Next Article in Journal
Long-Term Solar Photovoltaics Penetration in Single- and Two-Family Houses in Switzerland
Next Article in Special Issue
EU Carbon Emissions Market Development and Its Impact on Penetration of Renewables in the Power Sector
Previous Article in Journal
A New Wind Power Accommodation Strategy for Combined Heat and Power System Based on Bi-Directional Conversion
Previous Article in Special Issue
Achievements of the European Union Countries in Seeking a Sustainable Electricity Sector
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Real Levelized Cost of Energy with Indirect Costs and Market Value of Variable Renewables: A Study of the Korean Power Market

Department of Energy System Engineering, Chung-Ang University, 84 Heukseok-ro, Dongjak-gu, Seoul 06974, Korea
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2019, 12(13), 2459; https://doi.org/10.3390/en12132459
Submission received: 9 May 2019 / Revised: 20 June 2019 / Accepted: 24 June 2019 / Published: 26 June 2019
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Development and Implementation of Models of Electricity Market 2019)

Abstract

:
A levelized cost of energy (LCOE) is a methodology for comparing power generation costs in the transition to renewable energy (RE). However, the major limitation of evaluating RE based on the LCOE is that it does not consider indirect costs, such as the environmental and curtailment effect. This paper proposes the real LCOE (rLCOE) approach that accounts for indirect and direct generation costs. The mathematical approach to estimating indirect costs is derived from economic theory. The indirect effects, which quantify all benefits generated due to RE, is related to the variability of the share RE in the energy generation mix. The rLCOE enhances the accuracy of the economic comparison of power generation costs and the derivation of the optimal quantities of RE because external effects are incorporated into the LCOE principles. This approach has taken into account electricity demand, fuel prices, and environmental costs for each energy source to adequately compare generation costs. Simulations have been performed to demonstrate the application of the rLCOE approach in the Korean power market. Here, the unit variation of costs with the RE share were analyzed. The results show that indirect cost savings of an additional unit of RE begin to fall in scenario 3 in contrast to the result of LCOE approach indicating higher generation costs with RE share, especially, the proportion of RE in the generation mix is higher than 20%. Thus, the optimal power generation can be evaluated using the rLCOE approach.

1. Introduction

1.1. Background and Literature Review

The world is facing substantial environmental and energy challenges, one-third of the world’s population still does not have access to electricity, and that some developing countries have a plan to use fossil fuels as the major source of energy. Although this trend has existed, an economical and environmental source of electricity is required to fulfill the environmental regulation. However, there are some challenges with the feasibility of electricity generation from different sources, particularly as renewable energy (RE) is added to the grid. What is the real cost of transitioning to renewable energy? What is the optimal power mix for accommodating RE into the power grid efficiently?
To respond to these questions, various methodologies have been proposed to calculate the optimal RE share regarding low-carbon emissions [1,2,3,4,5]. Specifically, these studies have been conducted in terms of integrative and distributive generation planning. Reference [1] proposed the integration for distributed generation approach and determined an optimal investment plan to fulfill physical, economic, and operational constraints. In Reference [2], an integrated planning approach was also addressed and the probabilistic distribution was used for calculating the carbon footprint of distribution systems that included both direct and indirect emissions. Especially, reference [3] used an active-reactive optimal power flow containing carbon footprint allocation while considering transmission losses. In References [4,5], the carbon emission flow model that was introduced helps to clearly allocate carbon emission mitigation among different energy sources. However, these research approaches focused on single or hybrid systems, thus limiting their ability to consider the indirect effects of power systems as an economic principle.
On the other hand, levelized cost of energy (LCOE) is widely used as a methodological approach capable of comparing the profitability of different power sources while also calculating the optimal RE share. Policy makers in particular use LCOE to estimate and respond to the above-mentioned questions. The LCOE represents the cost of the entire life cycle per unit of power generation. Thus, it enables the comparison of generation costs of RE and non-renewable energy (NRE) [6]. RE sources show high fixed costs and low variable costs, while NRE sources have different fixed-to-variable-cost ratios. When the LCOE of RE is lower than that of NRE, it is conducive to the deployment of RE, and its penetration rate is accelerated [7].
There have been extensive studies on the use of LCOE in the electricity market. The effect of the variability of RE on system integration cost was analyzed in Reference [8]. Here, the author emphasized that the LCOE cannot demonstrate the economics of RE. In Reference [9], the electricity generation should respond to variable demand and cannot maintain uniform quality due to its variability. Therefore, the amount of electricity generated by RE can be different each time. Since the amount of RE generation is determined by an externality such as wind and solar density, the LCOE represents a variable value [10]. However, the LCOE neglects the temporal variability of electricity [11].
More recently, some important pioneering works have developed an effective economic approach to determining the LCOE [12,13,14,15]. An extended LCOE that applies economic theory has been utilized to evaluate power generation costs in [12]. Here, if the LCOE of RE is equal to the marginal economic value, it can be considered economically efficient under the conditions of a perfect market. In [13], the marginal system LCOE was proposed to formalize the arguably vague concept of integration costs. Here, the integration cost in terms of marginal LCOE has been estimated for RE penetration levels as high as 60% [13,14]. Furthermore, in [15], results indicated the same economic effect was achieved, assuming a perfect market where the marginal cost is equal to the market value. However, the above works did not evaluate indirect effects including environmental costs and the curtailment effect, as based on economic theory. Therefore, it is recommended that future studies continue to operationalize and measure the indirect effects of RE.
Meanwhile, other recent studies have considered a social value of the power market. In Reference [16], the economic assessment could account for both the cost and the social value of the technology. Social value became integral to understanding the representation of risk in the large wind power industry. This paper inspired critical costs modeling for wind energy projects including market risk mitigation strategies that included a review of social impacts. Especially, in [17], the authors recognize that indirect effects could cause market distortion and noted that it is difficult to assess indirect effects because a chain of cross-market price effects is involved. At the same time, the magnitudes, types, and interactions of economic distortions can also affect their size. That is the reason why many empirical results acknowledge the existence of indirect effects as a special case. For example, a decline in the share of RE in California as a result of market distortion effects was identified by [18,19]. Namely, the economic value of wind power is significantly reduced when the wind share increases from 0% to 60%. The authors proved the difficulty of comparing the LCOE of RE sources accurately. Thus, our research assumes a perfect market to reflect the economics of RE and evaluates external costs from an economic perspective. It reinforces the necessity of an improved approach to evaluating RE sources. Finally, our research conducted an in-depth analysis of power market factors including an indirect effect replacing NRE with RE penetration levels.

1.2. Contribution and Paper Organization

Our research proposes a new rLCOE approach that includes all of the economic, social, and indirect costs associated with RE. While based on the LCOE principle, this approach also reflects indirect effects. There is no unified definition for indirect costs in economic theory [20]. Thus, continued efforts are required in order to expand an effective approach for the estimation of indirect costs that are related to the economics of RE. Consequently, our work shows the mathematical expression for overall cost based on economic theory, so that the rLCOE is constructed as the sum of the generation costs including total indirect costs. The main purpose of rLCOE is to evaluate RE and NRE more efficiently. In fact, our approach can also reflect the market perspective. In summary, the main contributions of this work are categorized as follows:
(1)
The evaluation of power generation costs using the LCOE is constructed to be applicable to the comparison of generation sources. The rLCOE is intuitive and incorporates existing LCOE principles while expanding it to reflect external costs.
(2)
The rLCOE is linked to the economic concept of the market value, in contrast, the LCOE is only based on and limited to the current operation of the power system. More importantly, the estimation of the cost of the power system considers both direct and indirect effects; both are related to economic theory.
(3)
The indirect effect is related to the variability of RE. It can be quantified in terms of all benefits generated due to RE using the rLCOE approach.
(4)
It can explain the most important factors affecting the unit generation cost while analyzing the effect of the RE share through rLCOE.
(5)
All social welfare (SW) measures that incorporate the indirect effects from the RE share can be calculated, and differences from the existing methodology can be presented.
Unlike the existing LCOE approach, the rLCOE can account for indirect costs and directly calculate the costs incurred from RE. For example, the electricity price reflects the marginal cost and estimates the total cost derived from the current market environment. The rLCOE and indirect costs are derived as a quantitative expression, which can be applied to estimate market costs. The indirect costs of high RE shares can be evaluated as a range of costs with variability in accordance with fuel costs. Although indirect costs can be varied with growing RE shares, it can also present an economic barrier in terms of the expansion of the proportion of RE in the power generation mix.
This paper is organized as follows: In Section 2, the rLCOE is conceptually defined and quantified using a mathematical formulation that reflects economic formulas. In Section 3, we conceptualize the correlation between rLCOE and market value. Section 4 presents the methodology to estimate the changes in market values caused by changes in several key factors including demand and fuel costs. In Section 5, the methodology is applied to the Korean power market to evaluate the impact of RE on the grid in terms of market value, and conclusions are drawn in Section 6.

2. rLCOE Analysis

The LCOE is commonly applied to compare different power generation. The LCOE is expressed in terms of the unit cost ($/kWh) of electricity generation when the present value of expected profits from electricity sales is equivalent to the present value of all expected costs during the lifecycle [8]. The LCOE has several improvements as a cost metric, such as its ability to standardize costs into an easily comprehensible format across technology types [21]. Ultimately, it has become the standard formulation for cost comparisons and is applied by public authorities and many other stakeholders. Although it is widely used, the LCOE only examines the factors affecting the total direct costs of generating electricity, which cannot include indirect costs like environmental effects [22]. For that reason, previous research emphasizes that both direct and indirect costs should be considered to overcome the limitation of the LCOE [23]. In addition, recent studies of indirect costs of power generation have estimated different cost components using a bottom up approach. Namely, “air pollutant costs”, “water pollutant costs”, “human impact costs”, and “system costs” have been examined [12,24]. It is assumed that these components add up to total indirect costs, even though it is hard to consider all components.
For solving these problems, in our work, total environmental costs and indirect benefits are derived using a top-down approach. The rLCOE calculation is formulated as Equation (1) for including the direct and indirect plant costs as follows:
r L C O E = I C + O C ( 1 + r ) n A P ( 1 + r ) n + Δ ,
where n is the lifetime of the plant; IC is the initial investment costs, OC is the O&M (operating and maintenance) costs, AP represent the annual energy production at year t; r means the discount rate; and Δ indicates the indirect costs. The indirect costs Δ is given by:
Δ = d d E R E C N R E .
Equation (2) denotes the marginal indirect benefit including the environmental cost of increasing RE capacity instead of NRE. It is to be noted that opportunity costs are a form of indirect costs. Here, Δ represents marginal indirect benefit when the NRE is escalated as CNRE, cost of NRE, while a RE generation ERE is varied. Thus, the simplified rLCOE can be calculated as:
r L C O E = L C O E + Δ .
However, it is difficult to determine the indirect benefit when RE are added to the power market. Therefore, our research tried to formalize the rLCOE so that it was in line with Equation (3). We defined that the opportunity costs of a power source were all additional costs of NRE when RE was introduced. Since indirect costs cannot be measured or estimated directly, instead, a single system, with and without RE, need to be compared to identify additional indirect costs. For the RE case, the annual power demand Et in an electricity market is given by:
E t = E N R E + E R E ,
where ENRE denotes NRE electricity generation, Et is total electricity generation, and ERE is RE generation. Et is partly supplied by ERE. The resulting ENRE needs to be provided by dispatchable power plants.
Referring to Equation (4), Et is partly supplied by RE and NRE and total costs can be formulated as:
C t = C N R E C R E ,
C R E = E N R E E t C t ( 0 ) .
Here, Ct is the total cost, divided into the generation costs of RE and all other costs for NRE, Ct(0) is the average costs in a system without NRE. Since indirect costs of RE are designated as not being part of generation costs of RE, they can emerge from comparing the CNRE with and without RE. Unfortunately, the absolute difference of the costs can contain direct and indirect costs. Thus, it is important to define the specific costs per unit of NRE. This reconciles the problem of different values of NRE and RE. In Equation (6), indirect costs can stand for the difference of specific costs in the NRE system increased by ENRE when RE generation is volatile. The specific indirect costs CNRE/ENRE typically increase without RE.
Equation (6) comprises the additional costs in the NRE when introducing RE. The rLCOE can be evaluated with any power energy mix and it can estimate indirect costs comparing cases with and without RE.

