovation capabilities, government subsidies can counter the insufficient incentives caused by externalities and encourage enterprises to increase their R&D expenditure in green innovation by reducing the costs and risk of doing so [26,27,28]. In other words, government subsidies can encourage enterprises to increase their R&D expenditure in green technology.
However, some research of the manufacturing industry in Europe found that, although government subsidies help to reduce R&D costs for enterprises, they discourage them from investing in R&D on their own, i.e., a crowding-out effect exists [29]. This suggests that governments may fail to have a thorough grasp of corporate innovation, and government subsidies may distort innovation incentives. As such, government involvement may not drive enterprises to increase their R&D expenditure, but rather reduce it, resulting in a crowding-out effect [30].
Second is the impact of the government’s environmental legislation on green innovation. The government of a country can motivate enterprises to protect the environment through the offsetting effect of environmental legislation on innovation. This requires local governments to increase their efforts to improve policies relating to corporate green innovation and alleviate environmental pollution via green technology innovation. Regarding the regulatory effect of the government’s environmental legislation on green innovation, some research pointed out that enterprises prefer to develop and apply clean technologies to control their pollutant emissions and meet higher environmental standards [31]. Similarly, using German panel data, some scholars discovered that administrative capacity, such as laws, regulations, and environmental management, can improve a country’s green innovation output to some extent [32], consistent with the Porter Hypothesis.
However, some studies have shown that the impact of environmental legislation on innovation is not always effective. For instance, some scholars demonstrated that reducing energy costs can bring more benefits to society, but this reduction is unlikely to have much impact on environmental technological innovation [33]. Furthermore, some research also pointed out that strict environmental legislation can promote R&D innovation, but the cost of regulation is far greater than the incremental benefits brought about by such innovation [34,35].

2.3. Hypothesis

Government expansion can also increase public service functions, provide society with “positive externality” public services and products (such as transportation, energy, communication, and other types of infrastructure), and effectively make up for the “failure” and “vacancy” of the market [36]. Furthermore, it can have a positive spillover effect by limiting or eliminating monopoly and supporting enterprise development [37]. Therefore, government expansion can help ameliorate both the internal and external environment of green innovation, alleviate the shortage of capital, talent, and environment required for green innovation, and enhance a country’s green innovation.
However, continuous government expansion can lead to a distorted and ineffective allocation of social resources, resulting in the weakening of the positive externalities of public services [38]. Government expansion may also result in government influence in areas that should be characterized by “governance by inaction.” Indeed, the negative impact of such excessive intervention on green innovation has been noted in the literature [39]. In addition, bloated organs, redundant personnel, power rent-seeking, and other problems caused by government overexpansion have increased tax burdens and aggravated corruption [40], resulting in a crowding-out effect harming green innovation [41] and inhibiting a country’s green innovation output. In other words, with continued government expansion, a country’s green innovation capacity will show an inverted U-shaped relationship (i.e., rising first and then falling). Below, we elaborate on the specific mechanisms of environmental regulations and financial support.
Due to limited resources, small governments are unable to develop macro and all-inclusive environmental policies, but they can provide micro and targeted environmental regulations by enabling public power to control pollution and improve the ecological environment [42]. According to the Porter Hypothesis, scientific and reasonable environmental regulations can upgrade green production technology and enhance the degree of green innovation, thus overcoming the limited effect of regulations [43]. However, based on neoclassical economic theory, formalism and bureaucracy increase as the government expands, inevitably leading to more complex and stringent environmental regulations, such as overly high pollutant emission standards and taxes on pollution [44]. In neglecting real-world conditions, such overlapping administrative regulations result in not only a waste of government resources but a surge in the cost of pollution control for enterprises, consequently draining investment in green innovation. Indeed, it is well-known that as the cost impact of environmental regulations rises [45], the output of a country’s green innovation reduces over the long term.
As for financial support, in the initial stages of government expansion, fiscal policies tend to place greater emphasis on green innovation in production and life, and focus on addressing market failures [46]. This can help enterprises overcome capital shortage, financing constraints, and R&D risks, and stimulate green innovation practices. It can also encourage them to take a more active role in green innovation by compensating for the positive externalities caused by green innovation [47]. In addition, financial support can address the fund shortage associated with enterprises’ pollution control expenditure, enabling them to devote more resources to green innovation. However, undue financial support in the form of subsidies, tax exemptions, or fee reductions can make enterprises over-reliant on the government, and thus green innovation becomes unsustainable as the government expands. Once the government cuts investment, enterprises can encounter problems relating to insufficient motivation for innovation, declining output, and low efficiency [48]. Therefore, we propose the following hypothesis: there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation, all other conditions being equal.

3. Data and Methods

Based on panel data from 166 countries between 1995 and 2018, in this study, we empirically analyzed the relationship between government size and green innovation or, more specifically, whether there is a relationship between government consumption, size, and the number of green patents. Data on government size were taken from the Economic Freedom of the World (EFW) database, which has wide-ranging international influence and applicability [49]. The EFW has compiled data on government size and legal systems of property rights, among others, for 166 countries since 1975, all from third-party sources, and has been widely used in empirical research (e.g., the International Country Risk Guide, Doing Business Report of the World Bank) [50,51]. Data on the number of green patents were taken from the OECD Environmental Statistics Database, which includes country-level data on the environment and green technologies. Data for the control variables were obtained from the World Development Indicators (WDI) database.

3.1. Explained Variable

Green Patent (Patent): Green innovation R&D, application, and promotion rely on a country’s intellectual property system, in particular, the protection of green patents. The number of green patent applications can be used to measure the achievement of a country’s environmental protection and sustainable development [52]. Some scholars suggested that to distinguish between inter-organizational and intra-organizational relationships caused by non-green innovation, green patents should be regarded as an indicator of green innovation [53]. Therefore, in this study, we drew on the studies of some other scholars [54,55] and used the natural logarithm of the number of environmental green patent applications to measure the level of green innovation across countries.

3.2. Explanatory Variables

Government consumption expenditure (Govexpense): Some research discovered that the ratio of government consumption expenditure to GDP can be used to measure the size of a country’s government when studying the relationship between trade openness and government size [56]. Furthermore, countries with higher fiscal expenditures have larger governments, with government consumption expenditure being a major indicator [57]. Inspired by previous studies, in this study, we used the ratio of government consumption expenditure to GDP to measure government size.
Government size (Govsize): According to the definition of EFW, some research proposed that a total index to measure government size can be derived from measures of government transfer, subsidies, investment, taxation, and other sub-indices, as this index not only includes most of the sub-indices related to government size but can also reflect its size in a more comprehensive, complete, and representative way [58]. As such, inspired by previous studies, we adopted the natural logarithm of government size as a second indicator of the size of a country’s government.

