1. Introduction
Since its reform and opening up (reform and opening up is a policy of domestic reform and opening up that China began to implement at the Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Central Committee in December 1978), China has made great achievements in agriculture, feeding 1/5 of the world’s population on less than 10% arable land [
1]. It even achieved what was described as “twelve consecutive increases” in food production during the period 2003–2015, strongly responding to the question of “who feeds China”. However, while Chinese agriculture is growing rapidly, it is also facing many serious problems, such as excessive consumption of resources, serious non-point source pollution and the agroecological deterioration [
2,
3]. In order to reverse the unsustainable situation of agricultural development, the Chinese government has introduced a series of laws, regulations and policies to promote green growth (namely, to make resources efficient, clean and recyclable without slowing down the growth rate [
4]) in agriculture. The promulgation of these policies has undoubtedly provided useful ideas and feasible solutions to the dilemma of food security and ecological safety faced by China. It is foreseeable that green growth will become an inevitable trend in Chinese agricultural development in the future.
However, in the process of changing from extensive growth to intensive growth, Chinese agriculture has had to pay attention to the problem of resource misallocation. It is generally accepted that in a perfectly competitive economy, homogeneous factors should have the same marginal returns, otherwise there will be a flow from the side with lower returns to the side with higher returns, and eliminating such gaps will eventually lead to achieving market equilibrium. If factor markets are distorted, the free flow of factors will be restricted, resulting in an inability to be allocated to where they are most efficient [
5,
6]. In this case, the economy would fail to achieve the Pareto optimal allocation and result in social efficiency loss [
7,
8]. According to Restuccia and Rogerson [
9], Ouyang et al. [
10] and Su and Liang [
11], market segmentation, government regulation and lagging factor market reforms can all lead to resource misallocation. Especially in a government-dominated economy, lower factor prices help drive economic growth through increased factor inputs, so distorting factor markets are often used by governments as a policy tool for catch-up development strategies [
6,
12].
The Chinese agricultural sector has been largely dominated by the government in terms of resource allocation, with the flow of resources being regulated, and thus being unable to be allocated to the most efficient side (region or sector). This has led to an imbalance between marginal factor returns and factor prices, resulting in serious distortions in the allocation of agricultural production factors. Adamopoulos et al. [
13] found that under the household contract responsibility system (HRS), rural land is allocated equally, ignoring differences in productivity in agriculture, making the degree of land resource misallocation in rural China worse over time, resulting in a 36–84% loss in additive TFP. Zhao [
14] point out that the Rural Land Contract Law (RLCL) enacted by the Chinese government in 2003 prohibits land reallocation, which, while alleviating labor misallocation, also reduced farmers’ willingness to outsource their land, thereby exacerbating land misallocation and contributing to a 6% loss in total output.
The continuous resource misallocation not only results in TFP loss, but also leads to ecological degradation. On the one hand, lower factor price reduces producers’ willingness to improve the efficiency of resource use through technological innovation, leading to a stagnation of resource-saving technological progress [
15,
16]. On the other hand, a distorted price system fails to reflect the scarcity and opportunity of the cost of resources, and changes in factors of production, in turn, hinder the role of factor markets in optimizing resource allocation [
17]. Based on their respective studies, scholars have found that resource misallocation or factor market distortions can aggravate pollution emissions [
6,
18] and haze pollution [
19], reduce environmental efficiency [
20], green total factor productivity [
21], green technological progress [
22] and energy efficiency [
23]. For instance, Bian et al. [
18] studied the impact of market segmentation on environmental pollution from the perspective of resource misallocation and found that market segmentation has significantly aggravated the misallocation of labor and capital resources, which led to environmental pollution. However, the existing literature is mainly based on provincial or industry-level data, and the spatial spillover effects of resource misallocation affecting agricultural GTFP have not been studied at the city level. To fill this gap, this paper empirically examines the impact of resource misallocation on green total factor productivity in Chinese agriculture using a spatial panel model based on balanced panel data from 306 cities in China from 1996–2017. It is helpful to provide theoretical support for solving the dilemma of food security and ecological safety in China from a resource allocation perspective and also have implications for developing countries with similar resource endowments and facing similar problems.
The paper contributes to the literature in three major ways. Firstly, this paper uses data from 306 cities in China as the research sample. Most of the existing studies on resource misallocation and total factor productivity use provincial and farmer-level data, and there is a lack of empirical studies at the city level. The motivation for using city-level data in this paper stems from two points: On the one hand, it is difficult to precisely capture the spatial spillover effects of resource allocation on the impact of agricultural GTFP due to the huge differences in cropping structure, economic development, policies and resource endowments among provinces. In contrast, there is relatively little variation in various aspects across cities in the same province, thus allowing the interference of external factors in the empirical results to be eliminated. On the other hand, data at the household level are limited by the method of sample collection and the perceptions of the respondents, which may lead to problems, such as sample selection bias. The data at the city level are directly sourced from official statistics, which can effectively avoid biased results caused by data distortion. For this reason, this paper collects a total of 306 cities in China from 1996–2017 as a balanced panel data for the study sample.
Secondly, this paper focuses its research on green growth in agriculture. Existing studies on the impact of resource misallocation on green growth have mainly focused on regions and industries [
16,
20,
21,
23], and the causal relationship between resource misallocation and green growth in the Chinese agricultural sector has not been studied. As the ballast and propeller of economic growth, social progress and national development, the green growth of agriculture determines the bottom line and potential of the country’s livelihood. In this paper, we refer to Chen et al. [
22], Han et al. [
24], Han et al. [
25], Liu and Feng [
26], Tang et al. [
27], Zou et al. [
28], Qu et al. [
29] to account for agricultural non-point source pollution (unexpected output), and then measure agricultural GTFP using a sequential data envelopment analysis (DEA) method to provide indicator guarantees for subsequent empirical studies.
Thirdly, this paper uses a spatial panel model to examine the spatial spillover effects of resource misallocation on the impact of GTFP in agriculture. Existing studies have only considered resource misallocation to local regions or aggregate total factor productivity loss and have not yet focused on the spatial spillover effects of agricultural resource misallocation. Hao et al. [
21] used a spatial panel model to find that resource (labor and capital) misallocation has a negative impact on GTFP in 30 Chinese provinces. However, the study was not on agriculture, and the marginal effects of resource misallocation were not decomposed into direct and indirect effects, making it impossible to distinguish the spillover effects of resource misallocation on agricultural GTFP as coming from the local region or from other regions. Based on this, this paper uses a spatial panel model to empirically test the spatial spillover effect of resource misallocation on the impact of agricultural GTFP, and decomposes the regression coefficients into total, direct and indirect effects. The direct effect represents the net effect of changes in the independent variables in the local region, the indirect effect represents the effect of changes in the independent variables in other regions on the local region, and the total effect is the sum of the direct and indirect effects.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 describes the methods, variables and data.
Section 3 presents panel data test results.
Section 4 presents and discusses the empirical results, and
Section 5 ends with conclusions.
5. Conclusions
This paper empirically examines the spatial spillover effects of resource misallocation affecting agricultural GTFP, based on balanced panel data from 306 cities in China from 1996–2017 using a spatial panel model. The main findings of this paper are summarized as follows.
Firstly, Chinese agricultural GTFP is generally characterized by a “U” shaped change, with a decline (between 1996–2003) followed by an increase (between 2003–2017). Secondly, local resource misallocation hinders the achievement of green growth in agriculture, but labor misallocation in neighbor regions has a significant contribution to GTFP. The heterogeneity test results show that GTFP in the eastern region is more susceptible to negative spillovers from resource misallocation than in other regions, while the decline in GTFP in the central and western regions is noted to be affected by resource misallocation in the region. Finally, the negative effect of local resource misallocation on GTFP does not change depending on spatial geographical distance. In contrast, the indirect effect rises with increasing spatial distance, thus driving the total effect to also show an upward trend.
Based on the above conclusions, the policy implications of this paper are as follows. (1) Chinese government should strengthen agricultural green technology innovation and diffusion. The empirical results show that Chinese agricultural technological progress has shown a continuous upward trend, but the technical efficiency has always been in a deteriorating trend, thus leading to the weak growth of Chinese agricultural GTFP. Therefore, while the Chinese government should increase the research and development of green technologies in agriculture, it should also strengthen the promotion of green technologies and enhance the training of farmers to apply the new technologies in agricultural production. (2) Chinese government should strengthen environmental regulation. In this paper, the excessive use of chemical fertilizer and improper disposal of agricultural straw are the main causes of environmental pollution. Tang et al. [
53] argued that non-point source pollution caused about 6% of agricultural GDP loss. Based on this, on the one hand, the Chinese government should strengthen the propaganda and technical guidance on scientific fertilizer application and promote soil testing and formula technology. On the other hand, local governments in China should stop the burning and abandonment of agricultural straw and introduce new technologies for the comprehensive use of agricultural straw, such as feed and organic fertilizer. (3) Chinese government should promote the free movement of labor between regions and sectors. In this paper, resource (labor, land, machinery and fertilizer) misallocation will inhibit the agricultural GTFP. Therefore, it is urgent to correct the misallocation and promote the effective allocation of resource and factors. Among them, labor is the most important input, because if the rural and agricultural sectors gather a large amount of labor, it will not only lead to labor misallocation but also make it impossible to transfer and concentrate the cultivated land, achieve a large-scale operation, and then cause the misallocation of land, machinery and fertilizer. On the one hand, the Chinese government should eliminate the urban–rural dual structure, realize the equalization of urban and rural public services, and promote the flow of rural surplus labor to cities; on the other hand, the Chinese government should strengthen skills training in rural areas, so that farmers have the skills required to engage in non-agricultural work.
This paper has some limitations, which are as follows: Firstly, in the research sample, this study uses city data, which can directly reflect the temporal and spatial differences of agricultural resource misallocation and GTFP. However, the city data will smooth out the differences in farmers’ preference factors, and it is difficult to reveal the micro-mechanisms that the effect of resource misallocation will have on GTFP. In the future, sample data at the level of farmers or agricultural products can be used to explore in depth the micro-mechanism. Secondly, the Chinese government promises to strive to achieve peak CO2 emissions by 2030 and carbon neutrality by 2060. Although industry is the source of greenhouse gases, rapid development of agriculture also plays an important role, and the carbon emissions caused each year should not be underestimated. In the future, we will consider the relationship between resource misallocation and agricultural carbon emissions.