3. Evaluation of Social Welfare Using rLCOE

The rLCOE can be expressed as the marginal cost of an additional RE.
C t m i n ,
d d E R E C t = 0 .
In Equations (7) and (8), the cost-optimal deployment of RE is reached. This occurs when the total costs of a power mix are minimal when the share of RE varies. According to Equations (6)–(8), the total costs can be expressed as:
C t = C R E + C N R E E t E R E C t ( 0 ) .
Inserting this into the optimal Equation (9) indicates:
d d E R E C t = d d E R E C R E + d d E R E C N R E 1 d E R E d d E R E C t ( 0 ) .
In Equation (10), the interpretation of these terms gives the meaning for the evaluation of RE. The first summand is the marginal generation costs of RE expressed by rLCOERE and the second summand is the marginal indirect costs of NRE. The third summand is equal to 0 when RE is not present. Note that NRE creates indirect costs that have to be included in total costs Ct. Accordingly, the third summand equals the average indirect costs of the system as follows:
0 = r L C O E R E + r L C O E N R E 1 E t C t ( 0 ) .
Using Equation (11), the optimal condition is evaluated as follows:
C t ( 0 ) E t = r L C O E R E + r L C O E N R E ,
r L C O E R E = r L C O E N R E .
It can be seen from Equations (12) and (13) that the optimal deployment of RE is given by the point where the absolute value of rLCOERE is equal to the rLCOENRE. In Equation (13), the left-hand side can be explained as the marginal economic costs of RE, while the right-hand side can be seen as the value of RE because it represents the opportunity cost of covering power demand with NRE generation. In other words, RE deployment is optimal where the marginal economic costs of RE meet with their value, which is in line with economic theory.
Figure 1 illustrates the rLCOE approach depending on RE and NRE deployment. Firstly, Figure 1a depicts the correlation between rLCOE and RE deployment whereby indirect costs increase with higher RE deployment and can be negative, in particular if the penetration of RE is low. Figure 1b shows the relationships between rLCOE and market value when RE deployment varies. Here, the intersection of increasing rLCOE of RE and average costs in NRE gives an optimal quantity expressed as E*. By adding indirect costs to LCOE, rLCOE can be used to derive the optimal share of RE in the power generation market. In order to account for indirect costs and the market value of RE, an equivalent perspective can be explained as the marginal cost savings in the NRE when increasing the RE deployment. According to [25], SW is related with the quality of life that includes factors such as the condition of the environment (air, soil, water) and essential social services. In general, an increase in SW results in a decrease in social costs [26].
S W = d d E R E C N R E .
Equation (14) assumes marginal indirect costs, which can be explained as the cutback of the market value equal to SW. It can be compared to the average costs of NRE that correspond with the annual electricity price in a perfect market. The reduction of the market value is not only driven by the variability of RE, but can also be interpreted as the economic costs of variability. Inserting Equation (2) into (14), the optimal condition Equations (15) and (16) can be rephrased as follows:
Δ = d d E R E C N R E = C t ( 0 ) E t S W ,
Δ = S W .
The market value decreases with RE penetration. The optimal deployment of RE is given by the point where the market value of RE equals their marginal generation costs. To sum up, the methodology of accounting for indirect costs leads to the derivation of optimal levels of power generation from RE. It measures all the quantitative impacts of the variable power mix. In addition, it can calculate indirect costs expressed as market value. The market value of RE has the opposite effect to costs, which might be induced, in particular, during hours of high RE supply [19,27]. Since it is noted that the market value can be obtained from actual prices, it allows the quantification of indirect costs from market prices, if markets can be assumed to be perfect.

4. Estimation of Indirect Costs

4.1. Sensitivity Analysis

The Korean power market has been operated as a cost-based pool [28]. The market price is not only determined by the fuel cost, but because RE has a very low marginal cost, it can reduce the price of power. In this research, variation of the fuel costs, and variation of the electricity demand can be regarded as significant parameters for the sensitivity analysis.
Sensitivity analysis considers the level of uncertainty of the output that can be evaluated in terms of different sources of uncertainty in its inputs. Sensitivity analysis can be conducted using three different approaches: (i) Mathematical; (ii) statistical; and (iii) graphical [29]. The mathematical method assesses the sensitivity of a result to the change of an input using multiple input values. The statistical method involves conducting simulations in which inputs are set probability distributions and the variance in inputs is assessed based on the output distribution. The graphical method gives a representation of the sensitivity of outputs with respect to input changes in the form of graphs and charts. Mathematical sensitivity analysis will be conducted in our work. Although it does not address the variance in the output with respect to the volatility in the inputs, it can assess the effect of variation in screening important inputs. In addition, this method can be used for verification, and to distinguish inputs that requisite more advanced research. The mathematical sensitivity analysis is given by:
S e n s i t i v i y _ v a l u e = E t F C r L C O E ,
where FC denotes fuel costs, and Et is equal to total power demand.

4.2. Procedure of Proposed rLCOE Approach

The flowchart shown in Figure 2 illustrates our rLCOE analysis. SW can be obtained to determine the optimal RE mix in each scenario. The procedure for simulation is as follows:
Step 1: Initialize inputs and generate the scenario.
(1) Start with an initialization of inputs, which include CAPEX, OC, and the capacity factor.
(2) Generate a scenario based on the portion of RE capacity.
(3) Formulate total rLCOE with indirect factors. Total indirect cost will change according to each scenario.
Step 2: Evaluate SW by solving the rLCOE given in each scenario.
It is based on the result from rLCOE. Note that it can be checked whether the overall indirect cost of the power market is within the defined limits. If not, the rLCOE is infeasible. The scenario should be repaired, and step 2 can be repeated.
Step 3: Compare the rLCOE.
Each scenario is solved for rLCOE to obtain the figure for SW, which leads to the lowest total cost including indirect costs. After that, the sensitivity analysis can be conducted and the optimal RE mix comparing the scenario results can be printed and the procedure is finished.

5. Case Study

5.1. Data Description and Scenario Assumptions

The market price of power is determined by a number of different factors such as demand, power mix, fuel, CO2 price, and RE penetration. Since the future values of these factors can be determined by a policy framework at the country level, it is important to generate scenarios that appropriately follow government policy. In our work, the demand and the installed power capacity have been used in the 8th power supply plan in Korea [30]. Since this plan includes a target level of power capacity, generation mixes, and subsidy programs for the next 14 years (2018–2031), they are considered using the proposed rLCOE approach. Figure 3 shows the example of the power supply plan representing the average annual electricity demand with the growth rate. The growth of electricity demand is assumed to be 2.1%, which indicates that electricity demand has entered a low growth phase. The RE generation capacity in the power supply plan follows the RE target. Our study sets the proportion of RE with reference to the RE 3020 plan [31]. It assumes an increasing share of RE penetration in Korea, for instance, the total RE share in the generation mix rises to 20% by 2030. The variability of RE is also considered in this work. The data of yearly power generation profiles for RE are taken from the Korean Power Exchange [32]. In order to evaluate the effect of increasing RE generation to market price, our study took into account the historical average variations of RE utilization.
In Korea, the market price is determined by the marginal cost of the power plant [33], and then it can be linked to the international crude oil price. Since Asian LNG (Liquefied Natural Gas) is usually contracted from the Middle East, this contract type is mainly based on the crude oil price [34]. In our work, fuel costs are applied using assumptions based on IEA (International Energy Association) forecasts. Figure 4 shows the crude oil and gas price forecasts of the World Energy Outlook released by IEA [35]. The IEA data shows that crude oil prices rise to $124/bbl. by 2040, and LNG prices go up to $12.4/mmBTU.
The annualized total costs can be also computed for the proposed approach. Table 1 depicts the cost parameter of the energy source. It shows the fixed costs of each energy source and indicates other parameters used to compute the annualized costs. The annualized costs, which are inputs to the model, are used from cost estimates of the initial investment costs and fixed operational and maintenance costs. The interest rate is assumed to be 5%. The variable costs are computed from the cost estimates of the variable O&M and fuel costs.
Table 2 indicates the emission pollutants factors of the energy sources representing marginal damages. These data were used to calculate the total indirect costs. It determines the emission quantity and pollutant costs for rLCOE. Certainly, coal and crude oil have high CO2 emission factors; gas generates fewer emissions than other fossil fuels.
Emission costs are calculated by the average emission factor, which refers to the unit power plant energy consumption in power plants and the amount of emissions of CO2, SOx, NOx, and fine dust. Total emissions are multiplied by the unit’s fuel consumption, net calorific value of fuel, and emission factors, and are then divided by the total electricity consumed. The calculation Equation (18) is as follows:
f x = M x Q = F i × N V C i × M x i Q
where Mx denotes total emissions of x(i), Q is the total electricity generation (MWh), Fi is the fuel consumption of a unit i (unit of mass or volume), and NVCi is the net calorific value of fuel i (energy content, GJ/unit of mass or volume). In general, prior research has calculated the quantity of pollutants emitted using power plant and unit costs taken from descriptive statistics of the data set in [37,38,39]. The marginal costs of pollutants in Table 2 were maintained from prior literature. Although we used the existing data set, we focused on developing a methodology derived from economic theory showing mathematical expressions for estimating indirect costs.
In order to verify the proposed approach, Table 3 shows RE capacity and generation in each scenario. Scenario 1 was the base case so that the indirect costs of RE capacity could be determined using the base case as a reference. In scenario 1, RE capacity was assumed to increase to 20% of total consumption according to RE 3020 plan [40]. Scenario 2 was the low case including 24 GW of additional RE capacity until 2030, resulting in 13% RE share of total consumption. By comparing scenario 1 with scenario 2, the indirect cost of RE penetration at a low level in Korea could be computed. Finally, scenario 3 represented the high case of RE generation equal to 51% of total consumption. The comparison of this scenario with scenario 1 indicated the indirect costs of RE at this level of penetration.

5.2. Simulation Results

5.2.1. Impact of RE on the Grid

The Korean electricity market is operated as a cost-based pool. Since RE sources have very low marginal cost, which means low variable FC, it is dispatched first and thereby, reduces the demand for NRE sources. If power demand decreases, a power plant with a lower marginal cost can determine the market electricity price. Due to this principle, the larger the proportion of RE installed, the lower the electricity market price can be expected in day-ahead power market. Figure 5 illustrates the total power capacity and generation for the electricity demand with increasing shares of variable renewables in electricity generation. Since the total capacity of base load plants was defined, the utilization rate of NRE could be varied according to the reduction in power demand produced by RE. As shown in Figure 5a, the capacity of NRE was volatile in the cost-based pool, varying between 37%–51%. This can be explained by the relatively higher fuel price, which means NRE was not utilized, as well as the availability of sufficient flexibility due to existing NRE generation. In Figure 5c, especially, as the proportion of RE in total consumption rose to 51%, the dispatchable generations were curtailed significantly. As a result, the share of coal generation decreases from 67% (Scenario 1) to 26% (Scenario 3). The share of gas in total generation also decreased from 13% (Scenario 2) to 0% (Scenario 1–3). Although the total dispatchable capacity was decreased in the day-ahead market, the total reduction of demand could be regarded as low compared to the increase in RE capacity. This was because the low contribution of RE generation to accommodate peak load results in only a slight reduction in total capacity required for the NRE, whereas the capacity factors of generators decreased significantly as a utilization effect. Additional RE capacity in scenarios 1 to 3 increased the impact of demand curtailment when the RE utilization was stable as shown in Figure 5d. Consequently, the increase of RE capacity amplified the effect of decreasing electricity demand. The investments and total dispatchable capacity for the NRE on the day-ahead market could be decreased.
Figure 6 shows the simulation results of generation costs including the initial investment cost, variable O&M cost, and fixed O&M cost of total power source with increasing RE shares. The investment cost of RE was assumed to be $1400/kW, in line with currently realized costs [37]. In case of lower RE capacity, the total OC and FC were in the range of $19–24/MWh and $3–18/MWh for 21%–59% RE shares. The largest part of these costs comes from OC, which increased with increasing RE penetration. The FC decreased with increasing shares of RE. As shown in Figure 6b, an interesting finding was that the fuel cost of total generation decreased by 64% when a 59% increase in share of RE generation occurred. The additional RE capacity allowed peak demand to be reduced when NRE generation was low. Thereby, the total power capacity required a decline on the day-ahead market. This reduced the variable and indirect costs significantly by 50%–74%. However, the IC of the RE investments was higher than the total reduction of FC. Therefore, most of the net benefit of RE investments for reducing the total environmental and variable cost of RE was computed from the reduction of FC. It can be noted that the measure of the decrease in costs depends on the relative availability of RE generation capacity.

5.2.2. Market Value of RE

Another impact of variable RE was the increase in the market value, which was determined as the hourly weighted average price in the Korean power market. Since RE has very low marginal cost, RE reduces the market prices. As a result, their market value increases with RE penetration. Figure 7 shows the market value with increasing shares in total RE consumption. In scenarios 1 and 2, rLCOE decreased with lower RE penetration and it reached $28/MWh at 34% share and $26/MWh at 21% share, respectively. On the other hand, in scenarios 3, rLCOE of the power market was low and it was $27/MWh at 59% share because RE was utilized during peak hours and had a limited impact on the market value. An increase in RE penetration reduced the rLCOE via a decrease in average fuel costs. Thus, the effect of variable RE results in a difference between the average market price and the average fuel costs curtailed by RE during peak hours. The increase in the market value of RE affected the profitability of the power market in a positive way, which may imply a further reduction in the average market price for variable RE. That is, the market price decreased when the utilization of RE increased. Conversely, in scenarios 1 and 2, LCOE increased with higher RE penetration and reached $30/MWh at 34% share and $29/MWh at 21% share, respectively. In scenarios 3, LCOE was at its highest with $31/MWh at 59% share. The LCOE of scenario 1 was higher than that of scenario 2, the main reason being that the indirect effect was not considered in the LCOE approach. Scenario 3 indicated that despite a higher proportion of RE, the total cost increased. However, the rLCOE approach considered environmental and curtailment effects, and included other benefits when the NRE was not operating. The SW was increased from $1/MWh at scenario 2 to $4/MWh at scenario 1, and it was decreased to $3/MWh in scenario 3. According to these results, the market value of renewables increased in the Korean power market. Although the environmental costs had little impact on the electricity market, FC was the largest single component that mainly determines the magnitude of total indirect effects. Therefore, our work showed three main results for RE. First, the largest cost driver at moderate shares was the reduction of NRE, even though the residual capacity mix optimally adapted to RE deployment. Fortunately, these costs were saturated at higher market shares of RE. Second, with an increasing share of RE, overproduction costs occurred and grew rapidly. These costs drove the convex shape of indirect effects. Finally, SW began to fall for high RE shares. According to optimal shares, the RE showed positive indirect effects due to a high FC of NRE.

5.3. Sensitivity Analysis

In this research, the two inputs could be varied in mathematical sensitivity analysis: (1) The FC and (2) the electricity demand. The market price and RE capacity were varied according to the scenario assumption, thereby yielding one high-sensitivity and one low-sensitivity cost for each technology.
Figure 8 shows results of the sensitivity analysis with the fuel cost and electricity demand. It contained the indirect cost and the rLCOE values for the different combinations of costs for RE and NRE, respectively. It also corresponded to the range of indirect costs derived from the sensitivity analysis. For the rLCOE values, each cost combination was shown as a varying line, where the rLCOE varied with fuel price. According to Figure 8a, all the combinations of each scenarios followed the same linear shape, where the sharp increase in rLCOE came at a penetration level of scenario 1 with low RE share. When the portion of RE was low, the cost change was large because the effect of demand reduction was small. On the other hand, scenarios 1 and 3 show that the utilization rate of NRE, having a high variable cost, was kept low due to the high proportion of RE. Figure 8b shows the results for rLCOE from the sensitivity analysis of the electricity demand data input. These Figure 8a,b show that the high RE penetration represents the high curtailment of electricity demand, and low NRE generation could reduce the rLCOE.

6. Conclusions

Policy makers generally use LCOE to compare power sources for energy conversion and review economic feasibility. However, LCOE is not an ideal approach because it does not consider indirect costs. Comparing RE and NRE, LCOE tends to overestimate the economic viability of the power market whenever the share of RE increases. In order to overcome these limitations, this research proposed a new rLCOE approach, which was the sum of the LCOE and the marginal indirect costs per unit of electricity generation using the marginal cost of RE. Unlike the existing LCOE comparison, the rLCOE could determine the optimal power generation, which could facilitate a proper economic evaluation of RE. In order to standardize the rLCOE, it was necessary to define indirect costs mathematically based on economic theory. To validate the approach, a case study was performed on the existing electricity market in Korea. The following conclusions were drawn from this case study:
(1)
In the proposed approach, the indirect costs decreased with an increase in the market value of the power market as the proportion of RE increased. Using the rLCOE approach, the simulation results of scenarios 1, 2, indicate that the rLCOE decreased with lower RE penetration and increased in scenario 3 with a higher RE share, respectively. On the other hand, LCOE increased with higher RE penetration and scenarios 3 shows the highest LCOE. This indicates that an increase in RE penetration reduced the rLCOE via a decrease in the average fuel costs of curtailment effect.
(2)
The rLCOE and the total costs were significantly reduced by the RE supply, which could be an accelerator for RE capacity expansion. It means that RE capacity could be expanded until the SW of RE becomes stagnant. However, if the market value ceases to increase due to a high proportion of RE, no further installation will be necessary. Although the difference between rLCOE and LCOE was increased from scenario 2 to scenario 1, the value was decreased in scenario 3. Since indirect benefits decrease with a growing share of RE in the market, it could be an economic barrier to deploying RE with higher shares.
(3)
Our work indicates that the largest cost driver in the electricity market is the reduction of NRE, even though the residual capacity mix optimally adapts to RE deployment. With an increasing share of RE, indirect costs occurred and grew rapidly. According to optimal shares in scenario 2, RE shows positive indirect effects due to a high FC of NRE.
Therefore, the rLCOE effectively resolved the challenge of integrating RE and could guide policy makers in realizing a cost-efficient energy transformation with potentially high proportions of RE in the electricity market. In the future we plan to extend our research design to include additional considerations such as changes in market price in response to the interaction of additional indirect effects.

Author Contributions

S.-H.H. proposed the main idea of this paper and M.-K.K. coordinated the proposed approach and thoroughly reviewed in the manuscript. H.-S.R. provided essential information and supported in manuscript preparation. All authors read and approved the manuscript.

Acknowledgments

This research was supported by the Chung-Ang University Research Scholarship Grants in 2019. This research was also supported by Basic Science Research Program through the National Research Foundation of Koera (NRF) funded by the Ministry of Education (2017R1D1A1B03029308).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Home-Ortiz, J.M.; Melgar-Dominguez, O.D.; Pourakbari-Kasmaei, M.; Mantovani, J.R.S. A stochastic mixed-integer convex programming model for long-term distribution system expansion planning considering greenhouse gas emission mitigation. Int. J. Electr. Power Energy Syst. 2019, 108, 86–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Zeng, B.; Zhang, J.; Yang, X.; Wang, J.; Dong, J.; Zhang, Y. Integrated planning for transition to low-carbon distribution system with renewable energy generation and demand response. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 29, 1153–1165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Pourakbari-Kasmaei, M.; Mantovani, J.R.S.; Rashidinejad, M.; Habibi, M.R.; Contreras, J. Carbon footprint allocation among consumers and transmission losses. In Proceedings of the 2017 IEEE International Conference on Environment and Electrical Engineering and 2017 IEEE Industrial and Commercial Power Systems Europe (EEEIC/I&CPS Europe), Milan, Italy, 6–9 June 2017; pp. 1–6. [Google Scholar]
  4. Cheng, Y.; Zhang, N.; Wang, Y.; Yang, J.; Kang, C.; Xia, Q. Modeling carbon emission flow in multiple energy systems. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2019, 10, 3562–3574. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Cheng, Y.; Zhang, N.; Lu, Z.; Kang, C. Planning Multiple Energy Systems towards Low-Carbon Society: A Decentralized Approach. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Energy Information Administration (EIA). Levelized Cost Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy Outlook, 2019; EIA: Washington, DC, USA, 2019.
  7. Gough, M.; Lotfi, M.; Castro, R.; Madhlopa, A.; Khan, A.; Catalão, J.P. Urban Wind Resource Assessment: A Case Study on Cape Town. Energies 2019, 128, 1479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lucheroni, C.; Mari, C. Optimal integration of intermittent renewables: A system LCOE stochastic approach. Energies 2018, 113, 549. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Paul, D.; Ela, E.; Kirby, B.; Milligan, M. Role of Energy Storage with Renewable Electricity Generation; Technical report NREL/TP-6A2-47187; National Renewable Energy Laboratory: Golden, CO, USA, 2010.
  10. Kost, C.; Mayer, J.N.; Thomsen, J.; Hartmann, N.; Senkpiel, C.; Philipps, S.; Schlegl, T. Levelized cost of electricity renewable energy technologies. Fraunhofer Inst. Sol. Energy Syst. I.S.E. 2013, 144. [Google Scholar]
  11. Merrick, J.H. On representation of temporal variability in electricity capacity planning models. Energy Econ. 2016, 59, 261–274. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  12. Reichenberg, L.; Hedenus, F.; Odenberger, M.; Johnsson, F. The marginal system LCOE of variable renewables—Evaluating high penetration levels of wind and solar in Europe. Energy 2018, 152, 914–924. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Hirth, L.; Ueckerdt, F.; Edenhofer, O. Integration costs revisited–An economic framework for wind and solar variability. Renew. Energy 2015, 74, 925–939. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Brouwer, A.S.; van den Broek, M.; Zappa, W.; Turkenburg, W.C.; Faaij, A. Least-cost options for integrating intermittent renewables in low-carbon power systems. Appl. Energy 2016, 161, 48–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Frew, B.A.; Clark, K.; Bloom, A.P.; Milligan, M. Marginal Cost Pricing in a World Without Perfect Competition: Implications for Electricity Markets with High Shares of Low Marginal Cost Resources; National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL): Golden, CO, USA, 2017.
  16. Chinmoy, L.; Iniyan, S.; Goic, R. Modeling wind power investments, policies and social benefits for deregulated electricity market—A review. Appl. Energy 2019, 242, 364–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Rouwendal, J. Indirect effects in cost-benefit analysis. J. Benefit-Cost Anal. 2012, 3, 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Mills, A. Changes in the Economic Value of Variable Generation at High Penetration Levels: A Pilot Case Study of California; Ernest Orlando Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2012.
  19. Lamont, A.D. Assessing the long-term system value of intermittent electric generation technologies. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 1208–1231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Liljas, B. How to calculate indirect costs in economic evaluations. Pharmacoeconomics 1998, 13, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Obi, M.; Jensen, S.M.; Ferris, J.B.; Bass, R.B. Calculation of levelized costs of electricity for various electrical energy storage systems. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2017, 67, 908–920. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Ilas, A.; Ralon, P.; Rodriguez, A.; Taylor, M. Renewable Power Generation Costs in 2017; International Renewable Energy Agency (IRENA): Abu Dhabi, UAE, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  23. Benes, K.J.; Augustin, C. Beyond LCOE: A simplified framework for assessing the full cost of electricity. Electr. J. 2016, 29, 48–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Lew, D.; Brinkman, G.; Ibanez, E.; Hodge, B.M.; Hummon, M.; Florita, A.; Heaney, M. The Western Wind and Solar Integration Study Phase 2; National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL): Golden, CO, USA, 2013.
  25. Pacione, M. Urban environmental quality and human wellbeing-a social geographical perspective. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2003, 65, 19–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Conn, D. The evaluation of social costs and benefits. Ind. Mark. Manag. 1972, 2, 35–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  27. Fripp, M.; Wiser, R.H. Effects of temporal wind patterns on the value of wind-generated electricity in California and the northwest. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2008, 23, 477–485. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Song, Y.H.; Kim, H.J.; Kim, S.W.; Jin, Y.G.; Yoon, Y.T. How to find a reasonable energy transition strategy in Korea? Quantitative analysis based on power market simulation. Energy Policy 2018, 119, 396–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Christopher Frey, H.; Patil, S.R. Identification and review of sensitivity analysis methods. Risk Anal. 2002, 22, 553–578. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. The 8th Power Supply Plan in Korea. Available online: https://bit.ly/2VRvYU3 (accessed on 29 December 2017).
  31. RE 3020 Plan in Korea. Available online: https://bit.ly/2Lug8ec (accessed on 20 December 2017).
  32. Korea Power Exchange. Available online: https://www.kpx.or.kr (accessed on 12 December 2017).
  33. Min, C.G.; Kim, M.K. Impact of the Complementarity between Variable Generation Resources and Load on the Flexibility of the Korean Power System. Energies 2017, 10, 1719. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ason, A. Price Reviews and Arbitrations in Asian LNG Markets; Oxford Institute for Energy Studies: Oxford, UK, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  35. Energy Information Administration (EIA). World Energy Outlook. Available online: https://www.iea.org/weo/ (accessed on 1 January 2018).
  36. Vujić, J.; Antić, D.P.; Vukmirović, Z. Environmental impact and cost analysis of coal versus nuclear power: The US case. Energy 2012, 45, 31–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Galetovic, A.; Muñoz, C.M. Wind, coal, and the cost of environmental externalities. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 1385–1391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Pazheri, F.R.; Othman, M.F.; Malik, N.H.; Safoora, O.K. Reduction in cost with limited emission at hybrid power plant in presence of renewable power. In Proceedings of the 2014 IEEE Global Humanitarian Technology Conference—South Asia Satellite (GHTC-SAS), Trivandrum, India, 26–27 September 2014; pp. 20–24. [Google Scholar]
  39. Consonni, S.; Giugliano, M.; Grosso, M. Alternative strategies for energy recovery from municipal solid waste: Part B: Emission and cost estimates. Waste Manag. 2005, 25, 137–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  40. Park, J.; Bumsuk, K. An analysis of South Korea’s energy transition policy with regards to offshore wind power development. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 109, 71–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The principle of rLCOE with optimal RE deployment. (a) Relationship with rLCOE and RE deployment. (b) Correlation with rLCOE and market value.
Figure 1. The principle of rLCOE with optimal RE deployment. (a) Relationship with rLCOE and RE deployment. (b) Correlation with rLCOE and market value.
Energies 12 02459 g001
Figure 2. Proposed process of the rLCOE approach.
Figure 2. Proposed process of the rLCOE approach.
Energies 12 02459 g002
Figure 3. Electricity demand and growth rate for rLCOE in Korea.
Figure 3. Electricity demand and growth rate for rLCOE in Korea.
Energies 12 02459 g003
Figure 4. IEA market price projection. (a) Crude oil price; (b) Asian LNG price.
Figure 4. IEA market price projection. (a) Crude oil price; (b) Asian LNG price.
Energies 12 02459 g004
Figure 5. Electricity supply in the Korean power market. (a) Capacity volume; (b) Capacity mix. (c) Generation volume; (d) Capacity utilization.
Figure 5. Electricity supply in the Korean power market. (a) Capacity volume; (b) Capacity mix. (c) Generation volume; (d) Capacity utilization.
Energies 12 02459 g005
Figure 6. Costs in the Korean power market. (a) Generation cost; (b) Variable cost.
Figure 6. Costs in the Korean power market. (a) Generation cost; (b) Variable cost.
Energies 12 02459 g006
Figure 7. rLCOE and LCOE results in each scenario.
Figure 7. rLCOE and LCOE results in each scenario.
Energies 12 02459 g007
Figure 8. Sensitivity analysis. (a) Generation costs with variable fuel costs. (b) Generation costs with variable demand.
Figure 8. Sensitivity analysis. (a) Generation costs with variable fuel costs. (b) Generation costs with variable demand.
Energies 12 02459 g008
Table 1. Adapted cost parameters of the energy source for rLCOE from [36].
Table 1. Adapted cost parameters of the energy source for rLCOE from [36].
Energy SourceIC 1
($/kW)
VOC 2 ($/MWh)FOC 3 ($/kW/yr)FC 4
($/MWh)
Gas7600.85030
Coal14000.0808
Nuclear51000.01608
Wind14000.0440
Solar6000.0190
1 Initial investment costs, 2 variable O&M costs, 3 fixed O&M costs, and 4 fuel costs.
Table 2. Pollutant generation and cost from various generation plants for 1 GW/year [37].
Table 2. Pollutant generation and cost from various generation plants for 1 GW/year [37].
Energy SourceQuantity (Ton)Cost (USD)
Crude oilCO25,000,000
SO240,000
NOx25,000
Fine dust25,000
CoalCO26,000,000
SO2120,000
NOx25,000
Fine dust300,000
GasCO23,000,000
SO220
NOx13,000
Table 3. RE capacity and generation in each scenario.
Table 3. RE capacity and generation in each scenario.
Year20182022202620302031
Electricity generation (TWh)34.4116.6179.0251.6252.0
RE Capacity (GW)11.323.338.858.558.6
Electricity generation (TWh)34.486.6115.6150.1150.3
RE Capacity (GW)11.317.325.134.935.0
Electricity generation (TWh)34.4176.7305.9454.6455.4
RE Capacity (GW)11.335.366.3105.7105.9

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Hwang, S.-H.; Kim, M.-K.; Ryu, H.-S. Real Levelized Cost of Energy with Indirect Costs and Market Value of Variable Renewables: A Study of the Korean Power Market. Energies 2019, 12, 2459. https://doi.org/10.3390/en12132459

AMA Style

Hwang S-H, Kim M-K, Ryu H-S. Real Levelized Cost of Energy with Indirect Costs and Market Value of Variable Renewables: A Study of the Korean Power Market. Energies. 2019; 12(13):2459. https://doi.org/10.3390/en12132459

Chicago/Turabian Style

Hwang, Sung-Hyun, Mun-Kyeom Kim, and Ho-Sung Ryu. 2019. "Real Levelized Cost of Energy with Indirect Costs and Market Value of Variable Renewables: A Study of the Korean Power Market" Energies 12, no. 13: 2459. https://doi.org/10.3390/en12132459

APA Style

Hwang, S. -H., Kim, M. -K., & Ryu, H. -S. (2019). Real Levelized Cost of Energy with Indirect Costs and Market Value of Variable Renewables: A Study of the Korean Power Market. Energies, 12(13), 2459. https://doi.org/10.3390/en12132459

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop