1. Introduction
With the economic development entering the new normal, the current extent of resource consumption and environmental damage is approaching the ecological environment’s upper limit. Under the increasingly severe constraints of resources and environment, the extensive development mode of rapid economic growth relying on an overdraft of resources, environment, and ecological dividends can no longer survive. It is urgent to seek a new avenue of green transformation, break and solve the deadlock between environmental protection and economic growth, and expedite the sustainable development of the economy and society [
1]. The Fifth Plenary Session of the 18th Communist Party of China Central Committee put forward the five development concepts of innovation-driven development, balanced development, green development, open development, and development for all, highlighting the importance of green and innovation. The report of the 19th Session of the National Congress of the Communist Party of China proposed to “speed up the reform of the ecological civilization system and build a beautiful China”. Once again, the need to build a market-oriented green technology innovation system was emphasized. Taking green innovation as the critical strategy to drive green transformation, preventing and treating environmental pollution, and achieving a “win-win” between economic efficiency and environmental protection are eventful directions for China to practice green development in the long term. As microcarriers of social and economic wealth creation, enterprises are also the initiators of resource consumption and pollutant emission. Determining how to drive enterprises to carry out green innovation activities vigorously, improve the production process and technology, reduce the cost of environmental governance, and precipitate the transformation of green development concept to policy dividend is of great significance for the country to realize the socialist economy with Chinese characteristics and the construction of ecological civilization.
The existing literature generally elaborates the driving factors of green transformation from green innovation, focusing on the microenterprise level, mainly revolving around the external institutional environment and internal corporate governance. In terms of the institutional environment, based on institutional theory and stakeholder theory, we explore the influence of environmental regulation [
2,
3], government supervision [
4], upstream and downstream relationship [
5,
6], government subsidies [
7], and other factors. For corporate governance, based on resource dependence theory and information asymmetry theory, the effects of organizational capabilities [
8], political connections [
9], redundant resources [
10], board governance [
11], knowledge coupling [
12], and comparability of accounting information [
13] on green innovation have been probed. Wang and Wang [
14] found that government subsidies positively affect green innovation, and appropriate executive incentive strategies can compensate for innovation to achieve the optimal drive of fiscal and tax subsidies for green innovation activities. Extant studies have contributed to clarifying the interfering factors and mechanisms of green innovation but have neglected the market forces’ function in green transformation.
With the advent of the critical year for pollution prevention and control, SOEs began to gather strength to accelerate the transformation path and made certain achievements in improving the quality of the ecological environment through green innovation. Nevertheless, due to the lower level of marketization of SOE management [
15], the phenomenon of environmental inefficiency caused by excessive reliance on government support often occurs in large-scale SOEs. The process of pushing the green transformation requires not only relying on government forces but also using market forces to effectively give play to the internal incentive mechanism of the market [
16] to stimulate the enthusiasm for green innovation activities. Since the “Decision of the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China on Some Major Issues Concerning Comprehensively Deepening the Reform” adopted at the Third Plenary Session of the 18th Central Committee in 2013 clearly stated that China should actively develop the mixed-ownership economy, the mixed-ownership reform has become a major direction for the development of SOEs. The state expects to fulfill the effective integration of heterogeneous capital, establish a market-oriented governance system and operation mechanism, give full play to the role of the market in resource allocation, and release the reform dividend. Therefore, mixed-ownership reform is a major driving force for the SOEs’ green transformation.
At present, some SOEs have matters of environmental protection funds controlled by the government and weak awareness of environmental protection. The impact of mixed-ownership reform on green innovation may be implemented through the following two channels: From the environmental protection subsidies, the widespread existence of problems such as the “lack of actual controllers” and the “executive compensation control” in SOEs lead to the mismatch of environmental subsidies. The entry of non-state-owned capital reduces government intervention [
17] and has a certain voice in the arrangement of environmental protection subsidy funds. Establishing effective supervision and restriction mechanisms can alleviate the two types of agency conflicts, prevent the controlling shareholders and managers from encroaching on environmental protection subsidies, achieve the reasonable allocation of environmental protection subsidies, and provide a resource basis for green innovation. From the environmental responsibility, enterprises are required to participate in more green innovation activities [
18]. As policy burdens should be undertaken by SOEs [
19], managers who are subject to government intervention only regard environmental responsibility as a task that SOEs must fulfill and fail to pay attention to it. However, environmental information disclosure is a major channel for stakeholders to obtain environmental rights [
20]. Non-state shareholders who take the marketization as the guidance have a strong motivation to establish good relationships with stakeholders via actively performing environmental responsibilities for their interests, attract external investors’ support, and improve SOEs’ willingness and ability to launch green innovation. Then, whether and how the mixed-ownership reform impacts green innovation will be the main emphasis of the research.
Based on this, we take panel data of state-owned listed enterprises from 2008 to 2019 to explore the influence of mixed-ownership reform on the green transformation of SOEs and its specific mechanisms. The main results are as follows: (1) The diversity of mixed shareholders, the depth of mixed equity, and the restriction of mixed equity are significantly positively correlated with the number of green patent applications, and the mixed-ownership reform contributes to promoting the SOEs’ green transformation. (2) The shareholding ratios of heterogeneous equity have different effects on green innovation. Only the increase in the shareholding ratio of foreign shareholders has facilitated green innovation. (3) This paper proposes and confirms the two possible mechanisms of “environmental protection subsidies” and “environmental responsibility”. (4) Additional analysis indicates that mixed-ownership reform has a positive impact on green innovation only when SOEs are in heavily polluting industries or regions with a high degree of marketization. (5) We also detect that the mixed-ownership reform stimulates the development of green innovation activities of SOEs and then enhances the enterprise’s sustainable development ability.
This paper’s contributions are reflected in the following four aspects: Firstly, it expands the domain of the impact of mixed-ownership reform on SOEs’ investment decisions. Previous studies have found that the reform has optimized the investment decisions in terms of merger efficiency [
21], investment efficiency [
22], diversification [
23], and technological innovation [
24]. However, they all neglect the effect on environmental governance. This paper discusses how to allocate the government environmental subsidies to promote the green development of SOEs from the green innovation for the first time. Secondly, it enriches the research on the interfering factors of green innovation. Existing literature studies the driving factors from external institutional environment and internal corporate governance. Still, there is little attention paid to the driving role of dynamic adjustment of the ownership structure. Based on the practice of heterogeneous capital cross-shareholding and mutual restriction to optimize SOEs’ governance mechanism, we explore whether the mixed-ownership reform can propel enterprise green innovation. Thirdly, it reveals the internal logic of the mixed-ownership reform driving the green transformation of SOEs. Under the concern of stakeholders, the fulfillment of environmental responsibility helps to transform scientific practice to the green innovation that protects public health and ecological environment [
20]. Therefore, we analyze and verify the mechanisms from environmental protection subsidy and environmental responsibility. It provides a useful supplement to the related research on the governance path of SOE mixed-ownership reform. Finally, it provides empirical evidence to clarify the dispute on the effectiveness of SOE reform. On one side, SOE reform improves corporate efficiency by strengthening internal and external supervision mechanisms, such as by reducing financing costs [
25] and increasing risk-taking levels [
26,
27] and corporate value [
28,
29]. On the other side, Reinsberg et al. [
30] found that the privatization of SOEs in developing countries created opportunities for rent-seeking and had an adverse effect on the implementation of anticorruption policies. The results of this paper show that mixed-ownership reform has actively promoted the SOEs’ green transformation, which means that reform has improved the governance mechanisms and operation decisions of companies and resolved the controversy over the effectiveness of SOE reform in China.
2. Theoretical Analysis and Research Hypothesis
Green innovation is the essential method to drive green transformation. This paper uses it to represent the process of green transformation of enterprises. Green innovation mainly refers to improving products or processes related to energy conservation and emission reduction, pollution prevention, waste recycling, green product design, and environmental management by enterprises [
31]. Through green innovation, enterprises can offset the cost of environmental investment, improve resource utilization, increase the added value of enterprise products, meet market participants’ expectations, and effectively achieve the dual objectives of environmental protection and green competitiveness. Green innovation has evolved into an important strategic tool for enterprises to achieve sustainable development [
32]. It is crucial for the SOEs that are widely intervened in by the government to search for market forces to promote the enterprises’ green transformation.
Hao and Gong [
15] found that the mixed-ownership structure helps to make up for SOEs’ lack of marketization. The shift from public to private ownership stimulates more efficient management of available resources [
33]. With the mixed-ownership reform, the entry of external strategic investors can improve the operating efficiency and marketization level and release the motion of SOEs’ green transformation. The amount of resource input directly determines the intensity of enterprise innovation activities [
34]. The government’s environmental protection subsidies provide a source of funding for green innovation; thus, non-state capital has the motivation to promote the rational allocation of environmental protection subsidies to achieve sustainable development of enterprises. In addition, green innovation is an important form for enterprises to actively undertake their environmental responsibilities. The emergence of market forces possessed by non-state-owned shareholders will inevitably impact the performance of SOEs’ environmental responsibilities and prompt the environmental strategy from passive governance to active prevention and control. On this basis, from the dual path of capital allocation and responsibility fulfillment, this paper explores how the mixed-ownership reform drives the green transformation of SOEs, which has certain theoretical and practical value.
2.1. Mixed-Ownership Reform and Green Transformation of SOEs
The dedication of green innovation to environmental externalities is difficult to be converted into economic benefits in a short time [
35], and the long-term competitive advantage brought by green innovation cannot meet the urgent needs of the political promotion of SOEs’ executives. Therefore, catering to the superior government’s target and completing the political performance in a brief period are the mainstay for executives to make strategic decisions. The obtained environmental protection funds are more likely to expand SOEs’ scale and produce a “crowding effect” on the resources of green innovation activities. This is similar to the case in which local communities of Roşia Montană carefully weigh the costs and benefits of gold-mining projects to make decisions for avoiding village decline [
36]. Existing research manifests that environmental regulations have a positive impact on green innovation, but the high political connection of state-owned controlling shareholders provides the possibility for SOEs to circumvent environmental regulatory constraints, which will reduce the incentive function of environmental regulations. As the controlling shareholder, the government does not understand the specific situation of green innovation, and its excessive intervention in decision-making is likely to cause deviations from the original technological track and managers’ aversion and resistance, which inhibits the expansion of green innovation activities.
According to the resource-based theory, the formation of corporate competitive advantage begins with heterogeneous resources. There are huge distinctions in the resource endowments owned by different property rights enterprises. Non-state-owned shareholders can bring capital, technology, and advanced management concepts to SOEs. With the improvement of heterogeneous shareholders’ diversity, they use their social resources to satisfy the knowledge and technology requirements of green innovation and reduce the non-professional intervention of state-owned controlling shareholders. It ultimately ensures the rationality and scientificity of green innovation decision-making of SOEs. The shareholding ratio of non-state-owned shareholders represents the capital provided for SOEs and the autonomy in operating decisions; non-state-owned capital offers equity financing to ease the financing constraints and strictly supervises managers [
37]. When the equity restriction of non-state-owned capital reaches a certain degree, the bargaining power of non-state-owned shareholders increases in competing for control with the controlling shareholders, which restrains the opportunistic behavior of controlling shareholders and modifies their decision-making tendency. Although a certain cost is required for green transformation, in the long run, the benefits of green transformation are much higher than the cost [
38]. This effectively drives SOEs’ long-term economic performance and environmental performance. Under the condition that the non-state-owned shareholders play the role of restriction, the strategic resources occupied by the controlling shareholders are released, which promotes the occurrence of green innovation activities with large capital demand.
Regarding the considerations mentioned above, this paper presents the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis (H1). Mixed-ownership reform can drive the green transformation of SOEs.
2.2. The Mechanism of Environmental Protection Subsidies
Green innovation can reduce economic cost and environmental externality by improving the green process and producing a double value effect on the economy and environment [
39]. However, green innovation often involves the amelioration of production technology and process, which requires a large amount of resource input. Resource constraints and insufficient incentives are the main factors restricting enterprises from green innovation [
40]. The support of government environmental protection subsidies ameliorates the dilemma of green innovation funds shortage in enterprises [
41]. The 2019 “State of the ecological environment in China’s bulletin” disclosed that the central government had arranged RMB 53.2 billion of special funds for environmental protection. The wide existence of government intervention and agency problems in SOEs makes government environmental protection subsidies invalid. Green innovation has the characteristics of a long investment cycle, high uncertainty, and superior discretionary power. The “absence of actual controller” of SOEs and the “inherent compensation” of executives highlight the opportunistic motivation of management, which easily leads to the inflow of resources into the fields that bring private benefits to management, rather than into the fields that create enterprise value and social benefits [
42]. Wang and Zhang [
43] pointed out that compared with NSOEs, SOEs are less likely to lose government support and make few efforts to solve the corporate pollution problem. The lack of information of state-owned controlling shareholders leads to the misuse of environmental protection subsidy domination and inability to exert the function of environmental protection funds in SOEs’ green technology breakthroughs.
The introduction of non-state-owned strategic investors adds the proper channels for SOEs to obtain information, boosts the service efficiency of environmental protection subsidies, and brings down government intervention. SOEs no longer only cater to the government’s willingness to invest. Instead, they apply environmental subsidies for green innovation activities, reduce enterprises’ environmental pollution, and accelerate the exploitation of green products. Choi et al. [
44] indicate that non-state-owned shareholders are more concerned about how enterprises gain long-term competitive advantages than state-owned shareholders. Green innovation brings reputation advantages, competitive advantages, and competitiveness to enterprises [
45]. Therefore, non-state shareholders begin with the construction of sound environmental culture, improve the environmental awareness of management, complete the environmental management system, and allocate environmental protection subsidies in green innovation projects rationally. Yang, Ren, and Yang [
23] detect that the profit-seeking nature of non-state-owned shareholders gives them a strong motivation to supervise the controlling shareholders and management, which is conducive to building a governance mechanism with restriction and incentive compatibility, relieves the problems of “insider control” and “lack of supervision”, and cuts down the occupation of environmental protection subsidies. Furthermore, the professional management system implemented by the mixed-ownership reform employs managers through market-oriented mode and establishes the mechanism of manager compensation incentive [
15]. It alters managers’ attitude towards risk-taking, prompts the implementation of environmental protection subsidies, and pushes the smooth progress of green innovation.
In reliance on the above analysis, this paper suggests the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis (H2). Mixed-ownership reform can drive the green transformation of SOEs by promoting the rational allocation of environmental protection subsidies.
2.3. The Mechanism of Environmental Responsibility
As a part of corporate social responsibility, environmental responsibility requires enterprises to participate in more green innovation activities [
18]. Now the development of information technology and the improvement of user requirement complexity put forward new demands for the quality of enterprise products and services [
46]. Corporate environmental responsibility demands enterprises to produce more environmental protection products through green innovation to establish win–win cooperation with suppliers and customers. It can be seen that the fulfillment of environmental responsibilities is extremely important to drive the occurrence of green innovation behaviors. In 2019, the Party Central Committee approved the central leading group for ecological and environmental protection supervision, which inspected two central enterprises, China Minmetals Corporation Ltd. and China National Chemical Corporation Ltd. They found that some of its subsidiaries had weak awareness of environmental law and fraud in environmental protection issues (
http://www.xinhuanet.com/energy/2020-05/14/c_1125982597.htm, accessed on 5 April 2021). The gold-mining project implemented by the state-owned joint venture RMGC of Romania also has major health hazards and environmental degradation risks. Some SOEs still lack environmental awareness and neglect the fulfillment of environmental responsibility. SOEs have long been responsible for various policy goals [
47]. Therefore, external investors regard environmental responsibilities as SOEs’ obligations, which cannot be a means to enhance the corporate image and obtain investors’ funds, resulting in a shortage of managers’ willingness to fulfill. On account of the government and banks’ financial support, SOEs have no difficulties in resources and manpower and do not incorporate environmental compliance into their strategic planning.
With the decrease in state-owned equity, the policy tasks that SOEs need to undertake are reduced. At the same time, they also face the decline in implicit contract guarantee of state-owned property rights, which leads to the rise of bankruptcy risk and default risk [
23]. The absence of unconditional support from the government compels SOEs to attach importance to environmental compliance, actively assume environmental responsibilities, reduce the occurrence of corporate environmental violations, and increase the possibility of obtaining external financing. The enhancement of the discourse power and the strengthening of the restriction effect of non-state-owned shareholders can supervise the behavior of managers, improve their awareness of environmental protection, and urge them to actively fulfill environmental responsibilities, as well as drawing investors to provide capital support related to environment-friendly and mutually beneficial coexistence with enterprises. The continuous adjustment of the internal ownership structure of SOEs will appeal to the concern of all stakeholders. When social attention is high, enterprises need to consider how to satisfy market participants’ expectations, lessen waste, and protect the environment [
18]. Environmental information disclosure is the key for stakeholders to understand the environmental consequences of enterprises’ business activities [
20]. At this time, non-state shareholders are committed to assuming the responsibility of environmental information disclosure, gaining the recognition of stakeholders, establishing a good social image and reputation for the company, retaining employees with R&D capabilities, and increasing the SOEs’ green innovation output. Eventually, the scientific practice of society will gradually move towards the direction of green innovation to promote the emergence and consolidation of a “green country”.
In reliance on the above analysis, this paper proposes the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis (H3). Mixed-ownership reform can drive the green transformation of SOEs by promoting the active fulfillment of environmental responsibilities.
6. Conclusions
This paper emphasizes two perspectives of “environmental protection subsidy” and “environmental responsibility” to examine the impact of mixed-ownership reform on the green transformation of SOEs and its specific mechanisms. The main research conclusions are as follows: (1) After the non-state-owned capital shares in SOEs, the diversity of mixed shareholders, the depth of mixed equity, and the restriction of mixed equity enhance the green innovation output and consummate the environmental management mechanism of SOEs. (2) There are disparities in the impact of the shareholding ratio of heterogeneous equity on green innovation. Merely the increase in the proportion of foreign shareholders promotes green innovation. Private shareholders who fail to achieve the expected shareholding level and institutional investors who aim to earn the price difference have no effect. The self-protection psychology of natural person shareholders inhibits the occurrence of green innovation activities. (3) The positive impact of the mixed-ownership reform on the green transformation of SOEs is implemented through the dual path. On one side, by bringing down government intervention and agency conflicts, the mixed-ownership reform expedites the rational allocation and efficient use of government environmental protection subsidies and provides a resource base for green innovation activities. On the other side, the mixed-ownership reform enhances the environmental awareness to induce the independent performance of environmental responsibilities and releases the motivation and ability of SOEs’ green transformation after acquiring the support of the government and external investors. (4) If the SOEs belong to heavily polluting industries or regions with a high degree of marketization, the mixed-ownership reform has a significant role in promoting green transformation. In the case of different external environmental characteristics of SOEs, distinctions also exist in the impact of the adjustment of internal ownership structure on green innovation decisions. (5) The mixed-ownership reform has improved the enterprise environmental manifestation and realized the sustainable development of SOEs based on inducing green innovation.
On account of the above study findings, we suggest the following policy recommendations for accelerating the green transformation of SOEs and promoting sustainable development of the economy and society: (1) The governance mechanism of non-state-owned capital needs to be constantly consummated to give full play to its function of supervision and restriction of the green innovation decision-making of SOEs. The intensity of mixed-ownership reform should be gradually intensified to attract more heterogeneous non-state-owned shareholders, enhance their voice in operating activities, and improve the scientificity and correctness of SOEs’ green innovation decisions. (2) A priority selection scheme for heterogeneous non-state-owned shareholders should be formulated to achieve the optimal level of governance effects of the SOE reform. The above research results show that except for foreign shareholders, other non-state-owned shareholders cannot reach a consensus on innovation decisions due to their different interest demands, self-expectations, and risk preferences. At present, SOEs should give priority to the introduction of foreign shareholders, simultaneously consider a reasonable arrangement of the equity composition, establish a protection mechanism for the rights and interests of different non-state shareholders, give full play to the advantages of various forms of social capital, and heighten the green innovation capabilities of SOEs. (3) The process of mixed-ownership reform of SOEs in low marketization areas should be accelerated, and stratification and classification reform should be facilitated. The action of mixed-ownership reform on green innovation activities of SOEs is more prominent in low marketization areas, which indicates that the reform makes up for the deficiency of the institutional environment to a certain extent. Government departments should mobilize SOEs’ enthusiasm in low marketization regions to participate in mixed-ownership reform, establish a complete institutional system, better protect green innovation achievements, and stimulate enterprise innovative vitality. (4) There is a need to standardize the examination and approval mechanism of environmental protection subsidies, perfect the supervision mechanism, and ensure the rational distribution and use of SOEs’ environmental protection subsidies. Through the implementation of more stringent approval procedures for SOEs, such as clarifying the use and service life of environmental protection subsidies and specifying the detailed range of application, the service efficiency and the social benefits of environmental protection funds can be improved and the sustainable development of SOEs can be realized.
This paper preliminarily examines the economic consequences of mixed-ownership reform. Due to the availability of data, there are still some limitations and areas to be further expanded. In the sample selection, we only included the state-owned listed companies that disclose data publicly for research. However, among the large number of state-owned non-listed enterprises in China, non-state-owned shareholders may also hold certain shares to exert a positive effect on green innovation, which requires long-term manual data collection for follow-up verification. Moreover, mixed-ownership reform is in the process of continuous advancement and expansion. With the disclosure of more detailed data, we can track and analyze the policy and conduct more dimensional studies in the future, such as on how mixed-ownership reform affects corporate financial behaviors, and provide abundant evidence to support the optimization of the governance practices of SOEs.