3.3. Control Variables

GDP per capita (GDP): GDP is the most important statistic in macroeconomics. While GDP growth can solve problems such as financing difficulties, talent shortages, and misallocation of resources for green innovation [59], it can also increase national income per capita and stimulate social groups’ pursuit of a green life when their material needs are satisfied, thus driving the state, society, and enterprises to strengthen their support for green innovation [60]. Therefore, we used the natural logarithm of per capita GDP to measure the level of a country’s economic development.
Population density (Pop): The impact of population and its distribution on green innovation in a country is mainly achieved through two effects: a scale effect and a combined effect. Due to population, the scale effect can increase requirements for the development of production and life, which in turn encourages the country to solve problems such as resource scarcity and environmental degradation via green innovation [61]. In addition, the geographical distribution of a country’s population is important for green innovation, with the combined effect being brought about by talent aggregation [62]. Thus, we used population density to measure a country’s population.
Human capital (HCI): Human capital, specifically innovative talents, is a key factor in the success of green innovation [63]. As the most dynamic element in green innovation, human capital can not only “increase marginal returns and decrease marginal costs” with investment growth but can also provide an inexhaustible impetus for this. Thus, we used the human capital index to measure a country’s human capital.
Exchange rate (Xr): As one of the main external environmental factors for green innovation, exchange rate fluctuations can change relative prices and competition in the international market [64]. This can encourage enterprises to reduce the cost of importing intermediate goods through technological upgrading, changing original production methods, and accelerating new product R&D, in turn affecting the level of technological innovation in a country [65]. As such, we used the natural logarithm of the exchange rate (domestic currency/USD) as the main external factor of green innovation.
Consumer Price Index (CPI): The CPI reflects changes in the price of consumer goods and is usually used to observe a country’s inflation rate. As the CPI rises, the inflation rate will also increase, meaning that in the process of green innovation, the salaries of scientific researchers and the price of raw materials rise accordingly, squeezing green innovation expenditure [66]. We drew on the research of other scholars and selected a country’s CPI (in constant 2017 USD) to measure its inflation rate.
Capital Price (Cp): From design to R&D, and production to application, green innovation relies on a variety of activities requiring substantial investment, such as market development, production, and management innovation. Reasonable capital pricing can offer green innovation a favorable financing environment and strong capital support [67]. Considering this and following the research, we selected the capital price index (in constant 2017 USD) to measure the pricing level of a country’s green innovation market.
Social financing level (Sp): Innovation investment differs from other types of investment in that it is more likely to be affected by financing constraints. The main reasons are the large amount of innovation investment required, its high uncertainty and long payback period, which can result in internal financing failing to meet the needs of green innovation [68]. In addition, information asymmetry is likely to bring about moral hazard and adverse selection, leading to higher financing costs and harming green innovation output. Inspired by the research of some scholars [69], we used stock prices to measure a country’s financing capacity in green innovation.

3.4. Descriptive Statistics

The descriptive statistics of the main variables are presented in Figure 1 and Table 1. Table 1 shows that the average value of Patent is 2.808 and the standard deviation is 2.325, indicating a wide variation between different countries in terms of green patents. It is important to clarify which types of countries have more green patents. The standard deviation, minimum, median, and maximum values of Govexp are 2.137, 0.029, 6.000, and 12.957, respectively, showing that government expenditure differs greatly from country to country. The maximum Govsize is 2.245 and the minimum is 0.010, demonstrating that government size varies greatly between countries. In addition, we examined the descriptive statistics of the control variables. Taking GDP as an example, the standard deviation is 14.333, indicating a huge gap in the level of economic development between countries. The maximum Pop is 7.264 and the minimum is 0.019, which is in line with practice, and population density varies greatly across countries.
Table 2 reports the correlations between the main variables and their multicollinearity. As can be seen from Table 2, the variance inflation factor (VIF) of the main variables is less than 5, and Tolerance is greater than 0.2, indicating that the variables are independent and cannot be expressed linearly, i.e., there are no multicollinearity issues [70].

3.5. Model Setting

Drawing on the research designs of scholars [71], this study empirically analyzed the relationship between government size and green innovation using the two-way fixed effects approach. This is a useful method, as it can both improve the accuracy of econometric estimates and greatly reduce interference from multicollinearity [72]. The specific model is as follows:
              Y i , t = α 0 + α 1 G o v e r m e n t i , t + α 2 Z i , t + u i + λ t + ε i , t
where   Y i , t is our green innovation variable; G o v e r m e n t i , t is our explanatory variable of government size; Z i , t a vector of control variables that may affect green innovation; u i indicates time fixed effects; λ t indicates country fixed effects; and ε i , t is the error term.

4. Empirical Analysis

4.1. Benchmark Regression

The benchmark regression results of the effect of government size on green innovation are shown in Table 3. Table 3 is divided into two groups: columns (1)–(3) use Govexp, and columns (4)–(6) use Govsize as the measure of government size. All regressions control for time fixed effects and individual-specific fixed effects. In columns (1)–(3), after adding the control variables, the regression coefficients of Govexp and Govexp2 on Patent are 0.114 and −0.016, respectively, and are significant at the 5% and 1% levels. This indicates that the relationship between government size and green innovation is inverted U-shaped. Taking column (3) as an example, if the other control variables remain unchanged, every 1% expansion of government size will increase the output of green innovation by 11.4%; this value is significant at the 5% level when government size is relatively small. When government size continues to expand, every 1% expansion leads to a 1.6% reduction in the level of green innovation, significant at the 1% level. In columns (4)–(6), after adding the control variables, the coefficients of the primary and quadratic terms of Govsize on Patent are 1.224 and −0.490, respectively, both significant at the 1% level. This indicates that a country’s level of green innovation will first rise and then fall with government expansion, i.e., there is an optimal size of government. In summary, with government expansion, the level of green innovation in a country will show a nonlinear trend, demonstrating an inverted U-shaped relationship. Thus, our hypothesis is confirmed.

4.2. Mechanism Test

The empirical results above show that there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation. This raises the logical question of what causes this inverted U-shaped relationship and, more specifically, what are the mechanisms behind it. Following our theoretical analysis, we propose that environmental regulations, financial support, and other mechanisms contribute to the inverted U-shaped relationship.

4.2.1. Environmental Regulations

The influence of government size, as a core explanatory variable, on environmental regulations may affect the scientific quality of the mediating effect. In consideration of this, we use the environmental regulation index to carry out our regression analysis (Er—Environmental regulation index: Data taken from the OECD database. The higher the absolute value of Er, the stricter the environmental regulation requirements of a country). The results are presented in Table 4. As illustrated in Table 4, after adding the control variables, the coefficients of Govexp and Govsize on Er are 0.803 and 1.900, respectively, and are significant at the 1% and 10% levels. This demonstrates that government expansion greatly improves environmental regulations and promotes green innovation. Moreover, the coefficients of Govexp2 and Govsize2 are both negative and either highly significant or marginally significant. This indicates that excessive government expansion and too many strict and overly elaborate environmental regulations may waste government resources and cause inefficiency, i.e., there is a negative externality effect. Thus, a deterioration in the green innovation environment experienced by enterprises may lead to a long-term decline in a country’s green innovation output.

4.2.2. Financial Support

In addition to environmental regulations, government size affects the level of green innovation in a country through financial support. To test this, we use fiscal expenditure (Fs) as an indicator of a country’s level of financial support and analyze the impact of government size on green innovation. The regression results are shown in Table 5. After adding the control variables, the coefficients of the primary and quadratic terms of Govexp and Govsize on Fs are 0.053, −0.007, 0.118, and −0.007, respectively, and are either highly significant or marginally significant. This indicates that as governments expand, to enhance green innovation output, enterprises’ green innovation projects are supported in the initial stages by an increase in financial expenditure. However, excessive financial expenditure may result in a culture of dependency among enterprises, discouraging them from independent financing and self-development and, consequently, inhibiting a country’s long-term green innovation.

4.3. Heterogeneity Test

The theoretical analysis, empirical test, and mechanism test show that there is an inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation. In the context of green development, it is crucial to consider in which countries this relationship is more pronounced and clarify how best to determine the optimal size of government to offset the negative externalities of government expansion on green innovation. As such, we examine this inverted U-shaped relationship based on two factors at the national level: organizational inertia and R&D expenditure.

4.3.1. Heterogeneity Results in Countries with Different Levels of Organizational Inertia

Government size refers to the complexity of the internal and external environment of the government, whereby its influence on innovation is essentially the result of the environment. In this regard, the impact of governments of different sizes on innovation differs, just as different organizational characteristics influence innovation in various ways [73]. Compared with countries with low organizational inertia, those with high organizational inertia lead the way in organizational resources and structure, making the inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation more prominent in these countries.
When the government of a country with high organizational inertia is small, its organization is characterized by great flexibility and high decision-making efficiency. In such a context, there can be smooth communication of environmental regulations and financial support policies between management and technology departments. Both sides can coordinate flexibly, creating an atmosphere that encourages enthusiasm for innovation at the technical level [74]. However, when the government continues to expand, the division of its departmental functions becomes more extensive and mature, leading to high organizational inertia not seen in countries with low organizational inertia. To avoid the sunk and risk costs associated with organizational renewal, governments in such situations place greater emphasis on the predictability and enforceability of the organizational system. The resulting rigidity and other problems can lead to slow or even stagnant organizational change. Moreover, high organizational inertia can contribute to governments being slow to change environmental regulations, financial support, and other policies. As a result, it is likely to cause lock-in and orientation effects on green innovation [75], inhibiting the innovation momentum of enterprises and thus, the rate of green innovation in a country.
In conclusion, different organizational structures have different effects on green innovation. Compared with developing countries, developed nations have higher organizational inertia because they have well-developed organizational structures and cultures. As such, we use dummy variables and divide the sampled countries into developed and developing countries. Developed and developing countries are assigned a value of 1 and 0, respectively. The regression results are presented in Table 6, with Panel A representing the statistics of developed countries and Panel B representing the data of developing countries. In Panel A, when Govexp and Govsize increase, Patent first rises and then falls, which is consistent with the results of our benchmark regression and indicates that the inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation is prominent in developed countries. In Panel B, although the coefficient of Govsize2 is marginally significant, the coefficients of Govexp and Govsize are not significant, indicating that the inverted U-shaped relationship is not obvious in developing countries.

4.3.2. Heterogeneity Results in Countries with Different Levels of R&D Expenditure

A country’s green innovation output is closely related to its R&D expenditure [76]. Compared with countries with low R&D expenditure, the inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation is likely to be more pronounced in countries with high R&D expenditure, as government size does not affect financial support for green innovation in these countries. As the government invests more in R&D, the scale effect and combined effect of green innovation become more obvious, increasing the country’s green innovation output. However, although government overexpansion can provide green innovation with sufficient funds and talent, it can also trigger the threshold effect between R&D expenditure and green innovation [77]. When this occurs, excessive R&D expenditure can tempt enterprises to invest in more radical and riskier green innovation projects. Such risky behavior not only violates the laws of economic and social development but wastes green innovation resources and, in turn, hampers the improvement of green innovation efficiency.
The level of green innovation in different countries is largely determined by the amount of R&D expenditure. To differentiate the level of R&D expenditure between countries, we divide countries in our sample based on median R&D expenditure: countries with R&D expenditure higher than 7.286 are classified as “high investment countries” (denoted by H_R&D), and those with R&D expenditure less than 7.286 as “low R&D expenditure countries” (denoted by L_R&D). The regression results are presented in Table 7. Panel A reports the results of H_R&D, and Panel B reports those of L_R&D. In Panel A, the primary and quadratic terms of Govexp and Govsize are reversed to the regression coefficients of Patent and are significant at the 1% level. This suggests that the inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation is significant in countries with high R&D expenditure, consistent with theoretical expectations. As for Panel B, as the government continues to expand, green innovation output does have a nonlinear relationship. In other words, the inverted U-shaped relationship between government size and green innovation is not observed in countries with low R&D expenditure.

4.4. Robustness Tests

4.4.1. Replace the Explained Variable

In addition to the number of environmental green patent applications, the number of applications for water pollution control [78] and climate change [79] can measure a country’s green innovation level. These variables are denoted by Patent1 and Patent2, respectively. The natural logarithm of all patent applications is included in the regression, and the results are presented in Table 8 and are divided into two groups: columns (1)–(4) use Patent1 and columns (5)–(8) use Patent2 as the indicator of green innovation. In columns (1)–(4), after adding the control variables, the coefficients of Govexp and Govsize on the primary and quadratic terms of Patent1 are positive and negative, respectively, and they are highly significant or marginally significant. This indicates that government expansion inevitably leads to a nonlinear trend, or an inverted U-shaped relationship, in green innovation. In columns (5)–(8), like the results in columns (1)–(4), the coefficients of Govexp, Govexp2, Govsize, and Govsize2 on Patent2 are 0.153, −0.022, 1.267, and −0.543, respectively, and highly significant. This demonstrates that the inverted U-shaped relationship does not change significantly when using a different explained variable. Our benchmark results are therefore robust.

4.4.2. Add New Control Variables

To further verify the robustness of our baseline results, we add new control variables to the original control variables: the proportion of an industry’s added value to GDP (Industry); the proportion of total imports and exports to GDP; and the proportion of scientific researchers to the total population. The results are listed in Table 9. After adding the control variables, the primary and quadratic terms of Govexp and Govsize on Patent are reversed to each other and highly significant or marginally significant. This demonstrates that a country’s level of green innovation exhibits a nonlinear trend. Therefore, the inverted U-shaped relationship does not change substantially following the addition of new control variables. Our benchmark results are therefore robust.

4.4.3. Poisson Test and Negative Binomial Test

Theoretically, the number of environmental green patent applications, as a discrete variable, may not meet the assumption conditions of linear regression models, meaning that the conclusions drawn may not be reliable. As environmental green patents show a discrete distribution, we use the Poisson test and the negative binomial test to further analyze the impact of government size on green innovation. The regression results are shown in Table 10 and are reported separately for each test. We use our original data on the number of environmental green patent applications for both tests. For the Poisson test, the regression coefficients of Govexp, Govexp2, Govsize, and Govsize2 on Patent are 0.193, −0.015, 6.089, and −1.754, respectively, and are significant at the 5% or 10% level. For the negative binomial test, the regression coefficients of the primary and quadratic terms of Govexp and Govsize on Patent are reversed and highly significant or marginally significant. In other words, a country’s green innovation output shows an inverted U-shaped relationship as the government expands. Our benchmark results are therefore robust.

4.4.4. Systematic GMM Test

Although the two-way fixed effects model based on panel data can alleviate the effect of time-invariant omitted variables, it cannot account for the dynamic effect of the explained variable. Therefore, we adopt a two-step systematic GMM test to solve potential endogeneity [80]. The regression results are shown in Table 11, with columns (1)–(2) using Govexp and columns (3)–(4) using Govsize as the measure of government size. In all columns, after adding the control variables, the p-values of the Sargan test and the Hasen test are greater than 0.1, indicating over-identification. The p-values of the AR (1) test are all less than 0.01, which reveals that there is only first-order autocorrelation in the residual sequence of the sample. Therefore, the two-step systematic GMM test is effective. The results presented in Table 11 further indicate two important findings. First, the coefficient of the first-order lag of Patent is significantly positive at the 1% level, meaning that environmental technological innovation is continuous and dynamic. Second, the coefficients of the primary and quadratic terms of Govexp and Govsize on Patent are reversed to each other and significant at the 1% or 5% level. This is consistent with the results in Table 3. Overall, these results indicate that the inverted U-shaped relationship is more pronounced as government size expands.

4.4.5. Driscoll and Kraay Standard Errors

The Driscoll and Kraay standard errors can be used in fixed effects models to overcome heteroskedasticity in panel data [81]. Therefore, we use the Driscoll and Kraay standard errors to test the robustness of the relationship between government size and green innovation. The regression results are shown in Table 12. As revealed in Table 12, after adding the control variables, the coefficients of the primary and quadratic terms of Govexp and Govsize on Patent are reversed to each other and are highly significant or marginally significant. This means that as a country’s government expands, its green innovation level demonstrates a nonlinear trend. This result is consistent with those of Table 3, indicating that our benchmark results are robust.

5. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations

This study examines the impact of government size on a country’s green innovation using unbalanced panel data from 166 countries around the world for the 1995–2018 period. The results reveal that with government expansion, a country’s green innovation output exhibits a nonlinear trend, i.e., an inverted U-shaped relationship. A series of robustness and endogeneity tests show that our baseline results are robust. To determine in which countries this relationship is most pronounced, we use two indicators, organizational inertia and R&D expenditure, and divide the sampled countries accordingly. These two indicators are chosen because they not only reflect government size but also solve the acute problems of scarcity of funds, talent, and markets experienced in green innovation. Surprisingly, the results show that the inverted U-shaped relationship is more pronounced for countries with high organizational inertia and more R&D expenditure than for those with low organizational inertia and less R&D expenditure.
The results of this study are novel. Our research not only finds more factors that affect green innovation from the perspective of governments but also addresses research gaps in the relationship between government size and green innovation using both theoretical and empirical analyses and the perspective of government economics. Moreover, unlike previous linear studies, we find that with government expansion, a country’s level of green innovation has an inverted U-shaped relationship (i.e., there is an optimal government size effect). This finding not only overcomes the shortcomings of previous research and the narrow ideological viewpoints of linear studies, but better reflects the laws of economic and social development. This can, in turn, provide countries with a reference for determining and creating an optimal size of government.
However, restricted by the selection of variable indicators, the two-way fixed effect model selected in this article is relatively simple, which becomes the deficiency of this article and a problem that needs to be improved urgently. In addition, although we examine the inverted U-shaped relationship, we do not include all of the factors that can influence government size, green innovation, and the control variables, such as country’s gross industrial product, education level, etc. This may affect the validity and robustness of our conclusions. Although this research has limitations, it nevertheless provides a useful direction for future studies.
The policy recommendations of this study are as follows. The development of green innovation in a country is inseparable from the shaping of the optimal government size. In particular, it is necessary to optimize the structure of government expenditure, increase investment in public services and infrastructure in the field of green innovation, and create a better investment environment and financial support for green innovation. In addition, in order to prevent excessive intervention of government size on green innovation, the optimal government size needs to build a clean government through budgeting, supervision, and other means; effectively improve the utilization rate of capital, talent, and other resources in the field of green innovation; and prevent resource wasting and damages to social welfare. At the same time, the optimal size of government needs to create a flat, flexible, and highly effective administrative agency to manage the country’s green innovation projects and, as far as possible, similar functions, such as merging business organizations, and avoiding overlapping functions and management confusion caused by problems such as low efficiency and bloated government size in order to better service the country’s green innovation.
Furthermore, for government size—particularly in countries with high organizational inertia and R&D expenditure—there is a need to be cautious about policies that encourage government expansion to reach alarming levels, i.e., the point at which the influence of government size on green innovation turns from positive to negative. The main reason for this is the potential for excessive expansion by the government to eventually lead to even greater negative effects and, consequently, reduce the level of green innovation in the country. In addition, merely relying on government expansion to advance green innovation will not be effective every time. However, it may be possible to reduce the negative effects of government expansion on green innovation by controlling taxation, improving government financing channels, and using other auxiliary measures to build a government with optimal size.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, J.W. and L.L.; methodology, J.W. and L.L.; validation, X.Z. and W.L.; formal analysis, J.W. and L.L.; data curation, C.J. and X.Z.; writing—original draft preparation, J.W. and L.L.; writing—review and editing, J.W. and L.L.; visualization, C.J. and X.Z.; supervision, J.W.; project administration, C.J., X.Z., and W.L.; funding acquisition, J.W. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by General program of National Natural Science Foundation of China (72074176).

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Publicly available datasets were analyzed in this study. This data can be found here: https://www.fraserinstitute.org/economic-freedom/dataset?geozone=world&page=dataset&min-year=2&max-year=0&filter=0; (accessed on 13 September 2021).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship and/or publication of this article.

References

  1. Kuenkel, P. Transformation literacy as a collective stewardship task. Cadmus 2021, 4, 167–173. [Google Scholar]
  2. Harrould-Kolieb, E.R. (Re)Framing ocean acidification in the context of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) and Paris Agreement. Clim. Policy 2019, 19, 1225–1238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Li, Y.; Tong, Y.; Ye, F.; Song, J. The choice of the government green subsidy scheme: Innovation subsidy vs. product subsidy. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2020, 58, 4932–4946. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Smirnova, O.; Strumsky, D.; Qualls, A.C. Do federal regulations beget innovation? Legislative policy and the role of executive orders. Energy Policy 2021, 158, 112570. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Moore, J.N. Freedom and authority: “Right-sizing” government. Cato J. 2020, 40, 1–13. [Google Scholar]
  6. Newman, P. Modern Monetary Theory: An Austrian Interpretation of Recrudescent Keynesianism. Atl. Econ. J. 2020, 48, 23–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Benarroch, M.; Pandey, M. The relationship between trade openness and government size: Does disaggregating government expenditure matter? J. Macroecon. 2012, 34, 239–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bergh, A.; Fink, G.; Öhrvall, R. More politicians, more corruption: Evidence from Swedish municipalities. Public Choice 2017, 172, 483–500. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  9. Doig, A. Good government and sustainable anti-corruption strategies: A role for independent anti-corruption agencies? Public Adm. Dev. 1995, 15, 151–165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Fike, R.; Gwartney, J. Public Choice, Market Failure, and Government Failure in Principles Textbooks. J. Econ. Educ. 2015, 46, 207–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Popp, D. Promoting Clean Energy Innovation at the State and Local Level. Agric. Resour. Econ. Rev. 2020, 49, 360–373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Lim, J.N. The government as marketer of innovation. Eng. Constr. Archit. Manag. 2014, 21, 551–570. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Kiman, K.; Choi, S.O.; Lee, S. The effect of a financial support on firm innovation collaboration and output: Does policy work on the diverse nature of firm innovation? J. Knowl. Econ. 2021, 12, 645–675. [Google Scholar]
  14. Lixinski, L. Trialogical Subsidiarity in International and Comparative Law: Engagement with International Treaties by Sub-State Entities as Resistance or Innovation. Can. Yearb. Int. Law 2018, 55, 1–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Daube, M. Altruism and Global Environmental Taxes. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2018, 73, 1049–1072. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Li, Y.; Cheng, E. Market Socialism in Belarus: An Alternative to China’s Socialist Market Economy. World Rev. Political Econ. 2020, 11, 428–454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Sharmelly, R.; Ray, P.K. Managing resource-constrained innovation in emerging markets: Perspectives from a business model. Technol. Soc. 2021, 65, 101538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Siyu, M.; Yair, T. Licensing of a new product innovation with risk averse agents. Rev. Ind. Organ. 2021, 59, 79–102. [Google Scholar]
  19. Tjahjadi, B.; Soewarno, N.; Hariyati, H. The Role of Green Innovation between Green Market Orientation and Business Performance: Its Implication for Open Innovation. J. Open Innov. Technol. 2020, 6, 173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Ball, C.; Kittler, M. Removing environmental market failure through support mechanisms: Insights from green start-ups in the British, French and German energy sectors. Small Bus. Econ. 2017, 52, 831–844. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Chunkai, Z.; Deng, M.; Xiguang, C. Does haze pollution damage urban innovation? Empirical evidence from China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. Int. 2021, 28, 16334–16349. [Google Scholar]
  22. Novitasari, M.; Agustia, D. Green supply chain management and firm performance: The mediating effect of green innovation. J. Ind. Eng. Manag. 2021, 14, 391–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Rajarathinam, N.; Chandrasekaran, S.; Arunachalam, T. Electronic waste generation, regulation and metal recovery: A review. Environ. Chem. Lett. 2021, 19, 1347–1368. [Google Scholar]
  24. Lampel, J.; Miller, R.; Floricel, S. Information asymmetries and technological innovation in large engineering construction projects. R&D Manag. 1996, 26, 357–369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Kukuk, M.; Stadler, M. Financing Constraints and the Timing of Innovations in the German Services Sector. Empirica 2001, 28, 277–292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Timeus, K.; Gascó, M. Increasing innovation capacity in city governments: Do innovation labs make a difference? J. Urban Aff. 2018, 40, 992–1008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Sein, Y.; Prokop, V. Mediating Role of Firm R&D in Creating Product and Process Innovation: Empirical Evidence from Norway. Economies 2021, 9, 56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Indrawati, H. Barriers to technological innovations of SMEs: How to solve them? Int. J. Innov. Sci. 2020, 12, 545–564. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Mamuneas, T.; Nadiri, M.I. Public R&D policies and cost behavior of the US manufacturing industries. J. Public Econ. 1996, 63, 57–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Marino, M.; Lhuillery, S.; Parrotta, P.; Sala, D. Additionality or crowding-out? An overall evaluation of public R&D subsidy on private R&D expenditure. Res. Policy 2016, 45, 1715–1730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  31. Kuz’Min, M.I.; Kuznetsova, A.N. Ecological-Geologic Risks Related to the Development of Resource Regions. Geogr. Nat. Resour. 2018, 39, 95–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Horbach, J. Determinants of environmental innovation—New evidence from German panel data sources. Res. Policy 2008, 37, 163–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Chamuah, A.; Singh, R. Responsibly regulating the civilian unmanned aerial vehicle deployment in India and Japan. Aircr. Eng. Aerosp. Technol. 2021, 93, 629–641. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Szekely, F.; Strebel, H. Incremental, radical and game-changing: Strategic innovation for sustainability. Corp. Gov. Int. J. Bus. Soc. 2013, 13, 467–481. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Ahuja, G. Collaboration Networks, Structural Holes, and Innovation: A Longitudinal Study. Adm. Sci. Q. 2000, 45, 425–455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Dumbrell, N.P.; Adamson, D.; Wheeler, S.A. Is social license a response to government and market failures? Evidence from the literature. Resour. Policy 2020, 69, 101827. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Havercroft, J. The British academy Brian Barry prize essay: Why is there no just riot theory? Br. J. Political Sci. 2021, 51, 909–923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Amar, G.; Kose, J.; Nair, V.B.; Senbet, L.W. Taxes, institutions, and innovation: Theory and international evidence. J. Int. Bus. Stud. 2020, 51, 1413–1442. [Google Scholar]
  39. Xu, S.; He, X.; Xu, L. Market or government: Who plays a decisive role in R&D resource allocation? China Financ. Rev. Int. 2019, 9, 110–136. [Google Scholar]
  40. Slijepčević, S.; Rajh, E.; Budak, J. Determinants of corruption pressures on local government in the E.U.: Znanstveno-strucni casopis. Ekon. Istraz. 2020, 33, 3492–3508. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Damanpour, F.; Schneider, M. Characteristics of Innovation and Innovation Adoption in Public Organizations: Assessing the Role of Managers. J. Public Adm. Res. Theory 2008, 19, 495–522. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Lestari, E.R.; Dania, W.A.P.; Indriani, C.; Firdausyi, I.A. The impact of customer pressure and the environmental regulation on green innovation performance. IOP Conf. Ser. Earth Environ. Sci. 2021, 733, 012048. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Wang, P.; Dong, C.; Chen, N.; Qi, M.; Yang, S.; Nnenna, A.B.; Li, W. Environmental Regulation, Government Subsidies, and Green Technology Innovation—A Provincial Panel Data Analysis from China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 11991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Khan, S.U.; Shah, A.; Rizwan, M.F. Do Financing Constraints Matter for Technological and Non-technological Innovation? A (Re)examination of Developing Markets. Emerg. Mark. Finance Trade 2019, 57, 2739–2766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Liu, Y.; Li, Z.; Yin, X. The effects of three types of environmental regulation on energy consumption—evidence from China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2018, 25, 27334–27351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  46. Jin, S.; Lee, K. The Government R&D Funding and Management Performance: The Mediating Effect of Technology Innovation. J. Open Innov. Technol. Mark. Complex. 2020, 6, 94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Anwar, M.; Shuangjie, L. Spurring competitiveness, financial and environmental performance of SMEs through government financial and non-financial support. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2021, 23, 7860–7882. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Shuman, Z.; Changhong, Y.; Chen, H. Industry–university–research alliance portfolio size and firm performance: The contingent role of political connections. J. Technol. Transf. 2020, 45, 1505–1534. [Google Scholar]
  49. Coates, D.; Mirkina, I. Economic freedom of the Russian federation. J. Reg. Anal. Policy 2021, 51, 14–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Doran, C.; Stratmann, T. The Relationship between Economic Freedom and Poverty Rates: Cross-Country Evidence. J. Institutional Theor. Econ. 2020, 176, 686–707. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Teague, M.V.; Storr, V.H.; Fike, R. Economic freedom and materialism: An empirical analysis. Const. Politi Econ. 2020, 31, 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Li, X.; Lai, X.; Zhang, F. Research on green innovation effect of industrial agglomeration from perspective of environmental regulation: Evidence in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 288, 125583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Petruzzelli, A.M.; Dangelico, R.M.; Rotolo, D.; Albino, V. Organizational factors and technological features in the development of green innovations: Evidence from patent analysis. Innovation 2011, 13, 291–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Chen, A.; Chen, H. Decomposition Analysis of Green Technology Innovation from Green Patents in China. Math. Probl. Eng. 2021, 2021, 6672656. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Scarpellini, S.; Portillo-Tarragona, P.; Marin-Vinuesa, L. Green patents: A way to guide the eco-innovation success process? Academia 2019, 32, 225–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Pradhan, R.P.; Arvin, M.B.; Bahmani, S.; Bennett, S.E. The innovation- growth link in OECD countries: Could other macroeconomic variables matter? Technol. Soc. 2017, 51, 113–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Ocran, M.K. Fiscal policy and economic growth in South Africa. J. Econ. Stud. 2011, 38, 604–618. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  58. Murphy, R.H. Economic freedom variables endogenous to business cycles. J. Financial Econ. Policy 2019, 12, 65–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Tudor, C.; Sova, R. On the Impact of GDP per Capita, Carbon Intensity and Innovation for Renewable Energy Consumption: Worldwide Evidence. Energies 2021, 14, 6254. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Wen, J.; Deng, P.; Zhang, Q.; Chun-Ping, C. Is higher government efficiency bringing about higher innovation? Technol. Econ. Dev. Econ. 2021, 27, 626–655. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Liu, L.; Zhao, L. The Influence of Ethical Leadership and Green Organizational Identity on Employees’ Green Innovation Behavior: The Moderating Effect of Strategic Flexibility. IOP Conf. Series: Earth Environ. Sci. 2019, 237, 052012. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Liu, J.; Zhao, M. Study on Evolution and Interaction of Service Industry Agglomeration and Efficiency of Hebei Province China. Complexity 2020, 2020, 1750430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Jirakraisiri, J.; Badir, Y.F.; Frank, B. Translating green strategic intent into green process innovation performance: The role of green intellectual capital. J. Intellect. Cap. 2021, 22, 43–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Bae, J.W.; Elkamhi, R. Global Equity Correlation in International Markets. Manag. Sci. 2021, 67, 7262–7289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Katusiime, L. Mobile Money Use: The Impact of Macroeconomic Policy and Regulation. Economies 2021, 9, 51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Hansen, E.G.; Schmitt, J.C. Orchestrating cradle-to-cradle innovation across the value chain: Overcoming barriers through innovation communities, collaboration mechanisms, and intermediation. J. Ind. Ecol. 2021, 25, 627–647. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Colombo, L.; Dawid, H.; Kabus, K. When do thick venture capital markets foster innovation? An evolutionary analysis. J. Evol. Econ. 2010, 22, 79–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  68. Ritter, B.J.R. Innovation and communication: Signaling with partial disclosure. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 1980, 15, 853–854. [Google Scholar]
  69. West, K.D. Dividend Innovations and Stock Price Volatility. Econometrica 1988, 56, 37–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Singh, S.G.; Vasantha, K.S. Dealing with multicollinearity problem in analysis of side friction characteristics under urban heterogeneous traffic conditions. Arab. J. Sci. Eng. Sect. B Eng. 2021, 46, 10739–10755. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Melese, M.B.; Fogarassy, C. Examining the economic impacts of climate change on net crop income in the Ethiopian Nile basin: A Ricardian fixed effect approach. Sustainability 2021, 13, 7243. [Google Scholar]
  72. Wen, J.; Waheed, A.; Muhammad, Y.B.; Hussain, H. Examining the determinants of green innovation adoption in SMEs: A PLS-SEM approach. Eur. J. Innov. Manag. 2021, 24, 67–87. [Google Scholar]
  73. Taghizadeh, S.K.; Rahman, S.A.; Hossain, M.; Haque, M. Characteristics of organizational culture in stimulating service innovation and performance. Mark. Intell. Plan. 2019, 38, 224–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Ashok, M.; Al Badi Al Dhaheri, M.S.M.; Madan, R.; Dzandu, M.D. How to counter organizational inertia to enable knowledge management practices adoption in public sector organizations. J. Knowl. Manag. 2021, 25, 2245–2273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Sanz-Valle, R.; Naranjo-Valencia, J.C.; Jiménez-Jiménez, D.; Perez-Caballero, L. Linking organizational learning with technical innovation and organizational culture. J. Knowl. Manag. 2011, 15, 997–1015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Alexandre, G.; Petit-Romec, A. Engaging employees for the long run: Long-term investors and employee-related CSR: JBE. J. Bus. Ethics 2021, 174, 35–63. [Google Scholar]
  77. Chen, G. Government R&D expenditure, knowledge accumulation, and regional innovation capability: Evidence of a threshold effect model from China. Complexity 2021, 27, 68–85. [Google Scholar]
  78. Henry, H.F.; Suk, W.A. Sustainable exposure prevention through innovative detection and remediation technologies from the NIEHS Superfund Research Program. Rev. Environ. Health 2017, 32, 35–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Urbaniec, M.; Tomala, J.; Martinez, S. Measurements and Trends in Technological Eco-Innovation: Evidence from Environment-Related Patents. Resources 2021, 10, 68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Tauhidur, R.; Chhangte, R.L. A new ground motion model (GMM) for northeast India (NEI) and its adjacent countries for interface earthquakes considering both strong motion records and simulated data. Pure Appl. Geophys. 2021, 178, 1021–1045. [Google Scholar]
  81. Vogelsang, T.J. Heteroskedasticity, autocorrelation, and spatial correlation robust inference in linear panel models with fixed-effects. J. Econ. 2012, 166, 303–319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Histogram of government size and green patent applications.
Figure 1. Histogram of government size and green patent applications.
Ijerph 19 07328 g001
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Variables.
Table 1. Descriptive Statistics of Variables.
VariableObservationsMeanS.D.MinMedianMax
Patent24972.8082.3250.1312.1109.791
Govexp24975.8092.1370.0296.00012.957
Govsize24971.8750.2220.0101.9112.245
GDP249713.10314.3335.33110.90916.831
Pop24973.6594.9430.0192.2177.264
HCI24972.4550.6931.0492.5324.154
Xr24976.4428.7670.0012.19212.870
CPI24970.5090.5180.0840.44223.123
Cp24970.5530.7700.0060.50033.371
Sp24970.4480.5030.0650.36720.322
Note: This table provides the descriptive statistics of the main variables, including number of observations, mean, standard deviation, minimum, median, and maximum.
Table 2. Multicollinearity Test.
Table 2. Multicollinearity Test.
VariableGovexpGovsizePopHCIXrCPICpSpVIFTolerance
Govexp1 2.940.339
Govsize0.6511 2.280.438
GDP−0.107−0.069 2.060.486
Pop0.003−0.0551 2.070.482
HCI−0.486−0.184−0.0531 1.870.534
Xr0.2350.1890.041−0.1961 1.070.936
CPI−0.537−0.306−0.1040.626−0.2031 4.030.248
Cp−0.316−0.220−0.0950.432−0.1280.6461 2.160.463
Sp−0.441−0.271−0.1040.586−0.1840.8310.74814.740.211
Note: This table reports the multicollinearity of the main variables. VIF should be less than 5 and Tolerance should be greater than 0.2, indicating that there are no multicollinearity problems between the variables.
Table 3. Influence of Government Size on Green Innovation.
Table 3. Influence of Government Size on Green Innovation.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Govexp0.086 *0.111 **0.114 **
(1.72)(2.24)(2.28)
Govexp2−0.013 ***−0.016 ***−0.016 ***
(−3.04)(−3.86)(−3.88)
Govsize 0.939 **1.216 ***1.224 ***
(1.98)(2.60)(2.61)
Govsize2 −0.345 **−0.485 ***−0.490 ***
(−2.31)(−3.28)(−3.30)
GDP −0.000 **−0.000 ** −0.000−0.000
(−2.13)(−2.19) (−0.80)(−0.77)
Pop 0.008 ***0.008 *** 0.007 ***0.007 ***
(7.64)(7.59) (6.45)(6.32)
HCI 0.396 ***0.391 *** 0.700 ***0.684 ***
(2.90)(2.84) (5.00)(4.84)
Xr −0.000−0.000 −0.000−0.000
(−0.30)(−0.35) (−0.10)(−0.18)
CPI −0.094 −0.279 **
(−0.77) (−2.20)
Cp 0.032 −0.006
(0.58) (−0.09)
Sp 0.107 0.205
(0.88) (1.60)
_cons2.278 ***0.992 ***0.984 **1.700 ***−0.306−0.192
(14.35)(2.70)(2.57)(4.29)(−0.58)(−0.36)
YearYesYesYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYesYesYes
N182017261720193617971791
R20.4160.4680.4690.3840.4470.450
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 4. Regression Analysis of Government Size on the Environmental Regulation Index.
Table 4. Regression Analysis of Government Size on the Environmental Regulation Index.
VariableErErErEr
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Govexp0.772 ***0.803 ***
(4.47)(4.80)
Govexp2−0.069 ***−0.068 ***
(−4.81)(−4.94)
Govsize 2.379 **1.900 *
(2.28)(1.81)
Govsize2 −0.192 **−0.148 *
(−2.31)(−1.76)
_cons−0.5382.209−5.927 *−1.171
(−1.15)(0.87)(−1.81)(−0.29)
Control variablesNoYesNoYes
YearYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYes
N1444144414451445
R20.3100.3960.2770.359
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 5. Regression Analysis of Government Size on Financial Support.
Table 5. Regression Analysis of Government Size on Financial Support.
VariableFsFsFsFs
(1)(2)(3)(4)
Govexp0.0300.053 *
(1.14)(1.88)
Govexp2−0.006 ***−0.007 ***
(−3.04)(−3.36)
Govsize 0.103 **0.118 **
(2.22)(2.39)
Govsize2 −0.008 **−0.007 *
(−2.08)(−1.70)
_cons3.279 ***3.484 ***2.684 ***2.879 ***
(38.86)(16.24)(18.62)(11.29)
Control variablesNoYesNoYes
YearYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYes
N2361217026172330
R20.3040.3160.3470.349
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 6. Heterogeneity Test: Countries with Different Levels of Organizational Inertia.
Table 6. Heterogeneity Test: Countries with Different Levels of Organizational Inertia.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Panel A: Developed CountriesPanel B: Developing Countries
Govexp0.396 ***0.435 *** 0.0190.077
(4.90)(5.32) (0.19)(0.71)
Govexp2−0.051 ***−0.055 *** −0.007−0.013
(−5.37)(−5.77) (−0.95)(−1.61)
Govsize 4.6086.971 ** 0.9120.874
(1.36)(1.97) (1.44)(1.62)
Govsize2 −1.405−2.084 ** −0.341 *−0.345 *
(−1.44)(−2.03) (−1.72)(−1.89)
_cons3.841 ***1.569 *0.769−2.4511.572 ***0.1150.889−2.741 ***
(19.41)(1.65)(0.26)(−0.79)(4.52)(0.12)(1.51)(−2.81)
Control variablesNoYesNoYesNoYesNoYes
YearYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
N5375375375371283118313991254
R20.6430.6640.6240.6440.3610.4280.3340.346
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 7. Heterogeneity Test: Countries with Different Levels of R&D Expenditure.
Table 7. Heterogeneity Test: Countries with Different Levels of R&D Expenditure.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Panel A: H_R&DPanel B: L_R&D
Govexp0.174 ***0.187 *** −0.169−0.109
(3.36)(3.66) (−0.55)(−0.46)
Govexp2−0.020 ***−0.023 *** 0.0100.005
(−4.55)(−5.22) (0.46)(0.29)
Govsize 0.856 *1.205 ** 0.5480.758
(1.76)(2.52) (0.44)(0.54)
Govsize2 −0.304 **−0.459 *** −0.207−0.164
(−1.98)(−3.00) (−0.49)(−0.31)
_cons2.168 ***1.547 ***1.818 ***0.2502.535 **−0.5451.549 *−2.226
(13.66)(3.90)(4.46)(0.45)(2.25)(−0.16)(1.91)(−0.74)
Control variablesNoYesNoYesNoYesNoYes
YearYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
N1396132815001394424392436397
R20.4570.5060.4050.4720.3450.4410.3400.437
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 8. Robustness Test: Changing the Explained Variable.
Table 8. Robustness Test: Changing the Explained Variable.
VariablePatent1Patent1Patent1Patent1Patent2Patent2Patent2Patent2
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Govexp0.182 ***0.184 *** 0.120 **0.153 ***
(3.01)(3.05) (2.34)(2.97)
Govexp2−0.021 ***−0.023 *** −0.017 ***−0.022 ***
(−4.11)(−4.42) (−3.99)(−5.03)
Govsize 0.7731.013 * 0.949 *1.267 ***
(1.35)(1.79) (1.91)(2.58)
Govsize2 −0.314 *−0.398 ** −0.372 **−0.543 ***
(−1.73)(−2.17) (−2.39)(−3.50)
GDP −0.000 *** −0.000 *** −0.000 0.000
(−4.24) (−3.10) (−0.71) (0.64)
Pop 0.008 *** 0.007 *** 0.007 *** 0.006 ***
(6.26) (5.28) (6.56) (5.32)
HCI 0.715 *** 0.946 *** 0.387 *** 0.565 ***
(4.39) (5.68) (2.78) (3.91)
Xr −0.000 −0.000 −0.000 −0.000
(−0.56) (−0.18) (−0.31) (−0.04)
CPI −0.299 −0.590 *** 0.058 −0.145
(−1.47) (−2.91) (0.47) (−1.13)
Cp 0.066 0.038 0.023 −0.024
(1.04) (0.57) (0.42) (−0.41)
Sp 0.266 0.368 ** −0.033 0.118
(1.48) (2.00) (−0.26) (0.90)
_cons2.120 ***0.0222.010 ***−0.7071.953 ***0.686 *1.486 ***−0.112
(11.13)(0.05)(4.23)(−1.09)(12.11)(1.76)(3.58)(−0.20)
YearYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYesYesYesYesYes
N15131452159414981742164918471714
R20.2430.2890.2170.2800.4840.5310.4450.507
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 9. Robustness Test: Adding New Control Variables.
Table 9. Robustness Test: Adding New Control Variables.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Govexp0.145 **0.152 **0.164 **
(2.30)(2.38)(2.58)
Govexp2−0.017 ***−0.017 ***−0.017 ***
(−3.17)(-3.18)(−3.29)
Govsize 1.111 **1.142 **1.143 **
(2.20)(2.22)(2.24)
Govsize2 −0.337 **−0.331 *−0.332 **
(−2.01)(−1.95)(−1.97)
GDP−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 **−0.000 **−0.000 ***
(−3.09)(−3.05)(−4.15)(−2.13)(−2.16)(−3.32)
Pop0.009 ***0.009 ***0.004 **0.008 ***0.008 ***0.003
(7.90)(7.82)(1.99)(6.67)(6.63)(1.41)
HCI0.014−0.004−0.0070.356 *0.3370.337
(0.07)(−0.02)(−0.03)(1.73)(1.61)(1.61)
Xr0.0000.0000.0000.0000.0000.000
(1.10)(1.15)(0.37)(1.33)(1.35)(0.59)
CPI0.1990.1950.2110.0510.0590.073
(1.34)(1.31)(1.42)(0.33)(0.37)(0.46)
Cp0.0440.0530.0460.0150.0210.015
(0.78)(0.93)(0.82)(0.26)(0.34)(0.24)
Sp−0.111−0.116−0.124−0.004−0.016−0.025
(−0.68)(−0.70)(−0.75)(−0.02)(−0.09)(−0.15)
Industry0.0050.005*0.006 *0.0050.0050.005
(1.60)(1.71)(1.74)(1.43)(1.41)(1.44)
Openess −0.001−0.001 −0.000−0.000
(−1.04)(−1.27) (−0.28)(−0.46)
Emp 0.022 *** 0.022 ***
(3.15) (3.02)
_cons1.211 **1.258 **0.954 *−0.205−0.230−0.482
(2.21)(2.25)(1.69)(−0.31)(−0.33)(−0.70)
YearYesYesYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYesYesYes
N986961961103510081008
R20.4620.4640.4700.4290.4310.437
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 10. Robustness Test: Poisson and Negative Binomial Tests.
Table 10. Robustness Test: Poisson and Negative Binomial Tests.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)
ModelPoissonPoissonNbregNbreg
Govexp0.193 ** 0.233 ***
(2.09) (4.54)
Govexp2−0.015 * −0.028 ***
(−1.71) (−5.93)
Govsize 6.089 ** 4.378 **
(2.39) (2.19)
Govsize2 −1.754 ** −1.301 **
(−2.37) (−2.31)
GDP−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 ***−0.000 ***
(−4.81)(−5.60)(−4.35)(−4.04)
Pop0.008 ***0.008 ***0.008 ***0.008 ***
(5.53)(6.11)(10.85)(8.87)
HCI0.758 ***0.817 ***0.564 ***0.693 ***
(3.66)(4.04)(3.42)(3.97)
Xr−0.000−0.0000.0000.000
(−1.01)(−0.58)(0.29)(0.66)
CPI0.310 *0.357 **−0.293 *−0.565 ***
(1.71)(1.97)(−1.87)(−3.11)
Cp−0.242−0.2830.069 ***0.045
(−0.47)(−0.54)(2.85)(1.59)
Sp0.1340.216−0.1350.043
(0.38)(0.60)(−1.03)(0.32)
_cons−3.426 ***−8.582 ***−2.857 ***−6.378 ***
(−11.05)(−3.86)(−12.04)(−3.61)
YearYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYes
N1720179117201791
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 11. Robustness Test: GMM Estimators.
Table 11. Robustness Test: GMM Estimators.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)
L. Patent0.628 ***0.690 ***0.555 ***0.665 ***
(28.62)(45.32)(17.98)(74.49)
Govexp0.287 ***0.259 ***
(3.61)(4.66)
Govexp2−0.029 ***−0.018 ***
(−3.76)(−2.87)
Govsize 8.874 **11.112 ***
(2.32)(9.80)
Govsize2 −2.167 **−3.028 ***
(−2.07)(−9.77)
GDP0.0010.001−0.0010.001
(0.51)(0.52)(−0.45)(1.61)
Pop0.002 *0.008 ***0.003 ***0.009 ***
(1.95)(3.89)(3.45)(7.62)
HCI0.294 ***0.434 ***0.761 ***0.318 ***
(2.62)(7.42)(4.60)(3.62)
Xr−0.001 ***−0.001 ***−0.001 ***−0.001 ***
(−3.42)(−7.30)(−5.75)(-15.20)
CPI0.465 *-0.319 ***0.608 *−0.231 ***
(1.85)(-3.84)(1.92)(−4.80)
Cp−0.659 **−1.171 ***−0.533−0.547 ***
(−2.10)(−4.47)(−1.49)(−2.95)
Sp0.1821.580 ***−0.1270.679 ***
(1.41)(6.91)(−0.81)(3.77)
_cons−0.213−1.161 ***−9.705 ***−9.919 ***
(−0.60)(−6.14)(−2.62)(−11.11)
YearYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYes
AR(1)-P0.0000.0000.0000.000
Sargan-P0.6971.0000.9871.000
Hasen-P0.1450.3510.1760.439
N1720179117201791
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Table 12. Robustness Test: Driscoll and Kraay Standard Error Test.
Table 12. Robustness Test: Driscoll and Kraay Standard Error Test.
VariablePatentPatentPatentPatentPatentPatent
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Govexp0.086 **0.111 ***0.114 ***
(2.73)(2.97)(2.92)
Govexp2−0.013 ***−0.016 ***−0.016 ***
(−3.51)(−3.70)(−3.66)
Govsize 0.9391.216 *1.224 *
(1.60)(1.93)(1.98)
Govsize2 −0.345 *−0.485 **−0.490 **
(−2.08)(−2.67)(−2.76)
GDP −0.000−0.000 −0.000−0.000
(−1.57)(−1.67) (−0.65)(−0.65)
Pop 0.008 ***0.008 *** 0.007 ***0.007 ***
(9.52)(9.45) (9.01)(8.64)
HCI 0.396 ***0.391 *** 0.700 ***0.684 ***
(3.69)(3.59) (4.87)(4.70)
Xr −0.000−0.000 −0.000−0.000
(−0.37)(−0.43) (−0.13)(−0.23)
CPI −0.094 −0.279
(−0.61) (−1.66)
Cp 0.032 −0.006
(1.50) (−0.25)
Sp 0.107 0.205
(0.70) (1.44)
_cons2.278 ***0.992 ***0.984 ***1.700 ***−0.306−0.192
(27.24)(3.19)(3.15)(3.18)(−0.44)(−0.27)
YearYesYesYesYesYesYes
CountryYesYesYesYesYesYes
N182017261720193617971791
R20.4160.4670.4670.3840.4470.449
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively; Values in parentheses indicate t-statistics.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wen, J.; Li, L.; Zhao, X.; Jiao, C.; Li, W. How Government Size Expansion Can Affect Green Innovation—An Empirical Analysis of Data on Cross-Country Green Patent Filings. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 7328. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph19127328

AMA Style

Wen J, Li L, Zhao X, Jiao C, Li W. How Government Size Expansion Can Affect Green Innovation—An Empirical Analysis of Data on Cross-Country Green Patent Filings. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2022; 19(12):7328. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph19127328

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wen, Jun, Lingxiao Li, Xinxin Zhao, Chenyang Jiao, and Wenjie Li. 2022. "How Government Size Expansion Can Affect Green Innovation—An Empirical Analysis of Data on Cross-Country Green Patent Filings" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 19, no. 12: 7328. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph19127328

APA Style

Wen, J., Li, L., Zhao, X., Jiao, C., & Li, W. (2022). How Government Size Expansion Can Affect Green Innovation—An Empirical Analysis of Data on Cross-Country Green Patent Filings. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 19(12), 7328. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph19127328

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop