1. Introduction
Interactions between banks and enterprises are highly complex and nonlinear. Due to regulations, financial institutions, especially commercial banks, can only engage in financial intermediation. Their operations therefore depend on the caliber and financial standing of their clientele. Where lending strategies are based on credit risk and profit criteria, banks conduct thorough assessments of each counterparty before disbursing loans. Each calculated weighting of the aggregation of segmented units is recorded in the bank’s risk portfolios. Likewise, businesses require bank credit to support investments and keen management to account for the inherent disparities of their working capital. Concurrently, businesses generate positive flows for the banking system, either through income creation, a proportion of which is deposited in banks and supplies banks with funds, or intermediation charges that provide bank revenue.
When bank leverage falls below a certain threshold (
Desogus and Venturi 2019), its power to intervene is reduced as its role changes. The resulting reduction in supervisory provisions, greater availability of liquidity, and increased containment of portfolio risk indicators is often perceived to be a positive, short-term phenomenon. Increasingly acute over time, however, excessive credit restrictions tend to harm the positive environmental factors that help maintain a productive enterprise system (
Rozendaal et al. 2016).
In this work, we improve the analysis of the bank–enterprise two-dynamical system. (
see Desogus and Venturi 2019;
Desogus and Casu 2020b). Indeed, we have noted the significance of positive effects generated by an efficient banking sector that provides liquidity to the business sector so that the banks themselves are kept healthy and performing (
Iyer et al. 2014). We have also found that negative effects are produced by the failure of this situation, and we scrutinized the effectiveness of measures introduced in response to the COVID-19 pandemic lockdowns to avoid a further credit crunch. Such critical events could have occurred because of the generalized impairment of creditworthiness following the nationwide stoppages (
Caggiano et al. 2017;
Petrosky-Nadeau 2013); therefore, we examined the further development of critical default trends in the populations of enterprises and banks in Italy.
Most of the research and studies have been investigated how government interventions aimed at supporting bank lending to the productive sector have indeed developed analyses and considerations on measures that affect bank capitalization, that is, direct injections of liquidity into the system aimed at stimulating credit operations for companies (cf.
Laeven and Valencia 2013; cf. also
Tan et al. 2020). In contrast, this paper instead questions the effects of government intervention strategies based on guarantee measures, while at the same time, it considers certain scenarios characterized by financial crises and measures aimed at counteracting a credit crunch. Such measures are implemented through nominal ceiling allocations, which do not imply an immediate monetary transfer from the government to the banks, bringing with it (also) advantages in public accounting. In particular, we analyze a form of state intervention in business that is accompanied by a government guarantee, up to full coverage even in borderline cases, and zero weighting of bank provisions on the portion guaranteed by the fund, which when structured as they have been—with their immediate enforceability ensured—entails a significant mitigation of the banks’ credit risks.
This work currently represents an innovation in the recent scientific literature, both because of its approach, which is due to its conceptual choice of constructing and using mathematical models emanating from Lotka–Volterra dynamical systems in continuous time for the analysis of the topic, and because of its relevant ability to provide results capable of describing the complex solutions of the system. At the same time, these models succeed in intercepting the instantaneous variations caused by the persistence of the interconnections between banks, enterprises and government in the broader economic activity aimed at wealth production. The structure of the system is supported by a large database and records on business demographics and bank credit flows for Italy and the United Kingdom, which were collected, systematized and broken down into total disbursement volumes and NPLs, which confirm the general outcomes of our system of equations.
This paper goes so far as to establish that government support of bank lending through the provision of public loan guarantees may represent a best practice, particularly in contrast to the side effects of financial crises on the deleveraging of firms by banks. By replicating the examples presented in this paper, the mathematical model proposed can also be used as a tool for measuring the proper implementation of newly established guarantee funds. From a mathematical point of view, we use bifurcation theory (
Nishimura and Shigoka 2019;
Zhao and Zhao 2016;
Neri and Venturi 2007) to confirm the behavior of the dynamic solutions generated by these governments acts against credit restrictions, as empirically observed in the data. Some numerical simulation is presented.
2. The Dataset
Data from Italy relating to time intervals included in the second decade of the 2000s (the precise period is indicated in the caption of each table and figure; see
Table 1,
Table 2,
Table 3 and
Table 4) illustrate the correlation between the contraction of credit—especially what was made available to micro and small enterprises—and an increase in the mortality rate of those enterprises affected. As a consequence, this relationship also brought about increased levels of impaired credit.
Table 1 depicts the progressive reduction in loan disbursements, which we have deemed an independent variable. Adverse consequences to stakeholders in the production sector can be tied to this downward trend. Crucially, however,
Table 2 and
Table 3 show the disparate impacts of the credit crunch on enterprises of different sizes: whilst established micro enterprises exited the market more readily than new companies of a similar size, macro enterprises remained relatively unaffected (
Bassetto et al. 2015). Indeed, based on the data in
Table 1 and
Table 2, the correlation between the reduction in credit granted to the productive sector and the active population of SMEs is +0.73. The aggregate number of viable small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in the market is only marginally corrected by the incidence of macro-enterprises.
Considered alongside each other,
Table 1 and the negative relationship just outlined further correlate with the rise in net non-performing loans (NPLs) prior to the first quarter of 2017, whilst the data in
Table 1 and
Table 4 generate a Bravais–Pearson coefficient of −0.57 for March 2017. Where data in
Table 5 on the number of impaired loans from June 2017 to September 2019 may suggest a pivot to a downward trend, the shift was in fact caused by the European Central Bank guidelines, announced in March 2017, to incentivize the sale of NPLs and strengthen monitoring processes (
European Central Bank 2017). The responses by banks to these measures are reflected in the provisions and losses recorded in their financial statements. According to 2018 and 2019 reports by the ABI (Italian Banking Association) (
ABI-Cerved 2018a,
2018b,
2019b,
2019a), disposals ranged from EUR 50 to 70 billion per period. In fact, the estimated outlook for the 2020 to 2021 period, prior to the COVID-19 emergency, forecast renewed increases in NPLs (
ABI-Cerved 2019a).
Framed as businesses with strategic plans for profit maximization, banks thus continue to covet corporate savings, whilst at the same time they implement risk reduction methods while absorbing risk capital. This entails reducing credit availability, which diminishes short-term guarantee assets and administrative costs. Weakening the resilience of the system, this strategic framework tends to undermine the growth potential of the enterprise population and its ability to maintain stable mortality and birth rates.
The trickle-down effects, however, result in losses for banks caused by reduced funds from deposits and increased costs from impaired assets and net losses (
Bernanke et al. 1994;
Wehinger 2014). Where companies are also the source of salary payments and income for employees—and, by extension, of the entire economic system—these adverse consequences can pro-cyclically affect macroeconomic conditions on a national scale (
Buera et al. 2015).
Moving away from the dynamics of periodic stocks, the graph in
Figure 1, which is based on data from
Table 1,
Table 2,
Table 3,
Table 4 and
Table 5, tracks the percentage change in recorded monthly flows in terms of credit disbursed, demographic rate of enterprises (or the ratio of enterprises entering to those leaving the market), and the number of NPLs in Italy from 2012 to 2018. The data for NPLs only cover the first quarter of 2017, in light of our earlier discussion of regulatory changes for NPL management. Alongside the natural time lag caused by the macro-complexity of the objects analyzed (
Kurkina 2017),
Figure 1 confirms that the contraction of credit granted by banks to maximize their profit margins can be correlated with a progressive decline in (performing) firms in the market and with a general increase in NPLs. Recovering this disbursed credit will also catalyze a reversal of recent trends for NPLs and enterprises.
This reasoning, of course, has greater validity and application for banks operating primarily in the credit market, as a simultaneous diversification of assets would mitigate the cause-and-effect mechanism of the considerations discussed (
Baldini and Causi 2020). To confirm our empirical conclusions, a comparative survey of similar data from the United Kingdom (UK) was conducted.
Table 6,
Table 7 and
Table 8 detail the value of loans disbursed, business demographics and the conditions of NPLs in the UK. In addition, in this case, the datasets relate to time intervals included in the second decade of the 2000s (and, similarly to what was noted for the Italian data, the precise period is indicated in the caption of each table and figure). Because it is situated outside the euro area, the UK was taken as a comparative reference. In this case, we considered micro, small, and medium-sized enterprises (mSME), according to the provisions of the European taxonomic framework. As was observed in Italy, the UK study showed an inverse correlation between the amount of loans disbursed and the number of companies performing in the UK market. This, in turn, correlated with the level of NPLs for the period, accounting for the adjustment delay.
In particular, we examined the effects of the bank rescue package of GBP 50 billion, which was issued by the British government in response to the 2009 to 2010 financial crisis and recession (
Wong 2009). Where the package was designed to increase the amount of money available for banks to lend,
Figure 2 highlights simultaneous regrowth of loan disbursements, recovery of the enterprise population and a decline in NPLs in the first months of 2012.
These trends in the UK economy confirm that ad hoc government intervention that supports the provision of credit to SMEs has a positive impact on the productive fabric. By mitigating, and even negating, the effects of a credit crunch, the intervention helped to stabilize the banking system and prevented the stratification of impaired positions and NPLs in loan portfolios.
3. The General Model
We would now like to consider a purely dynamical nonlinear system:
where the independent state variables are
,
and
;
represents the population of banks,
represents the enterprises, and
the government intervention. Equation (1) thus describes the traditional imbalance caused by dynamic adjustments in the production market (
Calcagnini et al. 2019). Equation (2) refers to the corresponding imbalance in the credit market and repercussions for business demographics. Equation (3) represents government initiatives to help support enterprises to stay in the market. The intrinsic relationship between the populations of banks and enterprises is encompassed in this system of differential equations, in which the number of performing loans of one population is dependent on that of the other population. The populations of banks and enterprises, especially portfolio SMEs, are more sensitive to varying levels of financial support; respectively:
(
Desogus and Venturi 2019).
As such, banks find that restricting credit volumes increases their short-term performance, forcing enterprises out of the market and increasing the number of NPLs. These new circumstances should prompt banks to expand their lending business, which would then reactivate these cycles. Therefore, to preserve the bank–enterprise relationship, it is necessary to maintain the macro-system (see inter al.
Desogus and Casu 2020a;
Degryse and Van Cayseele 2000). This means that the stabilization of levels of leverage in the productive and business sectors should be consistent with the dynamic models profiled above. The recursive phases discussed earlier should be guaranteed, even when standardizing regulations are introduced. This is even more significant for fragile and/or partially impaired economic scenarios or under persistently unfavorable economic conditions (
De Angelo and Roll 2015).
Although the exogenous events that led to the unfavorable economic situation were—more or less—temporary, the repercussions appeared to have been immediately absorbed within the business cycle. Indeed, there was an exacerbation of the phase trajectories, which are normally pseudo-elliptical, toward an intensification of the credit contraction period and a manifestation of a progressive delay in the spontaneous rebound reaction of the bank–small-enterprise system (
Ganong and Liebman 2018).
In Italy, the main objective of government economic intervention during the COVID-19 emergency was to maintain proper operations of the bank–enterprise system. Here, it is crucial to note that the 2020 economic crisis was caused by exogenous elements—and not by pathologies internal to the system, as for example happened in the 2009–2011 crisis. Management of the current situation therefore focuses on ensuring temporary compensation for the sudden halt in productive activities, placing less emphasis on restoring economic and financial aspects that have themselves been damaged.
As delineated in Decree Laws No. 18 and No. 23 of 2020, the Italian government shifted its resource flows to direct public guarantees—in the model that we are considering, this effect is mathematically expressed by
—making them also immediately enforceable and with zero weighting on allocations (
D’Ignazio and Menon 2020). Other measures included reinsurance for the credit guarantee consortia, offering free access and coverage of between 80% and 90% for most lending operations. Instead of injecting liquidity into the productive system (and households) with ‘helicopter money’ or other direct forms, the Italian government focused on strengthening public guarantee funds. In this way, the government allowed banks to retain their role of financial intermediation unchanged, whilst also encouraging a quantitative expansion of credit provisions.
In light of this, it is apparent that a strong productive sector fosters a healthy banking sector, which in turn cultivates favorable circumstances for enterprises. It is therefore necessary for us to delve further into the dynamics of the bank–enterprise system as we take into consideration the limits imposed by the macroeconomic and idiosyncratic components peculiar to each enterprise in the population .
Hence, we would like to now consider the following three-dimensional continuous-time Lotka–Volterra model involving the population of banks being
, the population of enterprises being
, and the government intervention as
. Adapting Equation (3) for a purely three-dimensional economic nonlinear model, the system of equations as independent state variables is then:
This arrangement represents the interpretation of the purely dynamical nonlinear system formed by Equations (1)–(3), which has been constructed taking the contribution of government intervention on systemic effects through guarantees provided by the central fund into account. In this sense, government action is always aimed at MSMEs, which end up being the beneficiaries of support through the government guarantee. Instead, the population of banks receives these effects ‘reflexively’. Therefore, the mere algebraic sum of the two components
and
has been correctly imputed in the re-elaboration of the third equations (and replaced in the first), since there is no direct relationship between banks and the government intervention in support of the provision of credit. This reflexivity can be seen in the second equation of (
S), in the
contribution. Even the bank financing operations, provided by the Central Bank, (TLTRO—targeted longer-term refinancing operations) do not determine any interaction between
and
, being, for all intents and purposes, loans, albeit dependent on the subsequent granting of credit to the enterprises by the borrowing banks (
Castellacci and Choi 2014;
Ledenyov and Ledenyov 2012;
Hori and Futagami 2019).
The first equation is characterized from the following parameters: , where is an adjustment parameter in the traditional imbalance in the production market equation, is an interaction parameter between the population of the bank and enterprises in the first equation, is an interaction parameter between the population of the bank and enterprises in the second equation, is the decrease rate of the population of the enterprises, and k is the decrease rate of the population of the banks, with as the activation of the government guarantee fund. In a situation in which adequate leverage is available, the second equation is characterized by the following parameters: , where is an adjustment parameter in the credit market equation, is the growth rate of the population of enterprises, and is an interaction parameter between the population of the bank and the government intervention.
The vector of parameters abides inside the parameter space ∀ .
3.1. Steady States and Local Stability Properties
Let
be a generic point. Recall that a stationary (equilibrium) point
(
) of our system
is any solution such that:
The differential equations in
, solved for
,
, and
imply the following steady state value:
(
), with:
As mentioned in
Section 3, intervention through fund
F ensures indirect support for the disbursement of credit through collateral coverage payable; at the time of its activation, the fund will necessarily be
. That is,
represents an interaction parameter between the populations of banks and companies and also signals a (reciprocal) influence on the effects of a credit contraction. The incidence of
will therefore tend asymptotically toward the
parameter, with the effectiveness of
being reduced as it approaches
.
In Italy, this was acutely apparent as new operational provisions to reform the guarantee fund came into force on 15 March 2019 (pursuant to a 6 March 2017 inter-ministerial decree) (
MISE—Ministero dello Sviluppo Economico 2019). The main changes included the redefinition of intervention methods as direct guarantees, of reinsurance, and counter-guarantees. In addition, there was also the application of a valuation model based on the probability of default by beneficiary companies over all of the fund’s operations, the reorganization of measures covered, maximum guaranteed amounts, and the introduction of operations focusing on tripartite risk (
Hassan et al. 2022). In other words, the FCG (Central Guarantee Fund) is now equipped with a rating system for incoming applications, which makes guarantee percentages inversely proportional to the credit risk posed by the beneficiary company; stable companies, which ipso facto have interaction parameters (
and
), would be compatible with regular funding requirements and would receive moderate
assistance, whilst companies that are more at risk would receive greater
support. By considering feasible parameter values, we are presenting, for notational convenience, the following subset:
where the system’s steady state solution is called
(
.
3.2. Local Analysis
As is well-known, in a hyperbolic equilibrium point
, the local dynamical properties of a nonlinear system are described, for brevity, in terms of the Jacobian matrix (
Refaai et al. 2022). Hence, let
denote the Jacobian matrix of system
. So, simple algebra leads to the following
matrix:
Let be evaluated at the equilibrium point : =.
Then, the Jacobian matrix
can be evaluated at the steady-state value
for brevity, which is given by:
We therefore obtain:
where
is the trace of
, and
, and
is the sum of the principal minor of
. Note that the eigenvalues of
are the solutions of the characteristic equation:
where
I is the identity matrix.
We focus on local analysis in the set
Proposition 1. Let then:
- (a)
If , h*there exist two subsetsandsuch that when,has one eigenvalue with a positive real part and two eigenvalues with negative real parts, and when,has three eigenvalues with positive real parts. This means that if, we will have instability.
- (b)
If>, h*there exist two subsetsandsuch that when,has three eigenvalues with negative real parts, and when,has one eigenvalue with a negative real part and two eigenvalues with positive real parts. This means that the equilibriumwill be locally unique.
Proof. These results were obtained by applying the Routh–Hurwitz stability criterion to the system
, according to which the number of the positive eigenvalues of the Jacobian matrix
, evidently evaluated at the steady states
, will be equal to the number of variations of the sign in the scheme:
Case 1a. Let be and then:
When , and are positive, the sign of can be positive. In this case, we have one eigenvalue with a positive real part and two eigenvalues with negative parts, so will be an unstable saddle.
Case 1b. Let be and , then:
When , and are positive, the sign of can be negative. In this case, we have three eigenvalues with positive real parts, so will be a completely unstable saddle.
Case 2a. Let be and , then:
Both and are always negative, and the sign of is negative. In this case, we have three eigenvalues with negative real parts, so will be a stable saddle.
Case 2b. Let be and , then:
Both and are always negative, and the sign of is positive. In this case, we have one eigenvalue with a negative real part and two eigenvalues with positive real parts, so is a saddle focus. □
4. Global Analysis
Here, we need to go beyond the conventional stability analysis and use bifurcation theory. We have chosen h as the bifurcation parameter to examine the existence of Hopf bifurcating closed orbits from the steady state: (, , ).
Lemma 1. If , then there exists at least one value h = h* such that has a pair of purely imaginary roots.
Proof. Since changes sign in , by the Routh–Hurvitz criterion, we state that has one positive (real) eigenvalue and two complex conjugate roots whose real parts can be either positive or negative. It means that the two complex conjugate roots of can be either positive or negative. Furthermore, since the real parts of the complex conjugate roots vary continuously with respect to h, there must exist at least one value such that . When this occurs, by Vieta’s theorem, has a simple pair of purely imaginary eigenvalues. The sign ofis independent of ; Vieta’s theorem has been used properly. (Q.E.D.) □
Lemma 2. If , then the derivative of the real part of the complex conjugate eigenvalues with respect to h, evaluated at h = , will always be different from zero.
Proof. To prove that
cannot be zero at the bifurcation point
, by following the strategy developed by
Benhabib and Miyao (
1981), we show that:
Whereas is a second-degree polynomial in h changing sign at h = (see Lemma 1 proof), the bifurcation points cannot coincide with the minimum or maximum of the function. Therefore, there must be a neighborhood of h* where the derivative of with respect to h is different from zero. (Q.E.D.) □
Theorem 1. Assuming the hypotheses of Lemmas 1 and 2, then, there will be a continuous functionwith, and for all that are small enough, there will be a continuous family of non-constant positive periodic solutions (, , ) for the dynamical system (S), which will then collapse to the stationary point (, , ) as .
Proof. (It follows from the Hopf bifurcation theorem; see
Appendix A.) □
Example 1. Let h^;
Set.
According to Proposition 1, the equilibrium pointwill be a saddle focus with three eigenvalues with a real positive part: Example 2. Let ;
Set
According to Proposition 1, the equilibrium pointwill be a saddle focus with one real eigenvalue with a real positive part and two complex eigenvalues with a real negative part. Example 3. Let and ;
Set.
Then a Hopf bifurcation will result with eigenvalues Then, we know that there is a continuous family of non-constant positive periodic solutions P*(z*1, z*2, z*3) for the dynamical system (S), which collapses at the equilibrium point P*1 (z*1, z*2, z*3) as.
5. The Zero-Hopf Bifurcation
We will use
F as a bifurcation parameter to show that the linearization matrix of the righthand side of the system
, evaluated at the steady state, will have a zero eigenvalue. More specifically:
When we consider that , since we have assumed that , then we should remember that:
- ➢
Where is an adjustment parameter in the traditional imbalance in the production market equation;
- ➢
is the rate of decrease in the bank loans’ performance correlated to periods of negative demographics of SMEs;
- ➢
is the interaction parameter between banks and enterprises;
- ➢
describes the damping (or absorption effect)—on enterprises—of the oscillatory motion of the system dynamics and, in particular, of the compensatory intervention of the fund.
Therefore, if then , i.e., when the rate of decrease in the positive performance of the banking portfolios is equal to the product of the fund. However, there will be a difference among the damping and bank–enterprise interactions, normalized by the relationship with the absorption parameter.
We can also write the previous relation with respect to
:
In this situation, the intervention of the fund manages to maintain the condition of the system, yet without improving the performance indicators of the companies or the banks.
Theorem 2 (Gavrilov–Guckenheimer bifurcation)
. Let . Furthermore, let u = u() and v = v() such that at the same time and .
Then,has one real zero eigenvalueand two purely imaginary eigenvalues given bywhere.
Proof. We consider the matrix
that represents the Jacobian matrix
put into a normal form:
where
are evaluated at the bifurcation point
.
Let the parameters
choose, such that:
Then: .
So, we can rewrite
as:
in (14) vanishes and has at least one eigenvalue equal to zero.
Let . □
We can now show analytically and numerically that there is a Gavrilov–Guckenheimer two-bifurcation codimension. This phenomenon, which has recently been closely studied, takes the form of a pitchfork–Hopf interaction (
Bella and Mattana 2018;
Bosi and Desmarchelier 2018;
Bella et al. 2022), which is a linear degeneracy that can be associated with the onset of a 2-torus trapping region in the three-dimensional space enclosed by a two-dimensional surface (see
Figure 3).
Considering the case of the initial conditions
, then the attractor will have the form represented in
Figure 4.
6. Discussion
As the nonlinear differential equations defining this system are continuous and derivable complex functions, this system is also conditioned by a set of interaction and adjustment parameters that make each population dependent on the other. Conducting a dynamical analysis of the unique steady-state model, we applied a Jacobian matrix to describe the local dynamical properties of the hyperbolic equilibrium points . Considering the derived eigenvalues in the parameter space , we found that the equilibrium path is locally unique. Furthermore, by applying the Routh–Hurwitz criterion, we ascertained the fundamental stability of the system such that, for each instance that the fund was relied upon, . In practice, this means that the fund was structured to provide a guarantee that was inversely proportional to the credit risk posed by the company under review.
Where the economic crisis resulting from the COVID-19 pandemic and subsequent lockdowns in 2020 was caused by factors external to the financial economic system, we found that measures introduced by the Italian government were not focused on correcting the existing bank–enterprise system or aspects of it that may have suffered because of the crisis. Rather, those interventions sought to maintain the fabric of the bank–enterprise system healthy by attending to the unexpected lapses in productive activities. In particular, the Italian government made adjustments to the system by providing collateral coverage, payable through its public guarantee fund F, and by encouraging the continuation and increase in credit transactions.
Exploring the impacts of this intervention on the economic financial system and considering the growth rate of the small enterprises as bifurcation parameters, we were able to prove the existence of a stable Hopf cycle. Following from the collapse of all sufficiently small growth rates of the population of enterprises ρ(h) in a continuous family of non-constant positive periodic solutions to stationary point , we produced evidence of the existence of Hopf and zero-Hopf periodic solutions and that these tended to bifurcate from a saddle focus in a particular region of the parameter space. In addition, we observed the simultaneous occurrence of a zero eigenvalue and two purely imaginary eigenvalues (Hopf bifurcation), which gave rise to a Gavrilov–Guckenheimer bifurcation. In treating government intervention and the growth rate of the population of enterprises as two bifurcation parameters, we were able to deduce the existence of a two-bifurcation-related codimension with the persistence of a pre-existing Hopf limit cycle.
From this, we noted that whilst the intervention of fund F allowed for the condition of the system to be maintained, there was no indication that it improved the performance of companies or banks. In other words, when the relationship between the performance of banks, the absorption parameter and the interaction parameter between banks and enterprises is equal to the effect of the fund, the system achieves stability with no instrumental positive or negative change.
As we continue to operate with the uncertainties and instability introduced by the COVID-19 pandemic, understanding the underlying mechanisms of the options available to governments for ensuring continued stability and function of our financial economic systems is crucial (
Xu et al. 2022). Of potentially critical importance is identifying at what point, if at all, the Gavrilov–Guckenheimer bifurcation may bring the system into chaos. Further investigation may identify how the measures implemented by the Italian government in 2020 might be able to move beyond maintaining pre-existing performance levels. Perhaps these measures could also be applied to improving the performance of banks and companies, or in combination with other instruments to achieve similar or enhanced results. Additional research could also consider the feasibility and effectiveness of these measures in economies with structures dissimilar to Italy’s.
Since the COVID-19 pandemic was an exogenous force, this paper does not address impairments of creditworthiness or strategies for avoiding or mitigating credit crunches caused by poor internal structures. Likewise, it offers only a partial contribution to discussions on how to respond if an economic financial system were to suffer from contemporaneous exogenous and endogenous shocks (for instance, if the conditions of the COVID-19 pandemic and the 2009–2011 crisis were to occur at the same time).
7. Conclusions
This paper is attempting to provide some valuable insights on the interconnections and dependencies between banks, enterprises and the government in the interest of preventing a credit crunch enjoined by external factors. With the help of dynamical systems analysis and bifurcation theory, we have analyzed how the intervention of the guarantee fund in Italy has maintained the stability of the financial and economic system.
Drawing on
Bischi and Tramontana (
2010) for the discrete application of similar dynamical systems and on earlier two-dimensional modeling of the bank–enterprise system by
Desogus and Casu (
2020b), we have developed a three-dimensional continuous-time Lotka–Volterra dynamical model that demonstrates the interactions between populations of banks and enterprises and the government in a given financial system. Specifically, we focused on those interactions that are facilitated by credit transactions and the role of the guarantee fund in supporting the continuation of credit exchanges during periods of economic crisis.
This modeling has been informed by the cyclical trends that characterize economic financial models and that cause these systems to oscillate between states of stability and instability. This trajectory was confirmed through a comparative analysis of data from Italy and the UK that outlines how ad hoc government intervention in support of credit disbursement has helped to alleviate pressures within the system, to decrease the risk of impaired credit ratings and non-performing loans and to prevent a looming credit crunch.