Next Article in Journal
Participatory Governance as a Success Factor in Equity Crowdfunding Campaigns for Cultural Heritage
Next Article in Special Issue
A Stochastic Markov Chain for Estimating New Entrants into Professional Pension Funds
Previous Article in Journal
Bank Credit and Trade Credit: The Case of Portuguese SMEs from 2010 to 2019
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Effects of Securitization for Managing Banking Risk Using Alternative Tranching Schemes
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Stability and Bifurcations in Banks and Small Enterprises—A Three-Dimensional Continuous-Time Dynamical System

Department of Economics and Business Science, University of Cagliari, Via Sant’Ignazio 17, 09123 Cagliari, Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16(3), 171; https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16030171
Submission received: 20 December 2022 / Revised: 19 February 2023 / Accepted: 28 February 2023 / Published: 3 March 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue The Future of Banking Risk and Regulation)

Abstract

:
Here, we discuss a three-dimensional continuous-time Lotka–Volterra dynamical system, which describes the role of government in interactions with banks and small enterprises. In Italy, during the COVID-19 emergency, the main objective of government economic intervention was to maintain the proper operation of the bank–enterprise system. We also review the effectiveness of measures introduced in response to the COVID-19 pandemic lockdowns to avoid a further credit crunch. By applying bifurcation theory to the system, we were able to produce evidence of the existence of Hopf and zero-Hopf bifurcating periodic solutions from a saddle focus in a special region of the parameter space, and we performed a numerical analysis.

1. Introduction

In this paper, we consider a three-dimensional continuous-time Lotka–Volterra dynamical system (see Bischi and Tramontana (2010) for a discrete case), which describes the role of government in interactions with banks and small enterprises. This work follows up on other contributions in the literature that discuss the credit crunch and its effects on the bank–enterprise dynamical system (Ditzen 2018; Liu and Fan 2017; Marasco et al. 2016; Tsai 2017; Wang et al. 2018; Wei et al. 2018; Desogus and Venturi 2019).
Interactions between banks and enterprises are highly complex and nonlinear. Due to regulations, financial institutions, especially commercial banks, can only engage in financial intermediation. Their operations therefore depend on the caliber and financial standing of their clientele. Where lending strategies are based on credit risk and profit criteria, banks conduct thorough assessments of each counterparty before disbursing loans. Each calculated weighting of the aggregation of segmented units is recorded in the bank’s risk portfolios. Likewise, businesses require bank credit to support investments and keen management to account for the inherent disparities of their working capital. Concurrently, businesses generate positive flows for the banking system, either through income creation, a proportion of which is deposited in banks and supplies banks with funds, or intermediation charges that provide bank revenue.
When bank leverage falls below a certain threshold (Desogus and Venturi 2019), its power to intervene is reduced as its role changes. The resulting reduction in supervisory provisions, greater availability of liquidity, and increased containment of portfolio risk indicators is often perceived to be a positive, short-term phenomenon. Increasingly acute over time, however, excessive credit restrictions tend to harm the positive environmental factors that help maintain a productive enterprise system (Rozendaal et al. 2016).
In this work, we improve the analysis of the bank–enterprise two-dynamical system. (see Desogus and Venturi 2019; Desogus and Casu 2020b). Indeed, we have noted the significance of positive effects generated by an efficient banking sector that provides liquidity to the business sector so that the banks themselves are kept healthy and performing (Iyer et al. 2014). We have also found that negative effects are produced by the failure of this situation, and we scrutinized the effectiveness of measures introduced in response to the COVID-19 pandemic lockdowns to avoid a further credit crunch. Such critical events could have occurred because of the generalized impairment of creditworthiness following the nationwide stoppages (Caggiano et al. 2017; Petrosky-Nadeau 2013); therefore, we examined the further development of critical default trends in the populations of enterprises and banks in Italy.
Most of the research and studies have been investigated how government interventions aimed at supporting bank lending to the productive sector have indeed developed analyses and considerations on measures that affect bank capitalization, that is, direct injections of liquidity into the system aimed at stimulating credit operations for companies (cf. Laeven and Valencia 2013; cf. also Tan et al. 2020). In contrast, this paper instead questions the effects of government intervention strategies based on guarantee measures, while at the same time, it considers certain scenarios characterized by financial crises and measures aimed at counteracting a credit crunch. Such measures are implemented through nominal ceiling allocations, which do not imply an immediate monetary transfer from the government to the banks, bringing with it (also) advantages in public accounting. In particular, we analyze a form of state intervention in business that is accompanied by a government guarantee, up to full coverage even in borderline cases, and zero weighting of bank provisions on the portion guaranteed by the fund, which when structured as they have been—with their immediate enforceability ensured—entails a significant mitigation of the banks’ credit risks.
This work currently represents an innovation in the recent scientific literature, both because of its approach, which is due to its conceptual choice of constructing and using mathematical models emanating from Lotka–Volterra dynamical systems in continuous time for the analysis of the topic, and because of its relevant ability to provide results capable of describing the complex solutions of the system. At the same time, these models succeed in intercepting the instantaneous variations caused by the persistence of the interconnections between banks, enterprises and government in the broader economic activity aimed at wealth production. The structure of the system is supported by a large database and records on business demographics and bank credit flows for Italy and the United Kingdom, which were collected, systematized and broken down into total disbursement volumes and NPLs, which confirm the general outcomes of our system of equations.
This paper goes so far as to establish that government support of bank lending through the provision of public loan guarantees may represent a best practice, particularly in contrast to the side effects of financial crises on the deleveraging of firms by banks. By replicating the examples presented in this paper, the mathematical model proposed can also be used as a tool for measuring the proper implementation of newly established guarantee funds. From a mathematical point of view, we use bifurcation theory (Nishimura and Shigoka 2019; Zhao and Zhao 2016; Neri and Venturi 2007) to confirm the behavior of the dynamic solutions generated by these governments acts against credit restrictions, as empirically observed in the data. Some numerical simulation is presented.

2. The Dataset

Data from Italy relating to time intervals included in the second decade of the 2000s (the precise period is indicated in the caption of each table and figure; see Table 1, Table 2, Table 3 and Table 4) illustrate the correlation between the contraction of credit—especially what was made available to micro and small enterprises—and an increase in the mortality rate of those enterprises affected. As a consequence, this relationship also brought about increased levels of impaired credit.
Table 1 depicts the progressive reduction in loan disbursements, which we have deemed an independent variable. Adverse consequences to stakeholders in the production sector can be tied to this downward trend. Crucially, however, Table 2 and Table 3 show the disparate impacts of the credit crunch on enterprises of different sizes: whilst established micro enterprises exited the market more readily than new companies of a similar size, macro enterprises remained relatively unaffected (Bassetto et al. 2015). Indeed, based on the data in Table 1 and Table 2, the correlation between the reduction in credit granted to the productive sector and the active population of SMEs is +0.73. The aggregate number of viable small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in the market is only marginally corrected by the incidence of macro-enterprises.
Considered alongside each other, Table 1 and the negative relationship just outlined further correlate with the rise in net non-performing loans (NPLs) prior to the first quarter of 2017, whilst the data in Table 1 and Table 4 generate a Bravais–Pearson coefficient of −0.57 for March 2017. Where data in Table 5 on the number of impaired loans from June 2017 to September 2019 may suggest a pivot to a downward trend, the shift was in fact caused by the European Central Bank guidelines, announced in March 2017, to incentivize the sale of NPLs and strengthen monitoring processes (European Central Bank 2017). The responses by banks to these measures are reflected in the provisions and losses recorded in their financial statements. According to 2018 and 2019 reports by the ABI (Italian Banking Association) (ABI-Cerved 2018a, 2018b, 2019b, 2019a), disposals ranged from EUR 50 to 70 billion per period. In fact, the estimated outlook for the 2020 to 2021 period, prior to the COVID-19 emergency, forecast renewed increases in NPLs (ABI-Cerved 2019a).
Framed as businesses with strategic plans for profit maximization, banks thus continue to covet corporate savings, whilst at the same time they implement risk reduction methods while absorbing risk capital. This entails reducing credit availability, which diminishes short-term guarantee assets and administrative costs. Weakening the resilience of the system, this strategic framework tends to undermine the growth potential of the enterprise population and its ability to maintain stable mortality and birth rates.
The trickle-down effects, however, result in losses for banks caused by reduced funds from deposits and increased costs from impaired assets and net losses (Bernanke et al. 1994; Wehinger 2014). Where companies are also the source of salary payments and income for employees—and, by extension, of the entire economic system—these adverse consequences can pro-cyclically affect macroeconomic conditions on a national scale (Buera et al. 2015).
Moving away from the dynamics of periodic stocks, the graph in Figure 1, which is based on data from Table 1, Table 2, Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5, tracks the percentage change in recorded monthly flows in terms of credit disbursed, demographic rate of enterprises (or the ratio of enterprises entering to those leaving the market), and the number of NPLs in Italy from 2012 to 2018. The data for NPLs only cover the first quarter of 2017, in light of our earlier discussion of regulatory changes for NPL management. Alongside the natural time lag caused by the macro-complexity of the objects analyzed (Kurkina 2017), Figure 1 confirms that the contraction of credit granted by banks to maximize their profit margins can be correlated with a progressive decline in (performing) firms in the market and with a general increase in NPLs. Recovering this disbursed credit will also catalyze a reversal of recent trends for NPLs and enterprises.
This reasoning, of course, has greater validity and application for banks operating primarily in the credit market, as a simultaneous diversification of assets would mitigate the cause-and-effect mechanism of the considerations discussed (Baldini and Causi 2020). To confirm our empirical conclusions, a comparative survey of similar data from the United Kingdom (UK) was conducted. Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8 detail the value of loans disbursed, business demographics and the conditions of NPLs in the UK. In addition, in this case, the datasets relate to time intervals included in the second decade of the 2000s (and, similarly to what was noted for the Italian data, the precise period is indicated in the caption of each table and figure). Because it is situated outside the euro area, the UK was taken as a comparative reference. In this case, we considered micro, small, and medium-sized enterprises (mSME), according to the provisions of the European taxonomic framework. As was observed in Italy, the UK study showed an inverse correlation between the amount of loans disbursed and the number of companies performing in the UK market. This, in turn, correlated with the level of NPLs for the period, accounting for the adjustment delay.
In particular, we examined the effects of the bank rescue package of GBP 50 billion, which was issued by the British government in response to the 2009 to 2010 financial crisis and recession (Wong 2009). Where the package was designed to increase the amount of money available for banks to lend, Figure 2 highlights simultaneous regrowth of loan disbursements, recovery of the enterprise population and a decline in NPLs in the first months of 2012.
These trends in the UK economy confirm that ad hoc government intervention that supports the provision of credit to SMEs has a positive impact on the productive fabric. By mitigating, and even negating, the effects of a credit crunch, the intervention helped to stabilize the banking system and prevented the stratification of impaired positions and NPLs in loan portfolios.

3. The General Model

We would now like to consider a purely dynamical nonlinear system:
z ˙ 1 = f ( z 1 , z 2 , z 3 )
z ˙ 2 = g ( z 1 , z 2 , z 3 )
z ˙ 3 = h ( z 1 , z 2 , z 3 )
where the independent state variables are z 1 , z 2 and z 3 ; z 1 represents the population of banks, z 2 represents the enterprises, and z 3 the government intervention. Equation (1) thus describes the traditional imbalance caused by dynamic adjustments in the production market (Calcagnini et al. 2019). Equation (2) refers to the corresponding imbalance in the credit market and repercussions for business demographics. Equation (3) represents government initiatives to help support enterprises to stay in the market. The intrinsic relationship between the populations of banks and enterprises is encompassed in this system of differential equations, in which the number of performing loans of one population is dependent on that of the other population. The populations of banks and enterprises, especially portfolio SMEs, are more sensitive to varying levels of financial support; respectively:
z ˙ 1 = z 1 f 1 ( z 1 ,   z 2 ) z ˙ 2 = z 2 f 2 ( z 1 ,   z 2 )
(Desogus and Venturi 2019).
As such, banks find that restricting credit volumes increases their short-term performance, forcing enterprises out of the market and increasing the number of NPLs. These new circumstances should prompt banks to expand their lending business, which would then reactivate these cycles. Therefore, to preserve the bank–enterprise relationship, it is necessary to maintain the macro-system (see inter al. Desogus and Casu 2020a; Degryse and Van Cayseele 2000). This means that the stabilization of levels of leverage in the productive and business sectors should be consistent with the dynamic models profiled above. The recursive phases discussed earlier should be guaranteed, even when standardizing regulations are introduced. This is even more significant for fragile and/or partially impaired economic scenarios or under persistently unfavorable economic conditions (De Angelo and Roll 2015).
Although the exogenous events that led to the unfavorable economic situation were—more or less—temporary, the repercussions appeared to have been immediately absorbed within the business cycle. Indeed, there was an exacerbation of the phase trajectories, which are normally pseudo-elliptical, toward an intensification of the credit contraction period and a manifestation of a progressive delay in the spontaneous rebound reaction of the bank–small-enterprise system (Ganong and Liebman 2018).
In Italy, the main objective of government economic intervention during the COVID-19 emergency was to maintain proper operations of the bank–enterprise system. Here, it is crucial to note that the 2020 economic crisis was caused by exogenous elements—and not by pathologies internal to the system, as for example happened in the 2009–2011 crisis. Management of the current situation therefore focuses on ensuring temporary compensation for the sudden halt in productive activities, placing less emphasis on restoring economic and financial aspects that have themselves been damaged.
As delineated in Decree Laws No. 18 and No. 23 of 2020, the Italian government shifted its resource flows to direct public guarantees—in the model that we are considering, this effect is mathematically expressed by F —making them also immediately enforceable and with zero weighting on allocations (D’Ignazio and Menon 2020). Other measures included reinsurance for the credit guarantee consortia, offering free access and coverage of between 80% and 90% for most lending operations. Instead of injecting liquidity into the productive system (and households) with ‘helicopter money’ or other direct forms, the Italian government focused on strengthening public guarantee funds. In this way, the government allowed banks to retain their role of financial intermediation unchanged, whilst also encouraging a quantitative expansion of credit provisions.
In light of this, it is apparent that a strong productive sector fosters a healthy banking sector, which in turn cultivates favorable circumstances for enterprises. It is therefore necessary for us to delve further into the dynamics of the bank–enterprise system as we take into consideration the limits imposed by the macroeconomic and idiosyncratic components peculiar to each enterprise in the population z 2 .
Hence, we would like to now consider the following three-dimensional continuous-time Lotka–Volterra model involving the population of banks being z 1 , the population of enterprises being z 2 , and the government intervention as z 3 . Adapting Equation (3) for a purely three-dimensional economic nonlinear model, the system of equations as independent state variables is then:
{ z ˙ 1 = δ ( α z 1 z 2 τ z 2 + F k z 1 ) z ˙ 2 = μ ( h z 2 β z 1 z 2 + η z 1 z 3 + ( β F ) z 3 ) z ˙ 3 = τ z 2 + F
This arrangement represents the interpretation of the purely dynamical nonlinear system formed by Equations (1)–(3), which has been constructed taking the contribution of government intervention on systemic effects through guarantees provided by the central fund into account. In this sense, government action is always aimed at MSMEs, which end up being the beneficiaries of support through the government guarantee. Instead, the population of banks receives these effects ‘reflexively’. Therefore, the mere algebraic sum of the two components τ z 2 and F has been correctly imputed in the re-elaboration of the third equations (and replaced in the first), since there is no direct relationship between banks and the government intervention in support of the provision of credit. This reflexivity can be seen in the second equation of (S), in the η z 1 z 3 contribution. Even the bank financing operations, provided by the Central Bank, (TLTRO—targeted longer-term refinancing operations) do not determine any interaction between z 3 and z 1 , being, for all intents and purposes, loans, albeit dependent on the subsequent granting of credit to the enterprises by the borrowing banks (Castellacci and Choi 2014; Ledenyov and Ledenyov 2012; Hori and Futagami 2019).
The first equation is characterized from the following parameters: δ ,   α , τ ,   F , where δ is an adjustment parameter in the traditional imbalance in the production market equation, α is an interaction parameter between the population of the bank and enterprises in the first equation, β is an interaction parameter between the population of the bank and enterprises in the second equation, τ is the decrease rate of the population of the enterprises, and k is the decrease rate of the population of the banks, with F as the activation of the government guarantee fund. In a situation in which adequate leverage is available, the second equation is characterized by the following parameters: µ ,   h , β ,   η , where µ is an adjustment parameter in the credit market equation, h is the growth rate of the population of enterprises, and η is an interaction parameter between the population of the bank and the government intervention.
The vector of parameters ω ( α , β , δ ,   η , µ , τ , k , h , F ) abides inside the parameter space Ω + 6 × × × ( 0 , β ) , ω Ω .

3.1. Steady States and Local Stability Properties

Let P ( z 1 , z 2 , z 3 ) be a generic point. Recall that a stationary (equilibrium) point P * ( z 1 * , z 2 * , z 3 * ) of our system ( S ) is any solution such that:
z ˙ 1 = 0 ;       z ˙ 2 = 0 ;       z ˙ 3 = 0    
The differential equations in ( S ) , solved for z ˙ 1 = 0 , z ˙ 2 = 0 , and z ˙ 3 = 0 imply the following steady state value: P 1 * ( z 1 * , z 2 * , z 3 * ), with:
z 1 * = 0 ;     z 2 * = F τ ;     z 3 * = h F τ ( F β )
As mentioned in Section 3, intervention through fund F ensures indirect support for the disbursement of credit through collateral coverage payable; at the time of its activation, the fund will necessarily be 0 < F < β . That is, β represents an interaction parameter between the populations of banks and companies and also signals a (reciprocal) influence on the effects of a credit contraction. The incidence of F will therefore tend asymptotically toward the β parameter, with the effectiveness of F being reduced as it approaches β .
In Italy, this was acutely apparent as new operational provisions to reform the guarantee fund came into force on 15 March 2019 (pursuant to a 6 March 2017 inter-ministerial decree) (MISE—Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico 2019). The main changes included the redefinition of intervention methods as direct guarantees, of reinsurance, and counter-guarantees. In addition, there was also the application of a valuation model based on the probability of default by beneficiary companies over all of the fund’s operations, the reorganization of measures covered, maximum guaranteed amounts, and the introduction of operations focusing on tripartite risk (Hassan et al. 2022). In other words, the FCG (Central Guarantee Fund) is now equipped with a rating system for incoming applications, which makes guarantee percentages inversely proportional to the credit risk posed by the beneficiary company; stable companies, which ipso facto have interaction parameters ( α and β ), would be compatible with regular funding requirements and would receive moderate F assistance, whilst companies that are more at risk would receive greater F support. By considering feasible parameter values, we are presenting, for notational convenience, the following subset:
Ω 1 { ω Ω :   α + , β + , δ + , η + , μ + ,   k ,   τ + ,     h ,   0 < F < β }
where the system’s steady state solution is called P 1 * ( z 1 * , z 2 * , z 3 * ) .

3.2. Local Analysis

As is well-known, in a hyperbolic equilibrium point P * , the local dynamical properties of a nonlinear system are described, for brevity, in terms of the Jacobian matrix (Refaai et al. 2022). Hence, let J denote the Jacobian matrix of system ( S ) . So, simple algebra leads to the following ( 3 × 3 ) matrix:
J = | δ ( α z 2 k ) δ ( α z 1 τ ) 0 μ ( β z 2 + η z 3 ) μ ( h β z 1 ) μ ( η z 1 + β F ) 0 τ 0 |
Let   J be evaluated at the equilibrium point P i * : J ( P i *   ) =   J i * .
Then, the Jacobian matrix J can be evaluated at the steady-state value P 1 * ,   J (   P 1 * ) = J 1 * for brevity, which is given by:
J (   P 1 * ) = | δ ( α F τ k ) δ τ 0 μ ( β F τ + η h F τ ( β + F ) ) μ h μ ( β F ) 0 τ 0 |
We therefore obtain:
T r ( J 1 * ) = δ ( α F τ k ) + μ h  
D e t ( J 1 * ) = δ ( α F k τ ) μ ( β + F )
B ( J 1 * ) = δ ( α F τ k ) μ h + μ ( β F ) τ
where T r ( J 1 * ) is the trace of J (   P 1 * ) , and D e t ( J 1 * ) is   the   determinant   of   J (   P 1 * ) , and B ( J 1 * )   is the sum of the principal minor of J (   P 1 * ) . Note that the eigenvalues of J 1 *   are the solutions of the characteristic equation:
d e t ( λ I J 1 * ) = λ 3 T r ( J 1 * ) λ 2 + B ( J 1 * ) λ D e t ( J 1 * )
where I is the identity matrix.
We focus on local analysis in the set Ω 1
Proposition 1.
Let   ω   Ω 1 then:
(a)
If k <   F α τ , h* < h < 0 ,   there exist two subsets Ω 1 A and Ω 1 B such that when ω Ω 1 A , J 1 * has one eigenvalue with a positive real part and two eigenvalues with negative real parts, and when   ω Ω 2 A , J 1 * has three eigenvalues with positive real parts. This means that if ω Ω 2 A , we will have instability.
(b)
If k > F α τ , h* < h < 0 ,   there exist two subsets Ω 1 A and Ω 1 B such that when ω Ω 1 A , J 1 * has three eigenvalues with negative real parts, and when   ω Ω 2 A , J 1 * has one eigenvalue with a negative real part and two eigenvalues with positive real parts. This means that the equilibrium P 1 * will be locally unique.
Proof. 
These results were obtained by applying the Routh–Hurwitz stability criterion to the system ( S ) , according to which the number of the positive eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix J (   P 1 * ) , evidently evaluated at the steady states P 1 * , will be equal to the number of variations of the sign in the scheme:
1 ;         T r ( J 1 * ) ;       B ( J 1 *   ) + D e t ( J 1 * ) T r ( J 1 * ) ;         D e t ( J 1 * )
We define:
G ( J 1 * ) = B ( J 1 * ) + D e t ( J 1 * ) T r ( J 1 * )
Case 1a. Let   ω Ω 1 A be and k <   F α   τ ,   then:
When T r ( J 1 * ) , D e t ( J 1 * ) and B ( J 1 * ) are positive, the sign of G ( J 1 * ) can be positive. In this case, we have one eigenvalue with a positive real part and two eigenvalues with negative parts, so P 1 *   will be an unstable saddle.
Case 1b. Let   ω   Ω 2 A be and k <   F α   τ , then:
When T r ( J 1 * ) , D e t ( J 1 * ) and B ( J 1 * ) are positive, the sign of G ( J 1 * ) can be negative. In this case, we have three eigenvalues with positive real parts, so P 1 * will be a completely unstable saddle.
Case 2a. Let   ω Ω 1 A be and k >   F α   τ , then:
Both T r ( J 1 * ) and D e t ( J 1 * ) are always negative, and the sign of G ( J 1 * ) is negative. In this case, we have three eigenvalues with negative real parts, so P 1 * will be a stable saddle.
Case 2b. Let   ω   Ω 2 A be and k >   F α   τ , then:
Both T r ( J 1 * ) and D e t ( J 1 * ) are always negative, and the sign of G ( J 1 * ) is positive. In this case, we have one eigenvalue with a negative real part and two eigenvalues with positive real parts, so P 1 * is a saddle focus. □

4. Global Analysis

Here, we need to go beyond the conventional stability analysis and use bifurcation theory. We have chosen h as the bifurcation parameter to examine the existence of Hopf bifurcating closed orbits from the steady state: P 1 * ( z 1 * z 2 * z 3 * ).
Lemma 1.
If ω Ω 1 , then there exists at least one value h = h* such that J * ( P 1 * ) has a pair of purely imaginary roots.
Proof. 
Since G ( h ) = B ( J 1 * )   T r ( J 1 * ) + D e t ( J 1 * ) changes sign in Ω 1 , by the Routh–Hurvitz criterion, we state that J * has one positive (real) eigenvalue and two complex conjugate roots whose real parts can be either positive or negative. It means that the two complex conjugate roots of J 1 * can be either positive or negative. Furthermore, since the real parts of the complex conjugate roots vary continuously with respect to h, there must exist at least one value h = h * such that G ( h ) = 0 . When this occurs, by Vieta’s theorem, J 1 * has a simple pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues. The sign of   D e t ( J 1 * )   is independent of h ; Vieta’s theorem has been used properly. (Q.E.D.) □
Lemma 2.
If ω Ω 1 , then the derivative of the real part of the complex conjugate eigenvalues with respect to h, evaluated at h = h * , will always be different from zero.
Proof. 
To prove that d R e   λ ( h ) d h   cannot be zero at the bifurcation point h * , by following the strategy developed by Benhabib and Miyao (1981), we show that:
Sign   dRe   λ ( h ) d h | h *   = Sign   ( dTr   d h   B T r d B d h + d D e t d h )   = Sign   d G ( h )   d h | h *  
Whereas G ( h ) is a second-degree polynomial in h changing sign at h = h * (see Lemma 1 proof), the bifurcation points cannot coincide with the minimum or maximum of the function. Therefore, there must be a neighborhood of h* where the derivative of G ( h ) with respect to h is different from zero. (Q.E.D.) □
Theorem 1.
Assuming the hypotheses of Lemmas 1 and 2, then, there will be a continuous function h ( ρ ) with h ( 0 ) = h *   , and for all that are small enough ρ = 0 , there will be a continuous family of non-constant positive periodic solutions P 1 * ( z 1 * ( ρ ) z 2 * ( ρ ) z 3 * ( ρ ) ) for the dynamical system (S), which will then collapse to the stationary point P 1 * ( z 1 * z 2 * z 3 * ) as ρ 0 .
Proof. 
(It follows from the Hopf bifurcation theorem; see Appendix A.) □
Example 1.
Let ω   Ω 1 A ,   k <   F α   τ   a n d   h^   0.001050519739 ;
Set   ω ( α , β , δ ,   η , k , µ , τ , F ) = ( 0.00478 ,   0.02787 ,   1 ,   0.042 , 0.0250 ,   1 ,   0.03453 ,   0.025 ) .
According to Proposition 1, the equilibrium point   P 1 * will be a saddle focus with three eigenvalues with a real positive part:
λ R = 0.01450660897 ;   λ c , λ c ¯ = 0.006451815026 ± 0.0123613182   I .
Example 2.
Let ω   Ω 2 A ,   k <   F α   τ   a n d   h ^ 0.002750519739 ;
Set   ω ( α , β , δ ,   η , k , µ , τ , F ) = ( 0.00478 ,   0.02787 ,   1 ,   0.042 , 0.025 ,   1 ,   0.03453 ,   0.025 )
According to Proposition 1, the equilibrium point   P 1 * will be a saddle focus with one real eigenvalue with a real positive part and two complex eigenvalues with a real negative part.
λ R = 0.03593045781 ;   λ c , λ c ¯ = 0.00510109393 ± 0.007237778242   I .
Example 3.
Let ω   Ω 1   a n d   k <   F α   τ   and h * 0.001750529 ;
Set   ω ( α , β , δ ,   η , k , µ , τ , F ) = ( 0.00478 ,   0.02787 ,   1 ,   0.042 , 0.025 ,   1 ,   0.03453 ,   0.025 ) .
Then a Hopf bifurcation will result with eigenvalues
λ R = 0.02671023902 ;   λ c , λ c ¯ = ± 1.170195840   I .
Then, we know that there is a continuous family of non-constant positive periodic solutions P*(z*1 ( ρ ) , z*2 ( ρ ) , z*3 ( ρ ) ) for the dynamical system (S), which collapses at the equilibrium point P*1 (z*1, z*2, z*3) as ρ 0 .

5. The Zero-Hopf Bifurcation

We will use F as a bifurcation parameter to show that the linearization matrix of the righthand side of the system ( S ) , evaluated at the steady state, will have a zero eigenvalue. More specifically:
T r ( J h * ) = δ ( k + α F τ ) + h *
When we consider that T r ( J h * ) = k δ + δ α F τ + h * = 0 , since we have assumed that δ = 1 , then we should remember that:
Where δ is an adjustment parameter in the traditional imbalance in the production market equation;
k is the rate of decrease in the bank loans’ performance correlated to periods of negative demographics of SMEs;
α is the interaction parameter between banks and enterprises;
τ describes the damping (or absorption effect)—on enterprises—of the oscillatory motion of the system dynamics and, in particular, of the compensatory intervention of the fund.
Therefore, if T r ( J h * ) = 0 then k = h * δ + F α τ , i.e., when the rate of decrease in the positive performance of the banking portfolios is equal to the product of the fund. However, there will be a difference among the damping and bank–enterprise interactions, normalized by the relationship with the absorption parameter.
We can also write the previous relation with respect to F :
F ^ = τ ( k δ + h * ) δ α
In this situation, the intervention of the fund manages to maintain the condition of the system, yet without improving the performance indicators of the companies or the banks.
Theorem 2 (Gavrilov–Guckenheimer bifurcation).
Let ( h . F ) ϵ   Ω 1   . Furthermore, let u = u( h * F ^ ) and v = v( h * F ^ ) such that at the same time B ( J 1 * ) < 0 , and T r ( J 1 * ) = D e t ( J 1 * ) = 0 .
Then, J h * has one real zero eigenvalue λ R = T r ( J 1 * ) = 0   and two purely imaginary eigenvalues given by λ c , λ c ¯ ± i ξ where ξ = B ( J 1 * ) .
Proof. 
We consider the matrix J h * that represents the Jacobian matrix J 1 * put into a normal form:
  J h * = T 1 J 1           * T = [ 0 ξ 0 ξ 0 0 0 0 T r J 1           * ]
where T r ( J h * ) = T r ( J 1 * )   and   ξ = B ( J 1 * )   are evaluated at the bifurcation point h = h * .
Let the parameters h = h * and   F = F ^ choose, such that:
F ^ = τ ( k δ h * ) δ α
Then: T r (   J h * ) = Tr ( J 1 * ) = 0 .
So, we can rewrite J h * = T 1 J 1 *   T   as:
J h , F * = [ 0 ξ 0 ξ 0 0 0 0 0 ]
Det ( J h , F * ) in (14) vanishes and J h , F * has at least one eigenvalue equal to zero.
Let B ( J h , F * ) = ξ 2 . □
We can now show analytically and numerically that there is a Gavrilov–Guckenheimer two-bifurcation codimension. This phenomenon, which has recently been closely studied, takes the form of a pitchfork–Hopf interaction (Bella and Mattana 2018; Bosi and Desmarchelier 2018; Bella et al. 2022), which is a linear degeneracy that can be associated with the onset of a 2-torus trapping region in the three-dimensional space enclosed by a two-dimensional surface (see Figure 3).
Considering the case of the initial conditions ( w 1 ( 0 ) , w 2 ( 0 ) , w 3 ( 0 ) ) = ( 0.1 , 0.1 , 0.2 ) , then the attractor will have the form represented in Figure 4.

6. Discussion

As the nonlinear differential equations defining this system are continuous and derivable complex functions, this system is also conditioned by a set of interaction and adjustment parameters that make each population dependent on the other. Conducting a dynamical analysis of the unique steady-state model, we applied a Jacobian matrix J ( P * ) to describe the local dynamical properties of the hyperbolic equilibrium points P 1 * . Considering the derived eigenvalues J * in the parameter space Ω 1 , we found that the equilibrium path is locally unique. Furthermore, by applying the Routh–Hurwitz criterion, we ascertained the fundamental stability of the system such that, for each instance that the fund was relied upon, 0 < F < β . In practice, this means that the fund was structured to provide a guarantee that was inversely proportional to the credit risk posed by the company under review.
Where the economic crisis resulting from the COVID-19 pandemic and subsequent lockdowns in 2020 was caused by factors external to the financial economic system, we found that measures introduced by the Italian government were not focused on correcting the existing bank–enterprise system or aspects of it that may have suffered because of the crisis. Rather, those interventions sought to maintain the fabric of the bank–enterprise system healthy by attending to the unexpected lapses in productive activities. In particular, the Italian government made adjustments to the system by providing collateral coverage, payable through its public guarantee fund F, and by encouraging the continuation and increase in credit transactions.
Exploring the impacts of this intervention on the economic financial system and considering the growth rate of the small enterprises as bifurcation parameters, we were able to prove the existence of a stable Hopf cycle. Following from the collapse of all sufficiently small growth rates of the population of enterprises ρ(h) in a continuous family of non-constant positive periodic solutions to stationary point P 1 * , we produced evidence of the existence of Hopf and zero-Hopf periodic solutions and that these tended to bifurcate from a saddle focus in a particular region of the parameter space. In addition, we observed the simultaneous occurrence of a zero eigenvalue and two purely imaginary eigenvalues (Hopf bifurcation), which gave rise to a Gavrilov–Guckenheimer bifurcation. In treating government intervention and the growth rate of the population of enterprises as two bifurcation parameters, we were able to deduce the existence of a two-bifurcation-related codimension with the persistence of a pre-existing Hopf limit cycle.
From this, we noted that whilst the intervention of fund F allowed for the condition of the system to be maintained, there was no indication that it improved the performance of companies or banks. In other words, when the relationship between the performance of banks, the absorption parameter and the interaction parameter between banks and enterprises is equal to the effect of the fund, the system achieves stability with no instrumental positive or negative change.
As we continue to operate with the uncertainties and instability introduced by the COVID-19 pandemic, understanding the underlying mechanisms of the options available to governments for ensuring continued stability and function of our financial economic systems is crucial (Xu et al. 2022). Of potentially critical importance is identifying at what point, if at all, the Gavrilov–Guckenheimer bifurcation may bring the system into chaos. Further investigation may identify how the measures implemented by the Italian government in 2020 might be able to move beyond maintaining pre-existing performance levels. Perhaps these measures could also be applied to improving the performance of banks and companies, or in combination with other instruments to achieve similar or enhanced results. Additional research could also consider the feasibility and effectiveness of these measures in economies with structures dissimilar to Italy’s.
Since the COVID-19 pandemic was an exogenous force, this paper does not address impairments of creditworthiness or strategies for avoiding or mitigating credit crunches caused by poor internal structures. Likewise, it offers only a partial contribution to discussions on how to respond if an economic financial system were to suffer from contemporaneous exogenous and endogenous shocks (for instance, if the conditions of the COVID-19 pandemic and the 2009–2011 crisis were to occur at the same time).

7. Conclusions

This paper is attempting to provide some valuable insights on the interconnections and dependencies between banks, enterprises and the government in the interest of preventing a credit crunch enjoined by external factors. With the help of dynamical systems analysis and bifurcation theory, we have analyzed how the intervention of the guarantee fund in Italy has maintained the stability of the financial and economic system.
Drawing on Bischi and Tramontana (2010) for the discrete application of similar dynamical systems and on earlier two-dimensional modeling of the bank–enterprise system by Desogus and Casu (2020b), we have developed a three-dimensional continuous-time Lotka–Volterra dynamical model that demonstrates the interactions between populations of banks and enterprises and the government in a given financial system. Specifically, we focused on those interactions that are facilitated by credit transactions and the role of the guarantee fund in supporting the continuation of credit exchanges during periods of economic crisis.
This modeling has been informed by the cyclical trends that characterize economic financial models and that cause these systems to oscillate between states of stability and instability. This trajectory was confirmed through a comparative analysis of data from Italy and the UK that outlines how ad hoc government intervention in support of credit disbursement has helped to alleviate pressures within the system, to decrease the risk of impaired credit ratings and non-performing loans and to prevent a looming credit crunch.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, M.D. and B.V.; methodology, M.D. and B.V.; software, M.D. and B.V.; validation, M.D. and B.V.; formal analysis, B.V.; investigation, M.D.; resources, M.D.; data curation, M.D.; writing—original draft preparation, M.D. and B.V.; writing—review and editing, M.D. and B.V.; visualization, M.D.; supervision, B.V.; project administration, B.V.; funding acquisition, B.V. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research has been funded by Fondazione di Sardegna.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Compliance with Ethical Standards.

Data Availability Statement

The data used are shown in the tables within the text.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the anonymous reviewers for carefully reading this paper and for their many insightful comments and suggestions.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

To apply Hopf’s bifurcation theorem, we need first to put the system ( S ) into a normal form. Several steps are required.
  • First, we need to translate the fixed point P 1 * to the origin t 1 = z 1 z 1 * ,   t 2 = z 2 z 2 * ,     t 3 = z 3 z 3 * ;   h ˇ = h h * ;   t ,   z ,   z *   3   under which system ( S ) becomes:
    t 1 ˙ = δ - k t 1 + α t 1 t 2 + α t 1 F τ + F - τ t 2 + F τ t 2 ˙ = h ˇ + h * t 2 + F τ - β t 1 t 2 + β t 1 F τ + η t 1 t 3 + F h ˇ + h * τ β - F + β - F t 3 + F h ˇ + h * τ β - F t 3 ˙ = F - τ t 2 + F τ
  • As a second step, we need to separate the linear part of the vector field from the rest. Formally, this means that our system becomes:
    t ˙ = f ( t ) = J 1 *   t + F ( t )
    where J * ( P 1 * ) corresponds to the Jacobian of system (S) and where F ( t ) is computed by the usual Taylor expansion, and only terms of order 2 and higher are included:
    F 1 = δ α t 1 t 2 ;         F 2 = β t 1 t 2 + η t 1 t 3 ;         F 3 = 0
      | F 1 F 2 F 3 | = | δ α t 1 t 2 β t 1 t 2 + η t 1 t 3 0 |  
  • Finally, let T be the matrix that transforms J 1 * into a Jordan canonical form:   t = T w .
Hence, we can write our system as:
T w ˙ = J 1 *   T w + F ˇ ( T w )
or
w ˙ = T 1 J 1 *   T w + T 1 F ˇ ( T w )
which is a form that simplifies the linear part of system ( H ) as much as possible. The calculation of T—the matrix of coordinate change for system ( S ) —requires the determination of the basis vectors e 1 , e 2 , e 3 associated with the eigenvalues of J 1 * at the bifurcation point. By substituting B T r = D e t in the characteristic polynomial at the bifurcation point, the real eigenvalue, λ R , is positive and equal to T r , whereas the complex conjugate eigenvalues, λ c and λ c ¯ , are purely imaginary, with λ c = i B ( J 1 * ) and λ c ¯ = i B ( J 1 * ) . Now, we can define ξ = B ( J 1 * ) .
Since we know the form of the eigenvalues of J 1 * at the bifurcation point h = h * :
λ r = T r ( J 1 * ) ;   λ c , λ c ¯ = ± ξ i
The calculation of the basis vectors is not complicated. An eigenvector of J 1 * with the eigenvalue Tr ( J 1 * ) is e 1 , the eigenspace of J 1 * corresponding to the complex eigenvalues λ c , λ c ¯ = ± ξ i   where the orthogonal complement of the transpose of J 1 * corresponds to the real eigenvalue λ R = T r ( J 1 * ) .   So, we choose e 1 , e 2 , e 3 . Now we have the basis, and we can compute T.
e 1 = | j 11 * v 1 + j 12 * ξ j 21 * v 1 + j 22 * ξ j 32 * v 2 ξ | ;       e 2 = | v 1 v 2 v 3 | = | 1 1 0 | ;       e 3 = | ( j 22 * λ r ) λ r j 23 * j 32 * j 21 * j 32 * λ r j 32 * 1 |
T = | e 11 1 e 31 e 22 1 e 32 e 33 0 1 |
T = | j 11 * v 1 + j 12 *   ξ 1 ( j 22 * λ r ) λ r j 23 * j 32 * j 21 * j 32 * j 21 * v 1 + j 22 *   ξ 1 λ r j 32 * j 32 *   ξ 0 1 | = | T 11 1 T 13 T 21 1 λ r j 32 * j 32 *   ξ 0 1 |
Setting D = 1 β ( λ 3 ξ T 11 + ξ T 21 + T 13 j 32 * ), we can write:
T 1 = 1 D | 1 1 T 13 1 ξ ( λ 3 + ξ T 21 ) 1 λ 3 j 32 * 1 ξ j 32 * 1 ξ j 32 *   1 ξ ( ξ T 11 ξ T 21 ) |
Finally, we get the system put into a normal form:
  J h * = T 1 J 1           * T = [ 0 ξ 0 ξ 0 0 0 0 T r J 1           * ]
We   call   J h *   the Jacobian matrix J 1   * put into a normal form.
Where   T r ( J h * ) = T r ( J 1 * )   and   B ( J 1 * ) = ξ 2 is evaluated at the bifurcation point h = h * , such that:
( w ˙ 1 w ˙ 2 ˙ w ˙ 3 ) = [ 0 ξ 0 ξ 0 0 0 0 T r J ] ( w 1 w 2 w 3 ) +   ( F ˇ 1 a w 1 w 2 + F ˇ 1 b w 1 w 3 + F ˇ 1 c w 2 w 3 + F ˇ 1 d w 1 2 + F ˇ 1 e w 2 2 + F ˇ 1 f w 3 2 F ˇ 2 a w 1 w 2 + F ˇ 2 b w 1 w 3 + F ˇ 2 c w 2 w 3 + F ˇ 2 d w 1 2 + F ˇ 2 e w 2 2 + F ˇ 2 f w 3 2 F ˇ 3 a w 1 w 2 + F ˇ 3 b w 1 w 3 + F ˇ 3 c w 2 w 3 + F ˇ 3 d w 1 2 + F ˇ 3 e w 2 2 + F ˇ 3 f w 3 2 )

References

  1. ABI-Cerved. 2018a. Outlook ABI-Cerved Sulle Sofferenze Delle Imprese. Tech. Rep., ABI. Available online: https://www.abi.it/DOC_Mercati/Analisi/Scenario-e-previsioni/Outlook-ABI-Cerved/Outlook%20Abi-Cerved%20su%20sofferenze_Numero%206%20feb%202018.pdf (accessed on 19 May 2022).
  2. ABI-Cerved. 2018b. Outlook ABI-Cerved Sulle Sofferenze Delle Imprese. Tech. Rep., ABI. Available online: https://www.abi.it/DOC_Mercati/Analisi/Scenario-e-previsioni/Outlook-ABI-Cerved/Outlook%20Abi-Cerved%20sulle%20sofferenze%20delle%20imprese_Nr.%206%20dic%202018.pdf (accessed on 19 May 2022).
  3. ABI-Cerved. 2019a. Outlook ABI-Cerved Sui Crediti Deteriorati Delle Imprese. Tech. Rep., ABI. Available online: https://www.abi.it/DOC_Mercati/Analisi/Scenario-e-previsioni/Outlook-ABI-Cerved/Outlook%20Abi-Cerved_Edizione%20dicembre%202019.pdf (accessed on 20 May 2022).
  4. ABI-Cerved. 2019b. Outlook ABI-Cerved Sulle Sofferenze Delle Imprese. Tech. Rep., ABI. Available online: https://www.abi.it/DOC_Mercati/Analisi/Scenario-e-previsioni/Outlook-ABI-Cerved/Outlook%20Abi-Cerved%20sulle%20sofferenze%20delle%20imprese_Nr.%208%20luglio%202019.pdf (accessed on 20 May 2022).
  5. Baldini, Andrea, and Marco Causi. 2020. Restoring credit market stability conditions in Italy: Evidences on Loan and Bad Loan dynamics. The European Journal of Finance 26: 746–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bassetto, Marco, Marco Cagetti, and Mariacristina De Nardi. 2015. Credit crunches and credit allocation in a model of entrepreneurship. Review of Economic Dynamics 18: 53–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Bella, Giovanni, and Paolo Mattana. 2018. Bistability of equilibria and the 2-tori dynamics in an endogenous growth model undergoing the cusp–Hopf singularity. Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 39: 185–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Bella, Giovanni, Paolo Mattana, and Beatrice Venturi. 2022. Existence and implications of a pitchfork-Hopf bifurcation in a continuous-time two-sector growth model. Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 17: 259–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Benhabib, Jess, and Takahiro Miyao. 1981. Some new results on the dynamics of the generalized Tobin model. International Economic Review 22: 589–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bernanke, Ben Shalom, Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist. 1994. The financial accelerator and the flight to quality. The Review of Economics and Statistics 78: 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Bischi, Gian Italo, and Fabio Tramontana. 2010. Three-dimensional discrete-time Lotka–Volterra models with an application to industrial clusters. Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation 15: 3000–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Bosi, Stefano, and David Desmarchelier. 2018. Pollution and infectious diseases. International Journal of Economic Theory 14: 351–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Buera, Francisco Javier, Roberto N. Fattal Jaef, and Yongseok Shin. 2015. Anatomy of a credit crunch: From capital to labor markets. Review of Economic Dynamics 18: 101–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  14. Caggiano, Giovanni, Efrem Castelnuovo, and Giovanni Pellegrino. 2017. Estimating the real effects of uncertainty shocks at the zero lower bound. European Economic Review 100: 257–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Calcagnini, Giorgio, Germana Giombini, and Giuseppe Travaglini. 2019. A theoretical model of imperfect markets and investment. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 50: 237–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Castellacci, Giuseppe, and Youngna Choi. 2014. Financial instability contagion: A dynamical systems approach. Quantitative Finance 14: 1243–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. D’Ignazio Alessio, Ignazio, and Carlo Menon. 2020. Causal Effect of Credit Guarantees for Small-and Medium-Sized Enterprises: Evidence from Italy. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 122: 191–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. De Angelo, Harry, and Richard Roll. 2015. How stable are corporate capital structures? The Journal of Finance 70: 373–418. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Degryse, Hans, and Patrick Van Cayseele. 2000. Relationship lending within a bank-based system: Evidence from European small business data. Journal of financial Intermediation 9: 90–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Desogus, Marco, and Beatrice Venturi. 2019. Bank Crashes and Micro Enterprise Loans. International Journal of Business and Social Science 10: 191–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Desogus, Marco, and Elisa Casu. 2020a. A Contribution on Relationship Banking. Economic, Anthropological and Mathematical Reasoning, Empirical Evidence from Italy. International Research Journal of Finance and Economics 178: 25–49. [Google Scholar]
  22. Desogus, Marco, and Elisa Casu. 2020b. What Are the Impacts of Credit Crunch on the Bank-Enterprise System? An Analysis Through Dynamic Modeling and an Italian Dataset. Applied Mathematical Sciences 14: 679–703. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Ditzen, Jan. 2018. Cross-country convergence in a general Lotka–Volterra model. Spatial Economic Analysis 13: 191–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. European Central Bank. 2017. Guidance to Banks on Non-Performing Loans. Tech. Rep., European Central Bank. Available online: https://www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu/ecb/pub/pdf/guidance_on_npl.en.pdf (accessed on 16 May 2022).
  25. Ganong, Peter, and Jeffrey B. Liebman. 2018. The decline, rebound, and further rise in SNAP enrollment: Disentangling business cycle fluctuations and policy changes. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 10: 153–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Hassan, Zara, Nauman Raza, Abdel-Haleem Abdel-Aty, Mohammed Zakarya, Riaz Ur Rahman, Adeela Yasmeen, Abdisalam Hassan, and Emad E. Mahmoud. 2022. New Fractal Soliton Solutions and Sensitivity Visualization for Double-Chain DNA Model. Journal of Function Spaces 2022: 2297866. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Hori, Takeo, and Koichi Futagami. 2019. A Non-unitary Discount Rate Model. Economica 86: 139–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Iyer Rajkamal, José-Luis Peydró, Samuel da-Rocha-Lopes, and Antoniette Schoar. 2014. Interbank liquidity crunch and the firm credit crunch: Evidence from the 2007–2009 crisis. The Review of Financial Studies 27: 347–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Kurkina, Elena S. 2017. Mathematical Models of Investment Cycles. Computational Mathematics and Modeling 28: 377–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Laeven, Luc, and Fabian Valencia. 2013. The real effects of financial sector interventions during crises. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 45: 147–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Ledenyov, Dimitri O., and Viktor O. Ledenyov. 2012. On the new central bank strategy toward monetary and financial instabilities management in finances: Econophysical analysis of nonlinear dynamical financial systems. arXiv arXiv:1211.1897. [Google Scholar]
  32. Liu, Meng, and Meng Fan. 2017. Permanence of stochastic Lotka–Volterra systems. Journal of Nonlinear Science 27: 425–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Marasco, Addolorata, Antonella Picucci, and Alessandro Romano. 2016. Market share dynamics using Lotka–Volterra models. Technological Forecasting and Social Change 105: 49–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. MISE—Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico. 2019. Parte la Riforma Del Fondo. Available online: https://www.fondidigaranzia.it/parte-la-riforma-del-fondo/ (accessed on 26 April 2022).
  35. Neri, Umberto, and Beatrice Venturi. 2007. Stability and bifurcations in IS-LM economic models. International Review of Economics 54: 53–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Nishimura, Kazuo, and Tadashi Shigoka. 2019. Hopf bifurcation and the existence and stability of closed orbits in three-sector models of optimal endogenous growth. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics 23: 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Petrosky-Nadeau, Nicolas. 2013. TFP during a Credit Crunch. Journal of Economic Theory 148: 1150–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Refaai, D.A., Mohammed M.A. El-Sheikh, Gamal A. Ismail, Mohammed Zakarya, Ghada AlNemer, and Haytham M. Rezk. 2022. Stability of Nonlinear Fractional Delay Differential Equations. Symmetry 14: 1606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Rozendaal, Jeroen C., Yannick Malevergne, and Didier Sornette. 2016. Macroeconomic dynamics of assets, leverage and trust. International Journal of Bifurcation and Chaos 26: 1650133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Tan, Brandon, Deniz O. Igan, Maria Soledad Martinez Peria, Nicola Pierri, and Andrea F. Presbitero. 2020. Government Intervention and Bank Market Power: Lessons from the Global Financial Crisis for the COVID-19 Crisis. IMF Working Paper. Available online: https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/WP/Issues/2020/12/11/Government-Intervention-and-Bank-Market-Power-Lessons-from-the-Global-Financial-Crisis-for-49934 (accessed on 5 July 2022).
  41. Tsai, Bi-Huei. 2017. Predicting the competitive relationships of industrial production between Taiwan and China using Lotka–Volterra model. Applied Economics 49: 2428–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Wang, Sheng, Guixin Hu, and Linshan Wang. 2018. Stability in distribution of a stochastic competitive lotka-volterra system with S-type distributed time delays. Methodology and Computing in Applied Probability 20: 1241–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Wehinger, Gert. 2014. SMEs and the credit crunch: Current financing difficulties, policy measures and a review of literature. OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends 2013: 115–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Wei, Tie, Zhiwei Zhu, Yang Li, and Na Yao. 2018. The evolution of competition in innovation resource: A theoretical study based on Lotka–Volterra model. Technology Analysis and Strategic Management 30: 295–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Wong, Grace. 2009. UK Unveils Second Bank Rescue Plan. CNN. Available online: https://money.cnn.com/2009/01/19/news/international/britain_bank_bailout/index.htm (accessed on 25 May 2022).
  46. Xu, Changjin, Muhammad Farman, Ali Hasan, Ali Akgül, Mohammed Zakarya, Wedad Albalawi, and Choonkil Park. 2022. Lyapunov stability and wave analysis of COVID-19 omicron variant of real data with fractional operator. Alexandria Engineering Journal 61: 11787–802. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Zhao, Liming, and Zhipei Zhao. 2016. Stability and Hopf bifurcation analysis on a nonlinear business cycle model. Mathematical Problems in Engineering 2016: 2706719. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Changes in credit disbursed, population of enterprises in the market and number of NPLs in Italy from January 2012 to September 2018. The graph shows a general upward trend of 4.00% in NPLs from January 2012 to May 2017. There is a rise of 1.00% in enterprise population from January 2012 to January 2013, followed by a decline of 2.00% and stagnation until September 2018. Credit disbursement sees a sharp decline of 6.00% from January 2012 to May 2013, recovering gradually to reach original levels in 2015 and increasing a further 2.00% in 2017, before dropping back in 2018. Based on data in Table 1, Table 2, Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5.
Figure 1. Changes in credit disbursed, population of enterprises in the market and number of NPLs in Italy from January 2012 to September 2018. The graph shows a general upward trend of 4.00% in NPLs from January 2012 to May 2017. There is a rise of 1.00% in enterprise population from January 2012 to January 2013, followed by a decline of 2.00% and stagnation until September 2018. Credit disbursement sees a sharp decline of 6.00% from January 2012 to May 2013, recovering gradually to reach original levels in 2015 and increasing a further 2.00% in 2017, before dropping back in 2018. Based on data in Table 1, Table 2, Table 3, Table 4 and Table 5.
Jrfm 16 00171 g001
Figure 2. Percentage changes in credit disbursed, population of enterprises in the market and number of NPLs in the United Kingdom from September 2010 to March 2019. The graph shows a general decline in net NPLs in the UK from September 2010 to March 2019, dropping sharply in 2014 and falling by 70.00% by March 2019. The population of enterprises remains relatively unchanged until September 2014, after which there is a gradual increase of about 15.00% by March 2019. Gross lending declines 20.00% by September 2012, then rises 50.00% by September 2014, before fluctuating regularly to reach 20.00% above September 2010 levels in March 2019. Based on data in Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8.
Figure 2. Percentage changes in credit disbursed, population of enterprises in the market and number of NPLs in the United Kingdom from September 2010 to March 2019. The graph shows a general decline in net NPLs in the UK from September 2010 to March 2019, dropping sharply in 2014 and falling by 70.00% by March 2019. The population of enterprises remains relatively unchanged until September 2014, after which there is a gradual increase of about 15.00% by March 2019. Gross lending declines 20.00% by September 2012, then rises 50.00% by September 2014, before fluctuating regularly to reach 20.00% above September 2010 levels in March 2019. Based on data in Table 6, Table 7 and Table 8.
Jrfm 16 00171 g002
Figure 3. The Hopf cycle with h * = 0.001750529 .
Figure 3. The Hopf cycle with h * = 0.001750529 .
Jrfm 16 00171 g003
Figure 4. The zero-Hopf cycle.
Figure 4. The zero-Hopf cycle.
Jrfm 16 00171 g004
Table 1. Gross lending to enterprises in Italy, in billions of euros (January 2012–January 2020).
Table 1. Gross lending to enterprises in Italy, in billions of euros (January 2012–January 2020).
MonthLoansMonthLoansMonthLoans
01-20121876.2407-20141737.3001-20171627.13
02-20121867.0708-20141714.6802-20171626.02
03-20121843.1009-20141723.4903-20171622.25
04-20121855.3810-20141714.3104-20171610.56
05-20121848.4511-20141709.7905-20171614.94
06-20121839.2912-20141690.0806-20171591.44
07-20121842.2901-20151694.0707-20171554.87
08-20121824.7302-20151686.0808-20171534.32
09-20121814.3403-20151694.9309-20171524.81
10-20121816.0104-20151688.1410-20171527.56
11-20121822.0605-20151679.9911-20171528.31
12-20121803.7806-20151694.5412-20171531.91
01-20131807.2807-20151693.2001-20181531.41
02-20131804.5708-20151675.3702-20181538.13
03-20131784.3309-20151679.7603-20181528.03
04-20131779.0410-20151659.5004-20181528.99
05-20131771.1411-20151680.4605-20181531.15
06-20131757.3912-20151659.1906-20181468.33
07-20131761.5501-20161656.9607-20181471.66
08-20131737.3602-20161653.7308-20181453.09
09-20131737.0903-20161648.8409-20181449.99
10-20131725.2104-20161638.3510-20181445.76
11-20131712.0605-20161650.0411-20181452.22
12-20131706.8006-20161652.7612-20181412.34
01-20141755.4407-20161644.1701-20191412.80
02-20141748.4808-20161637.5802-20191407.97
03-20141741.6809-20161635.6903-20191383.85
04-20141734.2410-20161634.5904-20191389.70
05-20141719.4411-20161639.7605-20191385.88
06-20141730.6412-20161618.8806-20191370.11
07-20191374.30
08-20191349.54
09-20191346.08
10-20191337.47
11-20191334.66
12-20191312.60
01-20201325.77
Own processing based on data from the Bank of Italy, ISTAT and Chambers of Commerce.
Table 2. Total number of enterprises in Italy (2012–2018).
Table 2. Total number of enterprises in Italy (2012–2018).
Year2012201320142015201620172018
B2451233622572186225023182332
C417,306407,344396,422389,317399,458404,528406,508
D892610,16910,45910,77510,01510,04210,056
E8967912191469231906092309301
F572,412549,846529,103511,405534,824537,348537,853
G1,163,4131,153,6401,123,1341,105,2271,128,1171,129,7031,130,596
H131,755129,865125,688123,625127,651127,817128,172
I307,878313,207312,013315,464312,000311,478312,009
J97,28095,98996,99798,38196,93396,91697,080
K91,43493,03195,20996,17393,19993,34093,393
L235,434243,564239,134238,273237,137237,095237,067
M710,017691,700705,895714,934700,468700,308700,406
N143,770139,362139,898139,595139,959140,415140,724
P26,89027,67729,08829,56628,36028,25728,304
Q259,400261,056277,295285,231269,170269,050269,191
R63,05462,70464,16965,02263,16563,35163,404
S202,065199,902203,180203,680200,831200,794200,857
Total4,442,4524,390,5134,359,0874,338,0854,352,5974,361,9884,367,254
Own processing based on data from the Bank of Italy, ISTAT and Chambers of Commerce. Business categories: B: extraction of minerals from quarries and mines, C: manufacturing, D: supply of electricity, gas, steam and air conditioning, E: supply of water, sewerage, waste management and environmental remediation services, F: construction, G: wholesale and retail trade, repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles, H: transport and storage, I: accommodation and food service businesses, J: information and communications services, K: financial and insurance service businesses, L: real estate businesses, M: professional, scientific and technical businesses, N: rental and travel agencies, business support services, P: education, Q: healthcare and social services, R: arts, sports, entertainment and amusement businesses, S: other service businesses.
Table 3. Number of micro enterprises in Italy (2012–2018).
Table 3. Number of micro enterprises in Italy (2012–2018).
2012201320142015201620172018
B1907185017751712179617951795
C345,293338,015328,486321,837330,613330,526330,459
D83809610991610,205944894459443
E6485668867486816662866266625
F548,709528,592509,648492,388515,477515,341515,237
G1,124,5461,116,0871,086,6311,068,6591,089,7681,089,4811,089,262
H119,126117,430113,241110,756114,173114,143114,120
I288,119294,007292,996295,706290,253290,177290,119
J91,27489,89591,02092,27990,35390,32990,311
K88,99890,63792,83193,79990,79990,77590,757
L234,738242,874238,492237,637236,437236,374236,327
M702,053683,778698,154707,020691,902691,720691,581
N132,452128,082128,721128,394128,327128,294128,268
P25,23925,95727,35127,78126,35926,35226,347
Q253,160254,655270,894278,646262,123262,054262,001
R60,65860,38262,00163,01160,99760,98160,969
S198,593196,542199,755200,185197,103197,051197,011
Total4,229,7304,185,0814,158,6604,136,8314,142,5564,141,4654,140,633
Own processing based on data from the Bank of Italy, ISTAT and Chambers of Commerce.
Table 4. Net non-performing loans in Italy, in billions of euros (March 2012–March 2017).
Table 4. Net non-performing loans in Italy, in billions of euros (March 2012–March 2017).
MonthNPLsMonthNPLs
03-201280.3703-2015140.10
06-201285.1706-2015145.66
09-201288.6309-2015149.29
12-201293.4212-2015151.42
03-201397.3303-2016147.87
06-2013103.6406-2016149.68
09-2013108.9009-2016151.24
12-2013117.5112-2016154.03
03-2014125.3503-2017150.49
06-2014130.28
09-2014133.52
12-2014136.32
Own processing based on data from the Bank of Italy, ISTAT and Chambers of Commerce.
Table 5. Net nonperforming loans in Italy, in billions of euros (June 2017–September 2019).
Table 5. Net nonperforming loans in Italy, in billions of euros (June 2017–September 2019).
MonthNet NPLs
06-2017150.25
09-2017133.97
12-2017128.59
03-2018125.78
06-201899.45
09-201892.28
12-201873.55
03-201967.46
06-201966.08
09-201962.21
Own processing based on data from the Bank of Italy, ISTAT and Chambers of Commerce.
Table 6. Gross lending to enterprises in the United Kingdom, in billions of pounds (September 2010–June 2019).
Table 6. Gross lending to enterprises in the United Kingdom, in billions of pounds (September 2010–June 2019).
MonthLoansMonthLoansMonthLoans
09-20101170.0009-20131014.6009-20161421.70
12-20101167.4012-20131245.5012-20161485.90
03-20111154.5003-20141165.2003-20171444.10
06-20111134.1006-20141312.7006-20171409.30
09-20111177.7009-20141316.5009-20171454.30
12-20111103.4012-20141549.0012-20171419.20
03-20121011.7003-20151427.9003-20181408.80
06-2012950.6006-20151442.4006-20181501.50
09-2012910.2009-20151414.4009-20181407.90
12-2012935.2012-20151502.7012-20181451.90
03-20131012.9003-20161542.5003-20191410.80
06-20131024.7006-20161470.3006-20191372.20
Own processing of data from the Bank of England.
Table 7. Total number of enterprises in the United Kingdom (2009–2018).
Table 7. Total number of enterprises in the United Kingdom (2009–2018).
20092010201120122013
A135,049.21132,628.21132,044.91133,995.51134,798.33
B, D, E24,862.4524,416.7524,309.3624,668.4724,816.26
C233,580.46229,393.11228,384.24231,757.99233,146.54
F856,693.17841,335.40837,635.21850,008.96855,101.69
G478,605.48470,025.61467,958.44474,871.24477,716.37
H275,882.23270,936.54269,744.97273,729.70275,369.72
I163,062.87160,139.67159,435.38161,790.60162,759.95
J296,969.39291,645.67290,363.02294,652.33296,417.71
K78,419.7877,013.9776,675.2677,807.9378,274.10
L92,910.0691,244.4890,843.1992,185.1592,737.46
M723,907.38710,930.03707,803.36718,259.21722,562.58
N404,215.90396,969.60395,223.73401,062.07403,464.99
P274,440.67269,520.83268,335.48272,299.39273,930.85
Q305,627.51300,148.59298,828.54303,242.90305,059.75
R221,942.53217,963.81217,005.21220,210.86221,530.23
S266,270.39261,497.01260,346.95264,192.86265,775.74
Total4,832,439.484,745,809.284,724,937.254,794,735.174,823,462.27
20142015201620172018
A141,754.01147,097.77153,438.79152,991.04152,487.44
B, D, E26,096.8027,080.5828,247.9628,165.5328,072.82
C245,177.04254,419.59265,386.98264,612.56263,741.54
F899,225.45933,123.95973,348.59970,508.29967,313.68
G502,366.82521,304.77543,776.91542,190.13540,405.41
H289,578.97300,495.35313,448.95312,534.29311,505.52
I171,158.46177,610.70185,267.05184,726.43184,118.36
J311,713.04323,463.82337,407.54336,422.96335,315.56
K82,313.0985,416.0989,098.1688,838.1788,545.74
L97,522.77101,199.13105,561.57105,253.53104,907.07
M759,847.24788,491.54822,481.43820,081.37817,381.92
N424,284.02440,278.45459,257.75457,917.60456,410.28
P288,065.84298,925.19311,811.10310,901.22309,877.83
Q320,801.01332,894.39347,244.64346,231.35345,091.67
R232,961.32241,743.37252,164.32251,428.49250,600.86
S279,489.93290,025.98302,528.28301,645.48300,652.55
Total5,072,355.815,263,570.675,490,470.025,474,448.445,456,428.25
Own processing of data from the UK Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy. Business categories: B, D, E: mining and quarrying; supply of electricity, gas and air conditioning; supply of water, sewerage, waste management and environmental remediation services, C: manufacturing, F: construction, G: wholesale and retail trade, repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles, H: transport and storage, I: accommodation and food service businesses, J: information and communications services, K: financial and insurance service businesses, L: real estate businesses, M: professional, scientific and technical businesses, N: administrative and support services, P: education, Q: healthcare and social services, R: arts, entertainment and recreation businesses, S: other service businesses.
Table 8. Net NPLs in the United Kingdom, in billions of pounds (September 2010–June 2019).
Table 8. Net NPLs in the United Kingdom, in billions of pounds (September 2010–June 2019).
MonthNPLsMonthNPLsMonthNPLs
09-2010110.7109-2013113.1409-201632.02
12-2010124.7812-201398.1912-201629.66
03-2011124.7803-201498.1903-201729.66
06-2011124.7806-201498.1906-201729.66
09-2011124.7809-201498.1909-201729.66
12-2011125.0012-201452.1912-201723.19
03-2012125.0003-201552.1903-201823.19
06-2012125.0006-201552.1906-201823.19
09-2012125.0009-201552.1909-201823.19
12-2012113.1412-201532.0212-201833.85
03-2013113.1403-201632.0203-201933.85
06-2013113.1406-201632.0206-201933.85
Own processing of data from the World Bank and International Monetary Fund.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Desogus, M.; Venturi, B. Stability and Bifurcations in Banks and Small Enterprises—A Three-Dimensional Continuous-Time Dynamical System. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2023, 16, 171. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16030171

AMA Style

Desogus M, Venturi B. Stability and Bifurcations in Banks and Small Enterprises—A Three-Dimensional Continuous-Time Dynamical System. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2023; 16(3):171. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16030171

Chicago/Turabian Style

Desogus, Marco, and Beatrice Venturi. 2023. "Stability and Bifurcations in Banks and Small Enterprises—A Three-Dimensional Continuous-Time Dynamical System" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 16, no. 3: 171. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16030171

APA Style

Desogus, M., & Venturi, B. (2023). Stability and Bifurcations in Banks and Small Enterprises—A Three-Dimensional Continuous-Time Dynamical System. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 16(3), 171. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm16030171

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop