Next Article in Journal
Microwave-Assisted Transesterification of Macroalgae
Previous Article in Journal
Calculation of the Arc Velocity Along the Polluted Surface of Short Glass Plates Considering the Air Effect
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Energy, Pollutant Emissions and Other Negative Externality Savings from Curbing Individual Motorized Transportation (IMT): A Low Cost, Low Technology Scenario Analysis in Brazilian Urban Areas

1
(CEFET–RJ) Federal Center of Technological Education, Av. Maracana 229, Rio de Janeiro, RJ 20271-110, Brazil
2
Federal Center Energy Planning Program, Graduate School of Engineering, Federal University of Rio de Janeiro, Centro de Tecnologia, Bloco C, Sala 211 Cidade Universitária, Ilha do Fundão, Rio de Janeiro, RJ 21941-972, Brazil
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2012, 5(3), 835-861; https://doi.org/10.3390/en5030835
Submission received: 13 January 2012 / Revised: 16 March 2012 / Accepted: 19 March 2012 / Published: 22 March 2012

Abstract

:
This article examines the inefficient use of resources in the Brazilian transportation system. The energy use growth and external cost generation in this essential economic sector are considerable, and the trend is towards an increasing problem in the coming years. The continued expansion of Brazilian cities and the increase in demand for mobility is a result of a substantial growth in the number of road transport users, as increased earnings enable lower income groups to acquire and use individual motorized means of transport. The aim of this paper is to estimate the potential gains from reducing individual motorized transport by the year 2020. This investigation concludes that in a conservationist scenario, by prioritizing low cost, low technology public policies—which include operation of Bus Rapid Transit systems, walking and cycling facilities and congestion charges, among others—it should be possible to save over USD 30 billion and USD 26 billion in external transportation and infrastructure costs, respectively, up to 2020. In addition, these public policies can save more than 35 million Tons of Oil Equivalents in energy consumption and avoid almost 4,000 thousand tons of local pollution emissions and 37,500 thousand tons of GHG emissions in the same period.

1. Introduction

Worldwide, transportation generates over 23% of the total of greenhouse gas emissions arising from the use of energy and accounts for at least 26% of the planet’s energy consumption [1,2,3,4,5,6]. The transportation sector occupies between 15% and 25% of the land mass in major cities throughout the World [7,8,9,10,11], and the time lost in traffic congestion in several countries leads to an economic loss of approximately 1 to 3% of GDP [12].
Furthermore, over a million people die and three million are injured every year in road traffic accidents worldwide [13,14,15]. These accidents result in economic costs of approximately 5% of GDP in some countries [16]. Several countries considered to be ‘emerging’ economically, such as Brazil, have adopted transportation systems that repeat the errors committed by more developed countries, including the encouragement of individual motorized transportation as the standard model. This has not proved to be the optimal solution [17].
Additionally, studies on the causes of persistent poverty in the peripheral areas of large cities, both in developed and emerging countries, point to a lack of transportation as one of the principal causes of social ills [18]. It is clear that an economy suffers significant losses in the absence of adequate transportation support. A sustainable transportation strategy has the potential to make a significant contribution to the environmental, economic and social development of cities and surrounding areas [19].
In Brazil, where the government regularly proclaims its overriding commitment to both the efficient use of public resources and the improvement of living standards for the population, there is an urgent and evident need for a drastic overhaul of the currently unsustainable transportation system. An accurate and reliable projection of the consumption of resources and the level of emissions produced by our transportation system in the coming decades is a key factor in ensuring the adequate redirection of public policies and the consequent benefits to the population.
On that basis, this study presents data on the identified energy waste, pollution emissions and external costs of motorized passenger transportation (both collective and individual) in urban areas of Brazil. Based on this data, we then use multiple regression to project the extent to which the current system is unsustainable in the year 2020. The date is relevant because it is the IPCC benchmark for greenhouse gas emission targets and it is also the date chosen by the Brazilian government in its planning for greenhouse gas emission reductions.
In the first section of the paper, we present and examine the concept of sustainable transportation. The second section sets out data for passenger transportation in urban areas in Brazil, particularly regarding the costs of energy emissions, infrastructure and social costs. We then make projections for the same cost categories for the year 2020, comparing these results with a hypothetical substantial reduction in individual motorizing transportation. In conclusion, we recommend a governmental policy curbing car and motorcycle use in order to save natural, financial and energy resources in Brazil.
In order to organize this paper, we aim to respond to three questions. The first one is: what does the concept of sustainable transportation mean? The second one is: what are the external costs and wasted natural resources of the unsustainable transportation system in Brazilian cities nowadays and in 2020? The last one is: what would be the economic and social benefits (in terms of financial resources, energy and environmental issues) if the Brazilian Government decided to curb individual motorized transportation with low cost, low technology public policies?

2. Sustainable Transportation

According to the concept of sustainable development, human beings should use available resources to meet our present requirements only to the extent that such use does not prejudice the capacity to satisfy the needs of future generations [20]. In other words, according to the European Foundation for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions, sustainable development is a continuous economic development that does not threaten the environment or natural resources [9].
In general terms, sustainability may be defined as the capacity to impart long-term continuity to our present actions. Everything that can be continued indefinitely is sustainable; everything to the contrary is unsustainable.
Litman and Burwell [9] note that sustainability reflects an ethic of conservation, where standards of production and consumption are structured to minimize the use of resources and the waste of materials. Putting this concept into practice requires significant structural changes in the economy and the public policies of countries that have historically rewarded inefficiency in production and consumption.
How does this view of sustainability apply to a transportation system? For Litman and Burwell [9] the principal tenet of sustainable transportation is that governments must address environmental, economic and social factors in their transportation decisions. This view is firmly endorsed by Feitelson [21].
Other authors [22] maintain that there are four key elements to the concept of sustainable development for transportation: the protection of natural resources, the maintenance of intergenerational productive capital, the drive for improvement in individual quality of life and the fair distribution of that quality of life.
In another approach to the concept, Black [23] maintains that a sustainable transportation system is one that provides transportation and mobility from renewable energy sources, thereby minimizing local and global emissions, preventing avoidable deaths and injuries from road traffic accidents and minimizing the loss of economic productivity due to traffic congestion.
The reality of transportation systems remains far removed from the ideals visualized in academic circles and the offices of urban planners. Light-duty vehicles account for more than 44% of the energy use in transportation system all over the World (Table 1). With the expansion in the use of individual motorized transportation, particularly the use of motor cars, transportation systems throughout the world are deteriorating drastically [24].
Table 1. World transport energy use in 2000, by mode.
Table 1. World transport energy use in 2000, by mode.
Mode Energy useEnergy use (EJ)Share %
Light-duty Vehicles (LDV)34.244.5
2-wheelers1.21.6
Heavy Freight Trucks12.4816.2
Medium Freight trucks6.778.8
Buses4.766.2
Rail1.191.5
Air8.9511.6
Shipping7.329.5
Total76.87100
Source: WBCSD [25].
This system deterioration can be seen by the worldwide decreasing public transportation usage in some cities, as shown in Table 2.
Table 2. Trends in mode share of public transport in selected cities.
Table 2. Trends in mode share of public transport in selected cities.
CityEarlier yearPublic transport as a percentage of motorized tripsLater yearPublic transport as a percentage of motorized trips
Bangkok197053199039
Buenos Aires199349199933
Kuala Lumpur198534199719
Mexico City198480199472
Moscow199087199783
Sao Paulo197746199733
Seoul197067199261
Tokyo197065199048
Shanghai *198624199515
Warsaw198780199853
Source: Wright and Fulton [26]. * Another study discussing modes of transportation in China (Jihan) can be found in He et al. [27].
The large-scale use of cars for urban journeys adds to the inherent inefficiency and unsustainability of transportation systems in terms of the relevant energy and environmental and social dimensions and generates considerable waste of financial and natural resources [28].
Parry, Walls, and Harrington [29] and Schipper and Eriksson [30] illustrate the negative impacts of the use of the motor cars for city transportation systems and list the eight “cardinal sins” of such use: accidents, atmospheric pollution, the inefficient use of urban space, congestion, noise pollution, energy waste, the emission of greenhouse gases and the inefficient distribution of cargo.
The more a transportation system relies on individual motorized vehicles, the more unsustainable the system becomes. Table 3 depicts the principal impacts of individual motorized transportation on sustainability.
Table 3. Impacts of individual motorized transportation on society.
Table 3. Impacts of individual motorized transportation on society.
EconomicSocialEnvironmental
CongestionUnequal distribution of impactsWater and air pollution
Barriers to mobilityInequality in terms of mobilityLoss of habitats
AccidentsImpact on human healthHydrological impact
Infrastructure costsCommunity interactionDNRR
OthersHability
DNRRAesthetics
Source: Prepared by the authors based on Litman and Burwell [9]; DNRR: Depletion of non-renewable resources.
The current trend in transportation in the modern world is one of increasing unsustainability [31]. The number of cars produced and used in contemporary cities is growing at an increasing rate. The problem worsens with the increase in productivity of manufacturers (and the related fall in production costs) and the greater access to financial resources by the world’s population, in that the end result of these factors is that more people buy more cars. According to Sperling and Gordon [32] the use of individual motorized transportation (IMT) will become an even more serious problem in the next decade, as shown in Figure 1.
Figure 1. Estimated expansion of world vehicles. Source: Sperling and Gordon [32]. Note: The term cycles refers to motorcycles.
Figure 1. Estimated expansion of world vehicles. Source: Sperling and Gordon [32]. Note: The term cycles refers to motorcycles.
Energies 05 00835 g001
Sperling and Gordon argue that even if the number of individual motorized vehicles were to increase very little in developed countries, the number of vehicles in developing countries, such as China and India, are increasing at rates of 8% a year, which overwhelms the lower rate of increase in developed countries, as depicted in Figure 1.
Moreover, as Wright and Fulton [26] pointed (Figure 2), “if such nations follow the same path of automobile dependence as developed nations, there is little that technological advances can offer to offset such a monumental increase in motorization and its subsequent emissions”.
Figure 2. Vehicle ownership by region. Source: Wright and Fulton [26].
Figure 2. Vehicle ownership by region. Source: Wright and Fulton [26].
Energies 05 00835 g002
In Brazil, the number of motor cars is growing at a rate of 8% per year and for motorcycles the rate is 14% per year [33]. These rates may increase even further due to the increase of per capita income in Brazil. Between 2003 and 2009, per capita income increased from R$ 9,511 (approximately USD 5,705) to approximately R$ 17,467 (approximately USD 10,481) per annum in real values [34]. In addition, current owners of vehicles use their cars more and are travelling longer distances within cities so that the use of cars is becoming increasingly inefficient due to greater traffic congestion [35].
The good news is that developing cities have an advantage in terms of achieving a more sustainable transportation system. As noted by Wright [36] “most developing cities have a high mode share for public transit and non-motorized modes as well as a fairly high-density, mixed use design pattern. The challenge for these cities is to improve and modernize their transport systems in order to preserve their inherent advantages”. Table 4 presents this modal arrangement from different developing cities sampling.
Table 4. Mode share of urban transport in selected developing cities.
Table 4. Mode share of urban transport in selected developing cities.
CityNon-motorised transportPublic transportPrivate motorised vehiclesOther
Bamako, Mali (1984)6312260
Havana, Cuba (1998)5727611
Hanoi, Vietnam (1995)544420
Ouagadougou, Burkina Faso (1994)523450
Cairo, Egypt (1998)3647170
Sao Paulo, Brazil (1997)3533311
Santiago, Chile (1991)2056169
Bogotá, Colombia (2000)1571122
Source: Wright [37].
In summary, as stated by GTZ [38], “the only sustainable solution is to have people move by public transport rather than by individual automobile”. Thus, GTZ also shows that high user charges used to restrict automobile usage have problems, since these charges never cover social costs adequately. Other low cost, low technology policies such as BRT, walking and bicycling incentives, ecodriving, de-marketing cars, car-free days, etc., must be adopted, in particular in developing countries.

3. Energy, Emissions and External Costs Due to Unsustainable Transportation in Brazil

This section of the paper sets out the environmental, energy and social costs of the passenger transportation system in Brazil, limited to urban areas with over 60,000 inhabitants [39]. Analysis of the available data leads to the inevitable conclusion that the Brazilian transportation system results in a waste of social, financial, natural and energy resources to a degree that is incompatible with the country’s socio-economic and environmental conditions.
Based on these findings, it is also clear that the use of an unsustainable transportation system leads to public diseconomy in Brazil. Diseconomies arise when the average long-term costs show an upward trend, which is clearly the case in this situation [40].
If urban mobility is defined as the capacity of the transportation system to allow people to move from one place to another according to demand and the average long-term costs to the public in providing such travel are rising, then it is apparent that there are diseconomies of scale in the transportation system. In this case, the diseconomies are public because the public purse has to meet the negative external consequences of individual motorized vehicles, which are not covered by the taxes and duties paid by the users [12].
These negative external consequences, also called “external costs” can be defined as social costs that, without policy intervention, are not taken into account by the transport users. As noted in Maibach et al. [41] “transport users are thus faced with incorrect incentives for transport supply and demand, leading to welfare losses” exactly as in the Brazilian case. External costs can also be defined by the difference among private costs (or internal costs), borne by the transport user, and social costs, which reflects all “costs occurring due to the provision and use of transport infrastructure” [41]. Litman [42,43], Quinet [44], VTPI [45] and ARE [37] noted this cost distribution and definition of motor vehicle costs as shown in Table 5.
Table 5. Cost distribution and definition of motor vehicle.
Table 5. Cost distribution and definition of motor vehicle.
CostVariableFixed
Internal (user)Fuel, short term parking, vehicle maintenance, crash risk, user timeVehicle purchase, registration, insurance payments, long term parking
ExternalRoad maintenance, traffic services, insurance disbursements, congestion delays, environmental impacts, uncompensated crash riskRoad construction, subsidized parking, traffic planning, street lighting, land use impacts, social inequity
Source: Based on Litman [42,43].

3.1. Costs of Traffic Accidents

Globally, traffic accidents are one of the principal public health problems. It is estimated that over a million people lose their lives and 50 million are injured worldwide in road accidents every year [13]. Most of the victims are members of low income groups in developing countries—that is, people who are already amongst the World’s most socially and economically vulnerable.
Most of the infrastructure for urban transportation in the developing world’s major cities was constructed in the last four decades. Particularly in the most vulnerable segment of the World’s population, inadequate planning and the predominance of the interests of road vehicle users led to the construction of transportation systems with a high risk of accidents.
Road systems were constructed in public spaces and were designed to maximize the number and speed of vehicles using them. A large portion of these roads does not even have sidewalks, which results in an unequal struggle between vehicles made of steel and unprotected pedestrians.
In Brazil, the situation is compounded further by a legal system that is lenient, in practice, on aggressive or drunken drivers and also by a system of traffic management that encourages speed and impedes the free circulation of pedestrians. The result is that in Brazil R$ 8.9 billion (approximately USD 5.34 billion) is spent annually on social costs due to road traffic accidents in urban areas with over 60 thousand inhabitants. Of this total, R$ 7.7 billion (approximately USD 4.62 billion) is attributable to damage caused by individual motorized vehicles. The externality costs by mode of transport are presented on Figure 3 [39].
Figure 3. Externality costs by mode of transport, 2008. Key: CT–Collective Transport; IT–Individual Transport. Source: MMA [35].
Figure 3. Externality costs by mode of transport, 2008. Key: CT–Collective Transport; IT–Individual Transport. Source: MMA [35].
Energies 05 00835 g003

3.2. Atmospheric Pollution Emissions

The costs of atmospheric pollution generated by motor vehicles include damages to human health, the environment, and the aesthetics of Nature. This pollution may arise directly from the emissions of vehicles or indirectly from the emissions produced by the various tasks involved in the maintenance of the transportation system infrastructure, such as the extraction and refining of petroleum, the construction and maintenance of roads, and the manufacture of vehicles [9].
The generation of pollutants by motor vehicles is movable, dispersed and persistent and is one of the most difficult environmental factors to control and monitor. Vehicles operate in close proximity to people (vehicle users and pedestrians), so the impact of the pollution is direct.
In Brazil, as in several other countries, there has been a significant effort to reduce the levels of pollutants produced by motor vehicles. Although considerable advances have been made [35], the total amount of pollutants produced by the passenger transportation sector is still substantial. Individual motorized transportation is responsible for 83% of the carbon monoxide emitted by the transportation sector (collective transport generates only 2%). IMT also generates 68% of carbon dioxide produced by the sector, as opposed to 32% emitted by collective transportation. Both types of transportation (IMT and collective) carry roughly the same number of passengers per year (about 17 billion) in Brazil (Table 6).
Of the 28.1 million tons of pollutants [local pollutants: carbon monoxide (CO), hydrocarbons (HC), nitrogen oxides (NOx), sulphur oxides (SO2) and particulate material (PM)] and greenhouse effect pollutants [carbon dioxide (CO2)] generated by passenger transportation in the year 2008, in Brazil, 18.3 million were produced by IMT (17.1 by motor cars). Collective transport emitted 9.8 million tons. As a result, IMT is responsible for approximately 65% of total pollutant emissions in Brazilian cities (Figure 4).
Table 6. Relationship between the number of passengers transported by transport type, the emission of local pollutants and emission of greenhouse effect gases.
Table 6. Relationship between the number of passengers transported by transport type, the emission of local pollutants and emission of greenhouse effect gases.
Emissions 2008/2009Collective TransportIndividual Transport
Passengers/year16.8 billion17 billion
CO2%83%
34,000 tons1,500,000 tons
NOx14%9%
147,000 tons94,500 tons
CO232%68%
18,700,000 tons39,100,100 tons
Source: MMA [35].
Figure 4. Total emissions of atmospheric pollutants in 2008. Source: MMA [35].
Figure 4. Total emissions of atmospheric pollutants in 2008. Source: MMA [35].
Energies 05 00835 g004
In computing the health care and related social costs of pollutants emitted by passenger transportation, we found that out of a total of R$ 6.7 billion (approximately USD 4.02 billion), R$ 4.8 billion (approximately USD 2.88 billion) is generated by IMT and only R$ 1.9 billion (approximately USD 1.14 billion) originates from collective transport [39]. In this context, the most significant of the pollutant emissions, in terms of global warming, is the volume of CO2 emitted by individual transport.

3.3. Energy Waste

The transportation system requires a vast amount of non-renewable energy both in the construction of the system itself and then in the upkeep and management of the infrastructure. The data set out below demonstrate that opting for a system of urban mobility highly dependent on the motor car results in environmental and energy inefficiencies.
The intensity of energy use in the transportation sector increases substantially in societies that opt for a system centered on automobiles. Although Brazil has fewer motor vehicles per thousand inhabitants compared to more developed countries, a significant upward trend can be seen in this index since 2003, as shown in Figure 5 [33].
Figure 5. Cars per thousand inhabitants in Brazil. Source: DENATRAN [33].
Figure 5. Cars per thousand inhabitants in Brazil. Source: DENATRAN [33].
Energies 05 00835 g005
In Brazil, cities with over 60,000 inhabitants consume around 12.1 million Tons of Oil Equivalent (TOE) in their journeys. Motor cars alone consume 73% of this energy total, while collective public transportation consumes 24% (Figure 6).
The situation is substantially worse in cities with over a million inhabitants. Due to the mass use of IMT, large cities use eight times more energy per inhabitant than smaller cities. In large cities with more than a million inhabitants, 634 petroleum equivalent grams (PEG) are consumed per person per day, while the figure in small (less than 100,000 inhabitants) cities is only 76 PEG (Figure 7) [39].
Figure 6. Consumption of energy by type, 2008. Source: ANTP [39].
Figure 6. Consumption of energy by type, 2008. Source: ANTP [39].
Energies 05 00835 g006
Figure 7. Energy consumed per inhabitant per day by transport type (Petroleum Equivalent Grams). Source: MMA [35].
Figure 7. Energy consumed per inhabitant per day by transport type (Petroleum Equivalent Grams). Source: MMA [35].
Energies 05 00835 g007
Table 7 depicts energy consumption and mode rate in billion pass-km/million TOE per year and estimate data for 2020 in Brazilian cities. One can see that collective transportation produces 82 pass-km/TOE of energy average rate. Automobiles are responsible for 13.8 pass-km/TOE energy average rate and motorcycle by a 32.4 pass-km/TOE average rate. Consumption per passenger-km shows automobiles as the highest consumers, while collective transportation is the most efficient system. Automobiles need almost seven times more energy in order to move people through Brazilian cities.
Table 7. Energy Consumption and Efficient Rate in Bi Pass-Km/Million TOE per Year.
Table 7. Energy Consumption and Efficient Rate in Bi Pass-Km/Million TOE per Year.
Mode/Eff. Rate200320042005200620072008200920102011201220132014201520162017201820192020
CT Rate71.971.771.174.374.877.976.778.580.281.682.583.784.786.487.588.689.891.1
CT Energy2.62.72.82.82.92.93.03.03.03.03.03.03.03.03.03.03.03.0
Auto Rate13.913.814.014.013.813.913.813.813.813.813.713.713.713.713.713.613.613.6
Auto Energy7.67.88.18.38.68.88.99.09.39.59.79.810.010.210.310.410.610.7
Moto Rate35.040.030.033.336.730.035.032.431.632.931.831.231.830.730.830.630.129.9
Moto Energy0.20.20.30.30.30.40.40.40.50.50.50.50.50.50.50.50.50.6
IMT Total7.88.08.48.68.99.19.39.49.79.910.210.310.510.710.811.011.111.2
Total10.410.811.211.411.812.112.312.412.712.913.213.313.513.713.814.014.114.2
Note: Moto means motorcycle.

3.4. Infrastructure Costs and Use of Public Space

The cost of maintaining the transportation infrastructure in Brazil, defined in this study as the amount spent by public authorities on the functioning of the transportation system, amounted to R$ 11.1 billion (approximately USD 6.66 billion) per year in 2008. Of this sum, R$ 10.4 billion (approximately USD 6.24 billion) went towards the movement of IMT, and only R$ 0.7 billion (approximately USD 0.42 billion) is for collective transport [39].
Some authors, such as Quinet [15], argue that the expansion of the road system is socially beneficial. According to this line of reasoning, the real estate value of areas where expansion occurs is increased. Litman [46], however, argues that this view ignores the fact that the expenditure of time, money and manpower required to accommodate a system based on the private motor vehicle is much greater than other means of transportation.
Figure 8. Relative consumption and impact of the use of buses, motorcycles and cars in Brazilian cities (Bus value = 1). Source: ANTP [39].
Figure 8. Relative consumption and impact of the use of buses, motorcycles and cars in Brazilian cities (Bus value = 1). Source: ANTP [39].
Energies 05 00835 g008
Litman also notes that the designation of land for road construction results in a diseconomy of scale due to the cost of providing services, such as electricity, water, and garbage collection, to a sparsely populated area. This model of a transportation system also has an expansionist effect in urban areas, in some cases leading to unregulated expansion, and creates independent or isolated zones within the city. This can lead to even further public expense, including the duplication of infrastructure for the passage of vehicles, duplication of public and private services, and use of land for parking spaces and private garages [47].
There is a flagrant disproportionality in the use of road space in Brazil (Figure 8). Cars occupy 7.8 times more space per passenger-km than buses. This disparity becomes even more evident in light of the figures on average occupancy of each vehicle. Cars carry fewer than two people per vehicle, (a statistical average of 1.5), while buses carry an average of 30 passengers, and motorcycles carry one passenger (statistically: 1.1) [39]. Taking the bus as a reference point, Figure 8 illustrates this disparity.

4. Potential Savings by Cutting Individual Transportation

Based on transportation demand forecasting described in this appendix and presented in Maciel and Rosa [48], Table 8 presents a Business as Usual (BAU) scenario to urban zones in Brazil.
Table 8. Projection of transportation demand and external costs up to 2020.
Table 8. Projection of transportation demand and external costs up to 2020.
YearsBillion Passenger-KmMillions toe EnergyThousand Tons PollutionThousand tons CO2Billion USD ExternalBillion USD Infrastructure
200330010.41,59023,1355.94.7
200430810.81,57823,9136.45.2
200532111.21,50224,8047.05.5
200633411.41,53925,1987.45.7
200734711.81,59025,8358.46.1
200836012.11,62526,5189.56.7
200936712.31,65926,84210.47.1
201037212.41,60226,95310.87.4
201138312.71,63527,46211.77.9
201239012.91,67127,80312.68.4
201339713.21,67828,13613.59.0
201440313.31,68028,38814.39.5
201540913.51,68528,60315.110.0
201641513.71,69128,79316.010.7
201742013.81,70928,98316.911.4
201842514.01,71329,15717.712.2
201942914.11,71429,29718.613.0
202043314.21,72129,42019.413.9
Note: Bold and italic numbers refer to projection data.
But what could be a new scenario, considering a hypothetical Brazilian government decision to curb individual transportation? The new scenario is presented, assuming that individual transportation is cut by 30%. This value was chosen for the following reasons: first, it is related to the imminent threat of substantial reductions in oil product offerings in the coming decades and a high level of certainty that this reduction will be on the order of 30% [49]. It is important to note that oil is the primary energy source which supplies the global transportation system with over than 90% of its market share [5]. Second, there is a need to decrease approximately CO2 emissions in transportation by 30% by 2020 [50,51]. Third, passenger km demand is expected to grow by 30% by 2020 [52]. The latter deals with the contributing mechanism limitations such as the TDM (Transportation Demand Management) present in provoking commuting demand changes of circa 30% [53,54,55,56,57,58,59]. This reduction can be obtained by combining low cost, low technology policies in order to build a “conservationist scenario” by 2020. A summary of potential gains of such policies is presented below in Table 9.
Table 9. Summary of low cost, low technology policies in order to reduce IMT use.
Table 9. Summary of low cost, low technology policies in order to reduce IMT use.
PoliciesStudyEstimated Reduction
BRTKahn et al. [56]25%
De-marketing CarWright and Egan [57]22%
Traffic Calming and Speed LimitedVTPI [58]10%
Congestion ChargeSantos, Behrendt and Teytelboym [59] Leap [60]29%–34%
Car SharingVTPI [58]5%
Improved facilities for cycling and walkingVTPI [58]2%
TeleworkingVTPI [58]4%
Ergo, it can be stated that BRT is one of the main modes in mitigating IMT use. As noted by Kahn et al. [56] “Bus Rapid Transit (BRT) is ‘a mass transit system using exclusive right of way lanes that mimic the rapidity and performance of metro systems, but utilizes bus technology rather than rail vehicle technology’. BRT systems can be seen as enhanced bus service and an intermediate mode between conventional bus service and heavy rail systems”.
Its important to note that, to be more effective, BRT systems should “be part of a comprehensive strategy that includes increasing vehicle and fuel taxes, strict land-use controls, limits and higher fees on parking, and integrating transit systems into a broader package of mobility for all types of travelers” [56].
Although BRT could be considered as a low cost public policy (railroad and metro can cost 10 or even 15 times more), most BRT systems are being delivered in 1–15 million US$/km range (depending upon the capacity requirements and complexity of the project) [56].
The idea of transport de-marketing is not new. As quoted by Wright and Egan [57] “an example would be the advertising campaign mounted by the UK government during the Second World War, asking citizens to refrain from using transport resources generally: “Is your journey really necessary?” In one scheme in a residential experience with de-marketing in Adelaide (Australia) the result was a reported as a reduction of approximately 22% in vehicular traffic levels.
Leape [60] stated that as observed in London experience, a congestion charge can reduce IMT trips in 33%. Actually, Leap noted that “the number of private cars, vans, and trucks coming into central London dropped 27 percent between 2002 (before the charge) and 2003. The 33 percent drop in inbound car traffic represents some 65,000–70,000 trips that are no longer made”.
In addition, some other non-pricing measures to reduce passenger-km transportation demand can be used, such as ridesharing, transit improvements, HOV (high occupation vehicle) lanes, flexible work hours, telecommuting and land-use planning. These combined measures can reduce vehicle travel by less than 6 percent [61] (Graham-Rowe et al. [62] found a review of available evidences in 77 studies searching for car use reductions; these studies stated several others forms of intervention which can be used in order to reduce car use).
All of these aforementioned policies are only estimates, can be obtained in short and mid-term, and as other cities have experienced already, some Brazilian cities will achieve this goal of individual transport demand decrease faster. On the other hand, some urban areas will require more time and further public actions. Therefore, despite of the fact that the total reduction can exceed 30%, this target is enough to build a conservationist scenario which shows energy waste, atmospheric sunk and financial resources in Brazilian cities. It is also important to explain that this reduction is just a target intention and can be superseded if these combinations of low cost, low technology policies would be implemented, as one can see by summarizing the estimated reductions listed in Table 9. Hence, considering this combination of low cost, low technology public policies, the conservationist scenario would be presented as below (Table 10).
Table 10. Realized and projection of transportation demand, energy, emissions and external costs in a conservationist scenario: 2003–2020.
Table 10. Realized and projection of transportation demand, energy, emissions and external costs in a conservationist scenario: 2003–2020.
Billion Pass-Km/CSMillions TOE EnergyThousand Tons PollutionThousand Tons CO2Billion USD ExternalBillion USD Infra
YearMotoCarsCTTotalBAUCSBAUCSBAUCSBAUCSBAUCS
2003710618730010.4Energy: Potential Saving1,590Pollution: Potential Saving23,135CO2: Potential Saving5.9Externality: Potential Saving4.7Infrastructure: Potential Saving
2004810819230810.81,57823,9136.45.2
2005911319932111.21,50224,8047.05.5
20061011620833411.41,53925,1987.45.7
20071111921734711.81,59025,8358.46.1
20081212222636012.11,62526,5189.56.7
20091412323036712.31,65926,84210.47.1
20101412523337212.41,73026,95310.27.4
20111512824038312.71,63527,46211.77.9
2012109228839012.910.51,6711,26027,80324,00212.610.08.46.1
2013119329339713.29.21,6781,26328,13624,24013.510.79.06.6
2014119529840313.39.31,6801,26228,38824,39814.311.39.56.9
2015119630240913.59.51,6851,26328,60324,51515.111.910.07.3
2016119730641513.79.61,6911,26528,79324,61216.012.510.77.8
2017119831042013.89.71,7091,27628,98324,71216.913.311.48.3
20181110031442514.09.81,7131,27729,15724,80617.713.912.28.9
20191110131742914.19.91,7141,27629,29724,86818.614.513.09.5
20201210232043314.29.91,7211,27929,42024,91319.415.213.910.2
Summarize difference between BAU and CS Scenarios35.43,84237,51230.926.5
Notes: 1. In yellow there are the projections by 2020 year; 2. BAU–Business as usual; CS–Conservationist Scenario; 3. Moto means motorcycle.
The various columns under the “conservationist scenario” heading assume a 30% cut in IMT use in the future economy. The last line summarizes the economy potential which in this case, achieves savings of over 35 million of TOE; 3,842 thousand tons of local pollution; 37,512 thousand of CO2 (GHG); 30.9 USD billion in externalities; and almost 27 USD billion in mobility infrastructure.
The following section sets out comparative graphs for each external factor and the equations produced by the regression analysis [63]. The lines shown refer to the calculation of linear trends for each externality, based on real data gathered between 2003 and 2011, and a new projection, based on a 30% of linear reduction in IMT use (these linear trends are based on the EPE [64] study).
The trend is one of a rise in energy consumption until it reaches approximately 14 million TOE per year as a result of the continued patterns of the present urban transportation system, but it is possible to reverse this trend if one could consider reducing car and motorcycle use (Figure 9).
Figure 9. Trend of Energy Consumption versus Potential Reduction in Passenger Transportation—2012/2020.
Figure 9. Trend of Energy Consumption versus Potential Reduction in Passenger Transportation—2012/2020.
Energies 05 00835 g009
The study of the variation in the volume of local pollutants merits further critical analysis. The introduction of more stringent environmental legislation and the formulation of the Program for the Control of Air Pollution by Automotive Vehicles (PROCONVE) rules [coordinated by IBAMA, which set out the first emission limits for light vehicles and contributed to attaining the standards of air quality instituted by the National Program for the Control of Air Quality (PRONAR). On 28 October 1993, Law No. 8723 introduced compulsory reduction of emission levels of pollutants from vehicles, thus forcing technological developments by the manufacturers of fuels, engines and auto parts and making Brazilian and imported vehicles comply with the legal limits] led to significant advances in the reduction of local atmospheric pollutants [carbon monoxide (CO), nitrogen oxides (NOx), total hydrocarbons (THCescap)/evaporative emissions (NMHCescap), particulate material (PM), and aldehydes (RCHO)]. Although the Brazilian Environment Ministry forecasts [35] that these measures will continue to reduce the levels of pollution in Brazil, one important aspect that has been overlooked in these studies is that urban areas, which are the focus of this article, are recording progressively more severe congestion indices [16] (congestion is defined by Phil Goodwin as the obstruction which vehicles mutually create for each other, as well as for the speed of traffic flow, when the transport system nears its maximum capacity [65]). On that basis, advances in environmental efficiency may be partially offset by the extra time spent in city traffic, where the longer a vehicle is caught up in slow moving or arrested traffic, the greater the use of energy and the greater the energy inefficiency ([66] and Vasconcellos [16]). In any event, the time series forecast shows a trend towards growth, albeit with a R2 coefficient of 0.8705 (Figure 10).
Figure 10. Emission Trends for Local Pollutants–Passenger Transportation—2012/2020.
Figure 10. Emission Trends for Local Pollutants–Passenger Transportation—2012/2020.
Energies 05 00835 g010
Figure 11 shows that a significant proportion of total emissions of greenhouse effect gases in Brazil originate from the use of energy for urban mobility. The projected total for the year 2020 shows an increase in volume up to approximately 30 million tons of CO2 per year. The potential saving in this case reaches almost 92 million tons of CO2 in the next eight years.
Figure 11. CO2 Emissions Trends—2012/2020.
Figure 11. CO2 Emissions Trends—2012/2020.
Energies 05 00835 g011
The two final figures show a significant increase in external costs for public authorities in relation to the maintenance of the transportation system. First, Figure 12 describes the cost of the projected externalities as that of an unsustainable transportation system. These include social costs arising from the need to deal with accidents caused by the transportation system. Figure 13 shows the projected infrastructure costs due to traffic-related in cities, where the amounts represent costs spent on traffic expenditures.
Figure 12. External Factors Trends—2012/2020.
Figure 12. External Factors Trends—2012/2020.
Energies 05 00835 g012
Figure 13. Costs of Infrastructure Trends—2012/2020.
Figure 13. Costs of Infrastructure Trends—2012/2020.
Energies 05 00835 g013
All of the projected trends for negative external factors produced by the passenger transportation system in urban areas in Brazil point to increases by the year 2020. This trend towards an increase in costs will, in the near future, produce negative effects for the maintenance of the infrastructure and traffic support systems, which will be even more significant than the current effects. As a marginal negative effect, the public diseconomies generated in the process of energy consumption, the emission of pollution and, most of all, the emission of greenhouse effect gases, will tarnish Brazil’s international reputation and undermine its image as a country striving to improve its environmental track record. Finally, money misspent on external costs reduces the resources that might otherwise be allocated to key social areas such as education, policing and housing.

5. Conclusions

It is important to emphasize that this study aims to point what could happen in the near future in terms of the externalities present in the current passenger transportation system in Brazil. It is essential to note that the period for which data was analyzed precisely reflects the increase in demand by socio-economic classes C and D (Class C means a monthly average income between USD 672 and USD 2896. Class D means a monthly average income between USD 484 and USD 672, Neri, [67]) for access to motorized transportation. This change has been ongoing since 2003 [34].
We found that the negative externalities already at high levels, such as inefficient energy consumption, excessive production of local pollutants and greenhouse effect gases, and high external costs including expenditures on infrastructure, all show a trend towards increased growth by the year 2020.
Energy consumption and the generation of local pollutants force rising up the costs of the transportation system, but considerable effort is being made through government action and by the automobile industry itself to make motor vehicles more efficient from an energy and environmental viewpoint. Nevertheless, energy consumption is estimated to reach around 14 million TOE per year in 2020. In the case of local pollutants, the estimated amount is 1,721 thousand tons for the same period.
With respect to emissions of CO2, the most important greenhouse effect gas, the estimated amount will reach almost 30 million tons, which will contribute to the efforts of Brazil to reduce such emissions.
Even with considerable advances in the energy and environmental efficiency of motor vehicles seen in the last decade, the growth in the total number of individual motorized vehicles and their increasingly intense use will more than offset these advances. Social costs through road accidents and hospital costs produced by vehicle pollution are becoming progressively greater and more significant. It is estimated that they will reach R$ 32 billion (approximately USD 19 billion) in 2020. Similarly, infrastructure costs will exceed R$ 23 billion (approximately USD 14 billion) in the period under analysis.
Based on these data, we recommend that Brazil should invest in new research projects considering cost benefit analysis in order to redesign its transport system. Expanding collective transportation and limiting individual motorized transportation could be powerful alternatives, as it was thoroughly demonstrated in this article. Furthermore, we recommend further research on the potential for reducing public diseconomies generated by urban passenger transportation expenditures projected to year 2020. Possible areas of research include quantification of the acceleration of public diseconomies generated by the transport system.

Appendix (Based on Maciel and Rosa [48])

Projection of External Costs and Positive Effects Limiting IMT in the Transportation System for the Year 2020

Given that the current situation is already serious, with Brazil consuming economic, energy, material and natural resources in quantities far greater than it would in a more sustainable transportation system, what will the situation be in 2020 if the current system continues without change?
In order to make a data projection for the year 2020, we conducted a time series analysis, using a simple linear regression model. The aim of this study is to quantitatively project the negative externalities associated with the urban transportation system in Brazil.
According to Levine et al. [68], time series predictions project the future values of a variable based entirely on the observation of the present and past values of that variable (Han and Hayashi [69] argue “[…] passenger transport demand is usually estimated by one of two methods. One is to extrapolate the historical trend, where the passenger turnover volume (p-km) is regarded as the explained variable, and population, per capita GDP, vehicle numbers, etc. are the explanatory variables […]. The other way is to estimate transport demand according to the national development strategy […]”. We have chosen to extrapolate the historical trend in this study). This is precisely the aim of this research.
With regard to the calculation of trends, the author adds that “the trend is studied as a support for the making of medium and long-term predictions”. The model was constructed on the basis of an independent variable: the estimated demand for motorized urban travel. Future demand for passenger transportation is projected in billions of passengers.kilometers/year. In order to estimate this figure, our study used the database of IBGE [34] and DENATRAN [33], for defining the independent variables, including urban population, GDP per capita, automobile and motorcycle stock. Then, it estimated the passenger km multiple regression equation. Population has a strong relationship with mobility demand. More population probably means more people trying to get transportation by urban sites. The change in GDP per capita experienced by Brazil since 2003 is another factor that provokes more demand in individual transportation, given the income effect. Finally, the automobile and motorcycle total stock is the last variable to set the limits of individual motorized transportation in Brazilian cities (see Table A1).
Table A1. Brazilian data and the PKM demand.
Table A1. Brazilian data and the PKM demand.
TimeCars aTwo wheels aInhabitants bGDP per Capita (USD) cKm-pass per year d
200323,669,0326,220,156178,741,0005,730300
200424,936,4517,121,696181,106,0006,458308
200526,309,2568,153,069183,383,0007,054321
200627,868,5649,444,037185,564,0007,692334
200729,851,61011,154,985187,642,0008,544347
200832,054,68413,079,701189,613,0009,546360
200934,536,66714,688,678191,481,0009,888367
201037,188,34116,490,178193,252,60410,522372
201138,222,66017,555,629194,932,68511,342383
Notes: a Values from [33]; b c Values from [34]; d Values from [39].
Using a multiple regression analysis we calculate the statistics. The coefficient of determination R2 = 0.999656, indicate a strong correlation among variables. The standard error for the y estimate is 0.8216 which measures the standard deviation of y around its fitted value. The analysis of these statistics (see Table A2, Table A3 and Table A4) indicates a robust regression model.
Table A2. Summary Output—Regression Statistics.
Table A2. Summary Output—Regression Statistics.
Multiple R0.99
R Square0.99
Adjusted R Square0.99
Standard Error0.82
Observations7
Table A3. Anova.
Table A3. Anova.
dfSSMSFSignificance F
Regression43933.50983.371456.710.0006
Residual21.350.67
Total63934.85
Table A4. Regression statistics—Variables.
Table A4. Regression statistics—Variables.
CoefficientsStandard Errort StatP-valueLower 95%Upper 95%Lower 95%Upper 95%
Intercept−707.54160.08−4.410.04−1396.39−18.7529−1396.34−18.75
X11.77 × 10−54.16 × 10−64.250.051−3.55 × 10−52.15 × 10−7−3.55 × 10−52.14 × 10−7
X22.59 × 10−56.06 × 10−64.270.05−1.47 × 10−75.2 × 10−5−1.47 × 10−75.19 × 10−5
X37.5 × 10−61.33 × 10−65.6360.0341.77 × 10−61.32 × 10−51.77 × 10−61.32 × 10−5
X40.0130.0052.330.146−0.040.01−0.0380.011
The resulting PKM demand equation is:
Y = β 0 + β 1 × X 1 + β 2 × X 2 + β 3 × X 3 + β 4 × X 4
replacing the variables:
P K m D e m a n d = 707.54 + 1.77 E 05 × X 1 + 2.59 E 05 × X 2 + 7.50 E 06 × X 3 + 1.30 E 03 × X 4
or:
P K m D e m a n d = 707.54 + 1.77 E 05 × A u t o m o b i l e s + 2.59 E 05 × M o t o r c y c l e s + 7.50 E 06 × P o p u l a t i o n + 1.30 E 03 × G D P p e r c a p i t a
Table A5 and Figure A1 present the forecasts for PKM demand.
Table A5. PKM Demand forecasts.
Table A5. PKM Demand forecasts.
TimeCarsTwo wheelsInhabitantsGDP per Capita (USD)km.pass per year
201240,149,51219,058,199196,526,29312,044390
201342,076,36420,560,770198,043,32012,747397
201444,003,21622,063,340199,492,43313,450403
201545,930,06823,565,910200,881,68514,153409
201647,856,92025,068,481202,219,06114,855415
201749,783,77226,571,051203,510,42215,558420
201851,710,62428,073,621204,759,99316,261425
201953,637,47629,576,192205,970,18216,964429
202055,564,32831,078,762207,143,24317,666433
Figure A1. Forecasts of passenger demand 2010–2020.
Figure A1. Forecasts of passenger demand 2010–2020.
Energies 05 00835 g014
The Adjusted R Square statistic shows the strong relationship between time and transport demand (in relation to t stat, it is important to note that “The exact critical t depends on the degrees of freedom. At the 10% level, the critical t will be about ± 1.67, while the 5% critical t is about ± 1.96. It is usually required that the analysis is 90% (P value of 0.10 or less) certain of the estimate in order to conclude a “significant” relationship between the Y and X variable. In some cases, 80% might be notable” (Regression Analysis, 2011). The value is 0.99, which indicates that about 99% of transportation demand is explained by the time series.
Then, using the estimated transportation demand as the exogenous variable, this study estimates the external costs of urban transportation system in Brazil. Therefore, the variable “mobility demand” becomes the independent variable, and costs are estimated as a function of this variable. The calculated estimates are shown in Table A6.
Table A6. Projection of external costs up to 2020.
Table A6. Projection of external costs up to 2020.
Billion Pass-kmMillions TOEThousand TonsThousand TonsBillion USDBillion USD
YearsMotoCarsCTTotalEnergyPollutionCO2ExternalInfra
Realized Demand2003710618730010.41,59023,1355.94.7
2004810819230810.81,57823,9136.45.2
2005911319932111.21,50224,8047.05.5
20061011620833411.41,53925,1987.45.7
20071111921734711.81,59025,8358.46.1
20081212222636012.11,62526,5189.56.7
20091412323036712.31,65926,84210.47.1
20101412523337212.41,73026,95310.87.4
20111512824038312.71,72527,46211.77.9
Projection20121513124439012.91,78527,80312.68.4
20131513324939713.21,82428,13613.59.0
20141513525340313.31,86128,38814.39.5
20151613725640913.51,90028,60315.110.0
20161613926041513.71,93828,79316.010.7
20171614126342013.81,97328,98316.911.4
20181614226642514.02,01929,15717.712.2
20191614426942914.12,05429,29718.613.0
20201714527243314.22,09329,42019.413.9

References

  1. Energy Information Administration (EIA). Annual Energy Outlook; EIA: Washington, DC, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  2. British Petroleum (BP). Bpstatistical Review of World Energy 2007; BP: London, UK, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  3. Energy Information Administration (EIA). CO2 Emissions from Fuels Combustions; OECD/IEA: Paris, France, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  4. Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). Working Group I Contribution to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change Fourth Assessment Report: Climate Change 2007—The Physical Science Basis—Summary for Policy Makers; IPCC: Paris, France, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  5. Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). World Oil Outlook 2007; OPEC: Vienna, Austria, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  6. World Business Council for Sustainable Development (WBSCD). Mobility 2030: Meeting the Challenges to Sustainability; World Business Council for Sustainable Development: Geneva, Switzerland, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  7. Dupuy, G. Les Territoires de L'automobile; Anthropos: Paris, France, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  8. Litman, T. VTPI 2009. Available online: http://www.vtpi.org/future.pdf (accessed on 26 September 2009).
  9. Litman, T.; Burwell, D. Issues in sustainable transportation. Int. J. Glob. Environ. 2006, 6, 331–247. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. de Vasconcellos, E.A. Transporte Urbano nos Países em Desenvolvimento; Anablume: São Paulo, Brazil, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  11. Litman, T. VTPI 2012. Available online: http://www.vtpi.org/land.pdf (accessed on 21 February 2012).
  12. Gwilliam, K. Cities on the Move: A World Bank Urban Transport Strategy Review; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  13. World Health Organization (WHO). World Report on Road Traffic Injury Prevention; WHO: Geneva, Switzerland, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  14. Granados, J. Reducing automobile traffic: An urgent policy for health promotion. Rev. Panam. Salud Publica 1998, 3, 227–241. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  15. Quinet, E. The social Costs of Transport: Evaluation and Links with Internalization Policies. In Internalizing the Social Costs of Transport; Button, K., Ed.; OECD: Paris, France, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  16. de Vasconcellos, E.A. Transporte e Meio Ambiente: Conceitos e Informações Para Análise de Impactos; Anablume: São Paulo, Brazil, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  17. Rosa, L.P. Climate Changes and Gases Emissions in the Energy System: Contributions from Transport Sector. In Transportation and Climate Change; Kahn, S.E., Ed.; COPPE/RJ: Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 2003; pp. 7–10. [Google Scholar]
  18. World Bank. Cities on the Move: A World Bank Urban Transport Strategy Review; The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development: Washington, DC, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  19. Gwilliam, K. A review of issues in transit economics. Res. Transp. Econ. 2008, 23, 4–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. World Commission on Environment and Development. Report of the World Commission on Environment and Development: Our Common Future; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1987. [Google Scholar]
  21. Feitelson, E. Introducing environmental equity dimensions into the sustainable transport discourse: Issues and pitfalls. Transp. Res. D 2002, 7, 99–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Gudmundsson, H.; Höjer, M. Sustainable development principles and their implications for transport. Ecol. Econ. 1996, 19, 269–282. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Black, W. Sustainable Transportation: Problems and Solutions; Guilford Press: New York, NY, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  24. Urry, J. The “System” of automobility. Theory Cult. Soc. 2004, 21, 25–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Fulton, L.; Eads, G. IEA/SMP Model Documentation and Reference Projection; World Business Council for Sustainable Development: Geneva, Switzerland, 2004. Available online: http://www.wbcsd.org/web/publications/mobility/smp-model-document.pdf (accessed on 15 February 2012).
  26. Wright, L.; Fulton, L. Climate mitigation and transport in developing nations. Transp. Rev. 2005, 25, 607–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. He, D.; Meng, F.; Wang, M.Q.; He, K. Impacts of urban transportation mode split on CO2 emissions in Jinan, China. Energies 2011, 4, 685–699. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Hau, T. Economics Fundamentals of Road Pricing: A Diagramatica Analysis; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
  29. Parry, I.; Walls, M.; Harrington, W. Automobile externalities and policies. J. Econ. Lit. 2007, XLV, 373–399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Schipper, L.; Eriksson, G. Taxation Policies Affecting Automobile Characteristics and Use in Western Europe, Japan and the United States. In Transportation and Energy: Strategies for a Sustainable Transportation System; Sperling, D., Shahen, S., Eds.; America Council for an Energy Efficient Economy: Washington, DC, USA, 1995; pp. 217–242. [Google Scholar]
  31. Chapman, L. Transport and climate change: A review. J. Transp. Geogr. 2007, 15, 354–367. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Sperling, D.; Gordon, D. Two billion cars. TR News 2008, 2–9. [Google Scholar]
  33. Departamento Nacional de Transportes (DENATRAN). Available online: http://www.Denatran.gov.br/ (accessed on 14 February 2012).
  34. Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (IBGE). Available online: http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/mapa_site/mapa_site.php#economia (accessed on 16 February 2012).
  35. Ministério do Meio Ambiente (MMA). 2010. Available online: http://www.mma.gov.br (accessed on 3 July 2010).
  36. Wright, L. The Limits of Technology: Achieving Transport Efficiency in Developing Nations; University College London: London, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  37. ARE. External Cost of Transport in Switzerland. Swiss Federal Office of Spatial Development. Available online: http://www.are.admin.ch/themen/verkehr/00252/00472/index.html?lang=en (accessed on 16 February 2012).
  38. GTZ. The role of transport in urban development policy. Sustainable transport: A sourcebook for police-makers in developing cities. Available online: http://www.unhabitat.org/downloads/docs/8858_57875_2_Dakar2010_GTZ_Sourcebook_07102010.pdf (accessed on 22 March 2012).
  39. Associação Nacional de Transportes Públicos (ANTP). Sistema de Informações da Mobilidade Urbana—Relatório Geral. Year. Available online: http://portal1.antp.net/site/simob/Downloads/Forms/AllItems.aspx (accessed on 14 February 2012).
  40. Rutherford, D. Routledge Dictionary of Economics; Taylor & Francis Group: London, UK, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  41. Maibach, M.; Schreyer, C.; Sutter, D.; van Essen, H.P.; Boon, B.H.; Smokers, R.; Schroten, A.; Doll, C.; Pawlowska, B.; Bak, M. Handbook on estimation of external costs in the transport sector. Produced within the Study on Internalisation Measures and Policies for All External Costs of Transport (IMPACT). CE Delft, for the European Commission DG TREN. 2008. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/transport/costs/handbook/doc/2008_01_15_handbook_external_cost_en.pdf (accessed on 18 February 2012).
  42. Litman, T. Transportation cost analysis; applications in developed and developing countries. Int. J. Appl. Econ. Econom. 1998, 7, 115–137. [Google Scholar]
  43. Litman, T. Transportation Cost and Benefit Analysis; Techniques, Estimates and Implications. 2009. Available online: http://www.vtpi.org/tca (accessed on 17 February 2012).
  44. Quinet, E. A meta-analysis of Western European external cost estimates. Transp. Res. D 2004, 9, 465–476. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Victoria Transport Policy Institute (VTPI). Online TDM Encyclopedia. Available online: http://www.vtpi.org/tdm (accessed on 18 February 2012).
  46. Litman, T. Land use impact costs of transportation. World Transp. Policy Pract. 1995, 1, 9–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Kelbaugh, D. Housing Affordability and Density; Washington Department of Community Development: Washington, DC, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
  48. Maciel, M.; Rosa, L. Externalidades negativas do transporte insustentável em zonas urbanas do Brasil para 2020. 2012, in press. [Google Scholar]
  49. Krumdieck, S.; Page, S.; Dantas, A. Urban form and long-term fuel supply decline: A method to investigate. Transp. Res. A 2010, 44, 306–322. [Google Scholar]
  50. IPCC. Working group III: Mitigation. Available online: http://www.ipcc.ch/ipccreports/tar/wg3/index.php?idp=106 (accessed on 14 March 2012).
  51. Vergara, W.; Haeussling, S. Transport and Climate: Lessons from the Partnership between Mexico City and the World Bank; The World Bank Latin America and the Caribean Region Sustainable Development Department (LCSSD): Washington, DC, USA, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  52. WBSCD. Mobility 2030: Meeting the challenges to sustainability. The Sustainable Mobility Project Full Report 2004; World Business Council for Sustainable Development: Geneva, Switzerland, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  53. Meyer, M. Demand management as an element of transportation policy: using carrots and sticks to influence travel behavior. Transp. Res. A 1999, 33, 575–599. [Google Scholar]
  54. Rotaris, L.; Danielis, R.; Marcucci, E.; Massiani, J. The urban road pricing scheme to curb pollution in Milan, Italy: Description, impacts and preliminary cost-benefit analysis assessment. Transp. Res. A 2010, 44, 359–375. [Google Scholar]
  55. Institute of Transportation Engineers. Evaluation of Employee Trip Reduction Programs Based on California’s Experience with Regulation XV; Institute of Transportation Engineers: Washington, DC, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  56. Kahn Ribeiro, S.; Kobayashi, S.; Beuthe, M.; Gasca, J.; Greene, D.L.; Lee, D.S.; Muromachi, Y.; Newton, P.J.; Plotkin, S.; Sperling, D.; Wit, R.; Zhou, P.J. Transportation and its Infrastructure. In Climate Change 2007: Mitigation; Contribution of Working Group III to the Fourth; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK and New York, NY, USA, 2007; pp. 323–386. [Google Scholar]
  57. Wright, C.; Egan, J. De-marketing car. Transp. Policy 2000, 7, 287–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. VTPI. Available online: http://www.vtpi. org/tdm (accessed on 17 February 2012).
  59. Santos, G.; Behrendt, H.; Teytekboym, A. Part II: Policy instruments for sustainable road transport. Res. Transp. Econ. 2010, 28, 46–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Leape, J. The London congestion charge. J. Econ. Perspect. 2006, 20, 157–176. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Greene, D.L.; Plotkin, S.E. Reducing Greenhouse Gas Emissions from U.S. Transportation; Pew Center on Global Climate Change: Arlington, VA, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  62. Graham-Rowe, E.; Skippon, S.; Gardner, B.; Abraham, C. Can we reduce car use, if so, how? A review of available evidence. Transp. Res. A 2011, 45, 401–418. [Google Scholar]
  63. Regression Analysis. 2011. Available online: http://org.elon.edu/econ/sac/regress.htm (accessed on 31 March 2011).
  64. Empresa de Pesquisa Energética (EPE). Estudo Associado ao Plano Decenal Consolidação de Bases de Dados do Setor Transporte: PDE 2021; Ministério de Minas e Energia: Brasília, Brazil, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  65. Goodwin, P. The Economic Costs of Road Traffic Congestion; The Rail Freight Group: London, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  66. Hymel, K. Does traffic congestion reduce employment growth? J. Urban Econ. 2009, 65, 127–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Neri, M. The Little Big Decade: Crisis, Scenario and the New Middle Class; CPS/FGV: Rua Barão de Itambi, Brazil, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  68. Levine, D.M. Statistics for Managers Using Microsoft Excel; Pearson Education: New Work, NY, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  69. Han, J.; Hayashi, Y. A system dynamics model of CO2 mitigation in China’s inter-city passenger transport. Transp. Res. D 2008, 13, 298–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Maciel, M.; Rosa, L.; Correa, F.; Maruyama, U. Energy, Pollutant Emissions and Other Negative Externality Savings from Curbing Individual Motorized Transportation (IMT): A Low Cost, Low Technology Scenario Analysis in Brazilian Urban Areas. Energies 2012, 5, 835-861. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5030835

AMA Style

Maciel M, Rosa L, Correa F, Maruyama U. Energy, Pollutant Emissions and Other Negative Externality Savings from Curbing Individual Motorized Transportation (IMT): A Low Cost, Low Technology Scenario Analysis in Brazilian Urban Areas. Energies. 2012; 5(3):835-861. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5030835

Chicago/Turabian Style

Maciel, Marcelo, Luiz Rosa, Fernando Correa, and Ursula Maruyama. 2012. "Energy, Pollutant Emissions and Other Negative Externality Savings from Curbing Individual Motorized Transportation (IMT): A Low Cost, Low Technology Scenario Analysis in Brazilian Urban Areas" Energies 5, no. 3: 835-861. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5030835

APA Style

Maciel, M., Rosa, L., Correa, F., & Maruyama, U. (2012). Energy, Pollutant Emissions and Other Negative Externality Savings from Curbing Individual Motorized Transportation (IMT): A Low Cost, Low Technology Scenario Analysis in Brazilian Urban Areas. Energies, 5(3), 835-861. https://doi.org/10.3390/en5030835

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop