Towards an Optimal IPO Mechanism
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Experimental Design, Subjects and Procedures and Data
2.1. Experimental Design
2.2. Subjects and Procedures
2.3. Data
3. Results
3.1. The Effect of Offering Discounts on Auction Outcomes
3.2. The Effect of Imposing Capacity Constraints on Auction Outcomes
4. Discussion
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Benveniste, Lawrence M., Alexander Ljungqvist, William J. Wilhelm Jr., and Xiaoyun Yu. 2003. Evidence of information spillovers in the production of investment banking services. The Journal of Finance 58: 577–608. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Benveniste, Lawrence M., and Paul A. Spindt. 1989. How investment bankers determine the offer price and allocation of new issues. Journal of Financial Economics 24: 343–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Biais, Bruno, Peter Bossaerts, and Jean-Charles Rochet. 2002. An optimal IPO mechanism. The Review of Economic Studies 69: 117–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Biais, Bruno, and Anne Marie Faugeron-Crouzet. 2002. IPO auctions: English, Dutch, French, and Internet. Journal of Financial Intermediation 11: 9–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chaplinsky, Susan, Kathleen Weiss Hanley, and S. Katie Moon. 2017. The JOBS Act and the Costs of Going Public. Journal of Accounting Research 55: 795–836. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dambra, Michael, Laura Cesares Field, and Matthew T. Gustafson. 2015. The JOBS act and IPO volume: Evidence that disclosure costs affect the IPO decision. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 121–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Backer, Philippe. 2015. Rebuilding IPOs in Europe: Creating Jobs and Growth in European Capital Markets. EU IPO Report. European Issuers, EVCA, FESE. Available online: https://news.europawire.eu/eu-ipo-report-rebuilding-ipos-in-europe-creating-jobs-and-growth-in-european-capital-markets-65432123456790/eu-press-release/2015/03/26/12/03/52/33106/# (accessed on 1 June 2020).
- Derrien, Francois, and Kent L. Womack. 2003. Auctions vs. bookbuilding and the control of underpricing in hot IPO markets. The Review of Financial Studies 16: 31–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jagannathan, Ravi, and Anne Guenther Sherman. 2005. Reforming the bookbuilding process for IPOs. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 17: 67–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jagannathan, Ravi, Andrei Jirnyi, and Anne Guenther Sherman. 2015. Share auctions of initial public offerings: Global evidence. Journal of Financial Intermediation 24: 283–311. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kremer, Ilan, and Kjell G. Nyborg. 2004. Divisible-good auctions: The role of allocation rules. The Rand Journal of Economics 35: 147–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ljungqvist, Alexander. 2007. Chapter III.4: IPO underpricing: A survey. In Handbook in Finance: Empirical Corporate Finance. Edited by B. Espen Eckbo. Amsterdam: Elsevier (North Holland Publishing Co.). [Google Scholar]
- Lowry, Michelle, Micah S. Officer, and G. William Schwert. 2010. The variability of IPO initial returns. The Journal of Finance 65: 425–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ritter, Jay R. 2011. Equilibrium in the initial public offerings market. Annual Review of Financial Economics 3: 347–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rock, Kevin. 1986. Why new issues are underpriced. Journal of Financial Economics 15: 187–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schnitzlein, Charles R., and Minjie Shao. 2013. Capacity constraints and the winner’s curse in multi-unit common value auctions. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 53: 188–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schnitzlein, Charles R., Minjie Shao, and Anne Guenther Sherman. 2019. Come on in, the water’s fine! An experimental examination of hybrid IPO auctions with a public pool. Journal of Financial Research 42: 5–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Sherman, Anne Guenther. 2005. Global trends in IPO methods: Book building vs. auctions with endogenous entry. Journal of Financial Economics 78: 615649. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shim, Hyeongsop, Junyoup Lee, and Ha-Chin Yi. 2019. Revisiting bookbuilding versus auction IPOs: A perspective of informationally efficient prices in the aftermarket. Journal of Financial Research 42: 491–523. [Google Scholar]
- Wilhelm, William J., Jr. 2005. Bookbuilding, Auctions, and the Future of the IPO Process. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance 17: 55–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | This private information “on management quality, strategy, and the ability to outperform competitors” of an IPO firm is assumed to be held by institutional investors that “spend their careers weighing the conflicting claims and forecasts” (Sherman 2005). |
2 | The intrinsic value (often also referred to as fair value) of a firm that goes public is eventually revealed in the secondary market as public information is incorporated in the stock price, but is not fully revealed in the primary market given the limited number of participants that set the price in that market. |
3 | Depending on the size of the IPO, only about 100–200 institutional investors are invited as they expect the investment banks to set up a physical meeting with the top management of the IPO firm. These road shows are limited to a maximum of ten business days, thereby constraining the number of participants in book building. |
4 | Ljungqvist (2007, page 378) notes: “Since the 1960s, this ‘underpricing discount’ has averaged around 19% in the United States, suggesting that firms leave considerable amounts of money on the table.” |
5 | Ritter (2011) also presents evidence of the occurrence of what he refers to as CLAS controversies: “C is the payment of excessive commissions by investors as a way of currying favor for IPO allocations. L is laddering, the practice of allocating shares in return for promises of additional purchases once the stock starts trading. A is biased analyst recommendations, with underwriters competing for business from issuers by either implicitly or explicitly promising favorable coverage from their research analysts. S is spinning, the practice of allocating shares from other IPOs to the personal brokerage accounts of issuing firm executives in return for investment banking business from the executives’ company.” |
6 | Free riders put in unrealistically high bids in order to increase the probability of an allocation on the assumption that these bids will not inflate the offer price far above the price that will come about when IPO shares subsequently start trading on the stock market. |
7 | This outcome is often referred to in the literature as efficient pricing (e.g., Schnitzlein and Shao 2013; Biais and Faugeron-Crouzet 2002) where the efficiency of price discovery is measured by both the deviation of the auction clearing price from the intrinsic value (i.e., valuation accuracy) and the standard deviation of this measure (i.e., reliability). |
8 | We assume that institutional investors are endowed with private information pertaining to IPO valuation (Ritter 2011; Rock 1986) and therefore—different from Schnitzlein et al. (2019)—we did not offer investors the choice to purchase the price signal to improve their valuation accuracy nor the choice of non-participation in the auctions. We note that Schnitzlein et al. (2019) found that there is no significant difference in both the rate of information purchase nor of participation across treatments. Both rates are close to 100%. |
9 | If the intrinsic value was 21, the investors would have suffered a loss of 1.08 per share. |
10 | We find no significant difference between the outcomes of the auctions with a low versus mid capacity constraints. More importantly, given the payoff of respectively −1.44 (SD 64.374) and 5.28 (SD 74.253), both these auctions did not provide a reliable incentive for investor participation. |
11 | According to Jagannathan et al. (2015) who surveyed internationally used auction mechanisms, both the US and France used uniform price auctions with discounts on the auction clearing price. |
12 | Schnitzlein and Shao (2013) did not report underpricing but instead auction revenue—the number of shares sold times the auction clearing price. |
Capacity Constraint | |||
---|---|---|---|
Discount | Low | Mid | High |
low | 1 | 2 | 3 |
mid | 4 | 5 | 6 |
high | 7 | 8 | 9 |
Investor | Identity | Price | Shares | Cumulative |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | large | 29 | 11 | 11 |
2 | small | 28 | 2 | 13 |
1 | large | 27 | 4 | 17 |
2 | small | 26 | 1 | 18 |
3 | large | 25 | 11 | 29 |
4 | small | 24 | 2 | 31 |
3 | large | 23 | 4 | 35 |
4 | small | 22 | 1 | 36 |
5 | large | 21 | 10 | 46 |
6 | small | 20 | 2 | 48 |
5 | large | 19 | 5 | 53 |
6 | small | 18 | 1 | 54 |
7 | large | 17 | 9 | 63 |
8 | small | 16 | 1 | 64 |
7 | large | 15 | 6 | 70 |
8 | small | 14 | 2 | 72 |
9 | small | 13 | 1 | 73 |
9 | small | 12 | 2 | 75 |
Variable | N | Mean | Std. Deviation | Minimum | Maximum |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
UP | 90 | 3.605% | 11.309% | −33.333% | 41.333% |
payoff | 90 | 19.160 | 64.074 | −240.000 | 150.000 |
freq | 90 | 52.758% | 11.888% | 22.222% | 78.000% |
error | 90 | 1.444 | 1.415 | 0.000 | 8.000 |
allocat_large | 90 | 22.056 | 3.406 | 10.000 | 29.000 |
allocat_small | 90 | 7.944 | 3.406 | 1.000 | 20.000 |
Discount_Dummy * | N | Mean | Std. Deviation | Std. Error Mean | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
UP | 0 | 30 | −3.340% | 10.357% | 1.891% |
1 | 60 | 7.078% | 10.169% | 1.313% | |
payoff | 0 | 30 | −23.000 | 67.627 | 12.347 |
1 | 60 | 40.239 | 50.886 | 6.569 | |
freq | 0 | 30 | 55.681% | 12.563% | 2.294% |
1 | 60 | 51.296% | 11.361% | 1.467% | |
error | 0 | 30 | 1.633 | 1.712 | 0.313 |
1 | 60 | 1.350 | 1.246 | 0.161 | |
allocat_large | 0 | 30 | 20.433 | 4.006 | 0.731 |
1 | 60 | 22.867 | 2.758 | 0.356 | |
allocat_small | 0 | 30 | 9.567 | 4.006 | 0.731 |
1 | 60 | 7.133 | 2.758 | 0.356 |
Levene’s Test Equality of Variances | t-Test Equality of Means | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable | Assumption | F | Sig. | t | df | Sig. 2 Tail | Mean Diff. |
UP | Equal variances assumed | 0.493 | 0.484 | −4.554 | 88 | 0.000 | −10.418% |
Equal variances not assumed | −4.526 | 57 | 0.000 | −10.418% | |||
payoff | Equal variances assumed | 3.053 | 0.084 | −4.966 | 88 | 0.000 | −63.239 |
Equal variances not assumed | −4.522 | 46 | 0.000 | −63.239 | |||
freq | Equal variances assumed | 1.277 | 0.262 | 1.666 | 88 | 0.099 | 4.385% |
Equal variances not assumed | 1.611 | 53 | 0.113 | 4.385% | |||
error | Equal variances assumed | 1.711 | 0.194 | 0.894 | 88 | 0.374 | 0.283 |
Equal variances not assumed | 0.806 | 45 | 0.424 | 0.283 | |||
allocat_large | Equal variances assumed | 3.117 | 0.081 | −3.376 | 88 | 0.001 | −2.433 |
Equal variances not assumed | −2.991 | 43 | 0.005 | −2.433 | |||
allocat_small | Equal variances assumed | 3.117 | 0.081 | 3.376 | 88 | 0.001 | 2.433 |
Equal variances not assumed | 2.991 | 43 | 0.005 | 2.433 |
Midlow_Dummy * | N | Mean | Std. Deviation | Std. Error Mean | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
UP | 1 | 30 | 6.439% | 12.567% | 2.294% |
2 | 30 | 7.716% | 7.185% | 1.312% | |
payoff | 1 | 30 | 31.839 | 58.439 | 10.669 |
2 | 30 | 48.640 | 41.315 | 7.543 | |
freq | 1 | 30 | 47.778% | 11.543% | 2.108% |
2 | 30 | 54.815% | 10.185% | 1.859% | |
error | 1 | 30 | 1.47 | 1.383 | 0.252 |
2 | 30 | 1.23 | 1.104 | 0.202 | |
allocat_large | 1 | 30 | 23.03 | 2.593 | 0.473 |
2 | 30 | 22.70 | 2.950 | 0.539 | |
allocat_small | 1 | 30 | 6.97 | 2.593 | 0.473 |
2 | 30 | 7.30 | 2.950 | 0.539 |
Levene’s Test Equality of Variances | t-Test Equality of Means | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable | Assumption | F | Sig. | t | df | Sig. 2 Tail | Mean Diff. |
UP | Equal variances assumed | 3.734 | 0.058 | −0.483 | 58 | 0.631 | −1.277% |
Equal variances not assumed | −0.483 | 46 | 0.631 | −1.277% | |||
payoff | Equal variances assumed | 2.185 | 0.145 | −1.286 | 58 | 0.204 | −16.801 |
Equal variances not assumed | −1.286 | 52 | 0.204 | −16.801 | |||
freq | Equal variances assumed | 0.052 | 0.820 | −2.504 | 58 | 0.015 | −7.037% |
Equal variances not assumed | −2.504 | 57 | 0.015 | −7.037% | |||
error | Equal variances assumed | 2.165 | 0.147 | 0.722 | 58 | 0.473 | 0.233 |
Equal variances not assumed | 0.722 | 55 | 0.473 | 0.233 | |||
allocat_large | Equal variances assumed | 1.198 | 0.278 | 0.465 | 58 | 0.644 | 0.333 |
Equal variances not assumed | 0.465 | 57 | 0.644 | 0.333 | |||
allocat_small | Equal variances assumed | 1.198 | 0.278 | −0.465 | 58 | 0.644 | −0.333 |
Equal variances not assumed | −0.465 | 57 | 0.644 | −0.333 |
Constraint_Dummy * | N | Mean | Std. Deviation | Std. Error Mean | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
UP | 0 | 60 | 0.285% | 11.085% | 1.431% |
1 | 30 | 10.245% | 8.607% | 1.571% | |
payoff | 0 | 60 | 1.920 | 68.969 | 8.904 |
1 | 30 | 53.639 | 32.825 | 5.993 | |
freq | 0 | 60 | 54.415% | 12.163% | 1.570% |
1 | 30 | 49.444% | 10.756% | 1.964% | |
error | 0 | 60 | 1.667 | 1.580 | 0.204 |
1 | 30 | 1.000 | 0.871 | 0.159 | |
allocat_large | 0 | 60 | 21.483 | 3.877 | 0.501 |
1 | 30 | 23.200 | 1.730 | 0.316 | |
allocat_small | 0 | 60 | 8.517 | 3.877 | 0.501 |
1 | 30 | 6.800 | 1.730 | 0.316 |
Levene’s Test Equality of Variances | t-Test Equality of Means | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Variable | Assumption | F | Sig. | t | df | Sig. 2 Tail | Mean Diff. |
UP | Equal variances assumed | 3.797 | 0.055 | −4.310 | 88 | 0.000 | −9.960% |
Equal variances not assumed | −4.686 | 73 | 0.000 | −9.960% | |||
payoff | Equal variances assumed | 10.709 | 0.002 | −3.885 | 88 | 0.000 | −51.719 |
Equal variances not assumed | −4.819 | 88 | 0.000 | −51.719 | |||
freq | Equal variances assumed | 0.658 | 0.420 | 1.897 | 88 | 0.061 | 4.970% |
Equal variances not assumed | 1.977 | 65 | 0.052 | 4.970% | |||
error | Equal variances assumed | 10.495 | 0.002 | 2.149 | 88 | 0.034 | 0.667 |
Equal variances not assumed | 2.577 | 87 | 0.012 | 0.667 | |||
allocat_large | Equal variances assumed | 12.944 | 0.001 | −2.308 | 88 | 0.023 | −1.717 |
Equal variances not assumed | −2.900 | 87 | 0.005 | −1.717 | |||
allocat_small | Equal variances assumed | 12.944 | 0.001 | 2.308 | 88 | 0.023 | 1.717 |
Equal variances not assumed | 2.900 | 87 | 0.005 | 1.717 |
Constraint_Dummy * | N | Mean | Std. Deviation | Std. Error Mean | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
UP | 0 | 40 | 4.137% | 9.519% | 1.505% |
1 | 20 | 12.958% | 8.974% | 2.007% | |
payoff | 0 | 40 | 27.630 | 55.013 | 8.698 |
1 | 20 | 65.458 | 28.714 | 6.421 | |
freq | 0 | 40 | 52.778% | 11.667% | 1.845% |
1 | 20 | 48.333% | 10.370% | 2.319% | |
error | 0 | 40 | 1.525 | 1.377 | 0.218 |
1 | 20 | 1.000 | 0.858 | 0.192 | |
allocat_large | 0 | 40 | 22.550 | 3.121 | 0.493 |
1 | 20 | 23.500 | 1.732 | 0.387 | |
allocat_small | 0 | 40 | 7.450 | 3.121 | 0.493 |
1 | 20 | 6.500 | 1.732 | 0.387 |
© 2020 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Huibers, F.E. Towards an Optimal IPO Mechanism. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2020, 13, 115. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm13060115
Huibers FE. Towards an Optimal IPO Mechanism. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2020; 13(6):115. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm13060115
Chicago/Turabian StyleHuibers, Fred E. 2020. "Towards an Optimal IPO Mechanism" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 13, no. 6: 115. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm13060115
APA StyleHuibers, F. E. (2020). Towards an Optimal IPO Mechanism. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 13(6), 115. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm13060115