5.1. Designs for Carbon Emission Reduction Targets
China’s government has established different carbon emissions targets for energy conservation and emissions reduction in different periods, and several targets for energy conservation and emissions reduction are presented below. First, the development planning of the “National 11th Five-Year Plan” noted that the energy consumption of per unit GDP would be reduced by 20% and the discharge of major pollutants would be reduced by 10% compared with 2005 levels by 2010. Second, the “Outlines of the National 12th Five-Year Plan for Energy Conservation and Emissions Reduction”published by the State Council mentioned that by 2015, the national chemical oxygen demands and sulfur dioxide emissions would be controlled to 23.476 million tons and 20.864 million tons, which represent decreases of 8% from the 25.517 million tons and 22.678 million tons observed in 2010, respectively. By 2015, the national ammonia nitrogen and nitrogen oxide emissions would be controlled within 2.38 million tons and 20.462 million tons, respectively, which represent decreases of 10% from the 2.644 million tons and 22.736 million tons observed in 2010. Third, the “Work Plan for Greenhouse Gas Emissions Control during the National 12th Five-Year Period” published by the State Council determined the target reduction of national carbon dioxide emissions per unit of GDP by 17% by 2015 from 2010 levels. Fourth, pursuant to the commitment made by China at the Copenhagen Climate Summit, China will reduce the intensity of carbon dioxide emissions per unit of GDP in 2020 by 40–45% compared with that of 2005.
Taking these targets for energy conservation, emissions reductions and demands into account, we set the following constraint reduction targets for carbon emissions.
For the first target for carbon emissions reduction, the total carbon emissions remain unchanged, and only the inter-temporal allocation of carbon emissions is altered. For the second target for carbon emissions reduction, to easily test the conclusion drawn by Stern [
9] and conform to the targets in the “Work Plan for Greenhouse Gas Emissions Control during the National 12th Five-Year Period”, we set a reduction of 5% in carbon emissions. The third target for carbon emissions reduction: According to the commitment made by China at the Copenhagen Climate Summit and the goal of a GDP growth rate of up to 7.5% during the national 12th Five-Year Plan Period, we set a reduction of 15% for carbon emissions. For the fourth target for the reduction of carbon emissions, to ascertain the losses in economic growth from the reduction of carbon emissions, we set a reduction of 40% in carbon emissions.
5.3. Measurement of Optimal GDP
According to Equation (7), we can obtain the optimal
y* for each year. Thus, we can calculate the optimal GDP that each province can reach under different reduction targets for carbon emissions by employing the equation
. The measurement results are presented in
Table 4.
By comparing the levels of optimal economic growth under various constraints of carbon emissions in
Table 4, the following conclusions can be reached:
First, if carbon emissions reductions do not occur, and only the resource allocation over the past 21 years is changed, then the following is observed: output0 ≥ sum GDP. In other words, for every province, the optimal GDP would be larger than the actual GDP. The optimal GDP in Guizhou and Shanxi would be twice the actual GDP, which indicates that, in many provinces, considerable room is available for reducing carbon emissions. If carbon emissions are reasonably allocated, then economic growth can be promoted through the effective allocation of resources.
Second, the data in
Table 4 show that output40 ≤ output15 ≤ ouput5 ≤ output0. Carbon emissions act as an output of economic activities; therefore, the reduction targets of carbon emissions inevitably constrain the level of economic activities, thereby resulting in a decrease in total economic output. As a result, a larger reduction of carbon emissions will cause a larger loss of economic growth. If the reduction of carbon emissions were increased from 5% to 15%, then the average loss rate of GDP would be 2.83%. If the reduction of carbon emissions were increased from 15% to 40%, then the average loss rate of GDP would be 18.66%. When only the optimal GDP under various constraints of reduction targets for carbon emissions is considered, and the actual GDP is neglected, if the resources can obtain an effective allocation and the time is substitutable, then a win-win effect between the reduction of carbon emissions and economic growth might not occur, and the Porter hypothesis or the double dividend hypothesis may not be applicable. However, if an efficiency loss occurs because the resources is not effectively allocated, a win-win effect between the reduction of carbon emissions and economic growth should still occur, and the two hypotheses would be suitable in China.
Third, by comparing the optimal and actual GDP, we find that, in most provinces, a dilemma does not occur between the reduction of carbon emissions and economic growth, and the results of these provinces support the Porter hypothesis or the double dividend hypothesis. In other words, a win-win effect occurs between the reduction of carbon emissions and economic growth; thus, a reduction of carbon emissions will contribute to an increase in the GDP. The provinces supporting the two hypotheses are Hebei, Shanxi, Inner Mongolia, Jilin, Heilongjiang, Jiangxi, Shandong, Henan, Hubei, Hunan, Guizhou, Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai, Ningxia, and Xinjiang. The provinces that do not support the two hypotheses are Tianjin, Liaoning, Shanghai, Fujian, Guangdong, and Yunnan. These provinces have obtained an average decrease of 1.45% in potential GDP compared with the actual GDP under a reduction target for carbon emissions of only 5%. The validity of the two hypotheses in certain provinces is related to the target size of the carbon emissions reductions, which applies to the following provinces: Beijing, Jiangsu, Anhui, Guangxi, Hainan, and Sichuan. Except for Hainan, the two hypotheses in all of these provinces is valid under reduction targets for carbon emissions of 5% and 15%. However, when the reduction target for carbon emissions is increased to 40%, the two hypotheses are invalid.
Certain provinces support two hypotheses, while others do not because certain provinces have low environmental efficiency and their energy consumption cannot be effectively utilized, and under the framework of the time substitution DEA model, the GDP’s increasing amplitude caused by the promotion of environmental efficiency exceeds the GDP’s decreasing amplitude caused by resource constraints. Therefore, a win-win effect might occur between the reduction of carbon emissions and economic growth in the Porter hypothesis or the double dividend hypothesis. However, once the resources are effectively utilized, neither an increase in GDP caused by the promotion of environmental efficiency nor a win-win effect between the reduction of carbon emissions and economic growth in the Porter hypothesis or the double dividend hypothesis will occur.
5.4. Measurement of Optimal Carbon Emissions
The optimal carbon emissions
b* of each province can be measured according to Equation (7). The results are shown in
Figure 2.
By comparing the optimal carbon emissions under various limits of carbon emissions reductions and actual carbon emissions for each province, we can draw the following conclusions:
First, to achieve the optimal output, each province must have implemented the carbon emissions reduction policy from 1995 to 2015. This criterion indicates that the implementation of energy conservation and emissions reduction cannot be delayed, and greater economic growth can be completed only by implementing the constraints of carbon emissions reduction over a relatively long period. If the period is too short, then fewer paths will be available to reduce carbon emissions, and the potential optimal output will not be reached.
Second, a comparison of the optimal carbon emissions and actual carbon emissions shows that the actual carbon emissions of several provinces, such as Beijing, are larger than the optimal carbon emissions under a carbon emissions reduction limit of 5% before 2000, however, the findings for the two emissions are reversed after 2000. This finding indicates that optimal carbon emissions are not always uniformly reduced. In addition, based on the time substitution and principle for the inter-temporal allocation of resources, we must fully consider the realities of each province in each year and, thus, guarantee the minimum loss of economic growth.
Third, based on the summarized results for the optimal carbon emissions under different carbon emissions reduction limits, the entirety of each province’s optimal carbon emissions are not equal to the constrained carbon emissions , and certain provinces’ optimal carbon emissions are even smaller than the targets set for carbon emissions. Based on this conclusion, we assume that the optimal carbon emissions in each situation are all smaller than the constrained carbon emissions , and we define the potential carbon emissions reductions of this province will be the largest. If the optimal carbon emissions are in the range of 5% to 15% of the constrained carbon emissions , we then define the potential of this province’s carbon emissions reduction as relatively large. If the optimal carbon emissions are all less than 5% of the constrained carbon emissions, we define the potential carbon emissions reduction of this province as average potential. Finally, if the optimal carbon emissions in each situation are all equal to the constrained carbon emissions , we define the potential carbon emissions reduction of this province as a relatively low potential. Therefore, the following conclusions are drawn:
The province with the largest potential for carbon emissions reduction is Inner Mongolia.
The provinces with a relatively large potential for carbon emissions reduction are Shanxi, Jilin, and Ningxia.
The provinces with an average potential for carbon emissions reduction are Hebei, Jiangsu, Anhui, Jiangxi, Shandong, Henan, Guizhou, and Shaanxi.
The provinces with a relatively low potential for carbon emissions reduction are Beijing, Tianjin, Liaoning, Heilongjiang, Shanghai, Zhejiang, Fujian, Hubei, Hunan, Guangdong, Guangxi, Hainan, Sichuan, Yunnan, Gansu, Qinghai, and Xinjiang.
The provinces with a larger potential for carbon emissions reduction are almost all western provinces, and the provinces with a relatively low potential for carbon emissions reduction are mostly eastern provinces. Wei, Ni, and Du [
16] also find that the eastern region has the least inefficient emissions and the highest marginal abatement costs, and the western region has the largest potential reduction capability and the lowest marginal costs associated with reducing CO
2 emissions. Wang et al. [
64] use the ZSG-DEA model and find that achieving both the emissions intensity reduction and the energy intensity reduction targets will require the provinces of Ningxia, Inner Mongolia, Shanxi, and Qinghai to shoulder heavier burdens of more than 60%; the provinces of Anhui, Jiangxi, Jiangsu, Sichuan, Shaanxi, and Hainan to shoulder comparatively light burdens below 30%; and the remaining Chinese regions to shoulder medium reduction burdens between 30% and 60%.
5.5. Analysis of Influencing Factors for the Potential GDP Loss Rate and Optimal Rate of Carbon Emissions
After obtaining the optimal GDP and optimal carbon emissions via measurements, identifying the influencing factors will provide definite objects for the establishment of carbon emissions reduction targets. For this purpose, we employed a regression analysis to identify the influencing factors of the potential GDP loss rate and optimal rate of carbon emissions.
A number of studies have analyzed the influencing factors of carbon emissions. For example, Wei, Ni, and Du [
16] use the initial income levels, the share of the heavy industry sector in the economy, the share of the tertiary industry in GDP, the share of coal in the total energy, and the share of international trade in GDP to analyze the CO
2 abatement potential. Additionally, Wei, Ni, and Du [
16] use the per capita GDP, energy consumption structure, industry structure, urbanization level, technology progress, and trade openness to analyze the forecasting CO
2 emissions. Many studies focused on the influencing factors of carbon emissions and optimal GDP have drawn on the STIRPAT equation proposed by York et al. [
65]. The equation indicates that carbon emissions are primarily influenced by environmental pressure, population size, the degree of affluence, and the technology level. Depending on the equation, this paper replaces the technology level with environmental efficiency, the degree of affluence with per capita GDP, population size with the population in each province, and environmental pressure with energy intensity. Thus, the following regression model is proposed:
where
LGDP represents the potential economic growth rate of loss, wherein
;
SumGDP represents the sum of the actual GDP;
Output represents the optimal output, and the ratio between them represents the potential GDP loss rate, wherein a larger ratio may represent a larger relative optimal output of the actual GDP and larger actual GDP loss rate;
represents the growth rate of optimal carbon emissions, wherein
and
represent the optimal carbon emissions under the condition of optimal output. CO
2 represents the actual carbon emissions, and larger values of
indicate that more CO
2 should be exhausted based on the original actual carbon emissions if the optimal output is reached;
represents per capita GDP;
P represents the total population scale;
EG represents energy intensity, which is found by dividing the total amount of energy consumption by the total GDP;
represents the technology efficiency value;
i represents the province;
t represents the year; we also control time effects;
represents the coefficient term; and
represents the residual term. This paper employs the fixed effect model of panel data to test the influences of the above factors on the optimal output and optimal carbon emissions. Firstly, we use variance inflation factors (VIFs) to test for multicollinearity and find that the VIF value between all independent variables is less than 2; therefore, multicollinearity is not observed. We then use the Hausman test to determine whether to use a fixed effects model or random effects model. Based on the Hausman test result, we select the fixed effects model to conduct the analysis. To rule out the heteroscedasticity, we also use White-Huber robust standard errors fixed-effects estimator. The regression results are shown in
Table 5:
Table 5 shows the influences of different factors on the optimal GDP loss and the optimal rate of carbon emissions.
(1) Environmental efficiency. Most previous studies have neglected the influence of environmental efficiency on carbon emissions; however, this type of variable has been added into the analysis in this paper. As shown in
Table 5, environmental efficiency has a significantly positive influence on the potential optimal GDP, the potential loss rate and the optimal rate of carbon emissions. This conclusion explains why the win-win effect of the Porter hypothesis or the double dividend hypothesis could occur in certain provinces but not in others. Higher environmental efficiency can contribute to higher resource utilization efficiency. In this case, if certain constraints of carbon emissions reductions are provided, then additional GDP losses will not occur. In addition, higher environmental efficiency associated with reaching the optimal output under the foregoing condition corresponds to a greater amount of carbon emissions because of the higher energy resource utilization and higher the optimal carbon emissions. If more energy resources are input during the years with lower environmental efficiency, then the carbon emissions will not be fully utilized, and low utilization efficiency will inevitably result in a failure to reach the optimal GDP output.
(2) Per capita GDP. Although per capita GDP significantly increases the potential optimal GDP loss rate, it significantly decreases the optimal carbon emissions. This conclusion indicates that provinces with a higher per capita GDP will incur greater GDP losses once the constraints of carbon emissions reductions are implemented. Therefore, to achieve the potential optimal GDP, provinces with a higher per capita GDP should reduce carbon emissions smaller than those provinces that have higher living standards and demands for energy; therefore, the constraints for carbon emissions reductions will cause a larger output decrease compared with provinces with a lower per capita GDP (to some extent). Similarly, provinces with a higher per capita GDP will generally have larger energy demands; therefore, the amount of the carbon emissions that can be reduced will not be large.
(3) Population. The population scale significantly reduces the potential optimal GDP loss rate and significantly enlarges the optimal carbon emissions. This conclusion indicates that provinces with larger population scales will obtain smaller GDP losses when certain constraints of carbon emissions reductions are provided and, accordingly, more carbon emissions on an original basis are required. Moreover, in a given region, a greater population may correspond to the increased production of carbon emissions to meet the demand of economic activities. In general, provinces with a larger population are also large energy consumers. Furthermore, provinces with a low level of economic development often have relatively low resource utility efficiency. In this case, greater carbon emissions reductions can be achieved, and a lower GDP loss rate may occur under the constraints of carbon emissions reductions. In addition, because provinces with larger population scales and higher energy consumption have relatively large carbon emissions, their ability to reduce carbon emissions and achieve optimal carbon emissions will be considerable.
(4) Energy intensity. Energy intensity significantly reduces the potential optimal GDP loss rate but has a non-significant influence on optimal carbon emissions, which is likely because the provinces with higher energy intensity have relatively high energy consumption per unit GDP, thereby resulting in relatively low energy utilization efficiency. In addition, the provinces in China with higher energy intensity generally have relatively high energy consumption, which results in large carbon emissions, low technical environmental efficiency, and a considerable ability to reduce carbon emissions.
These findings summarizing the foregoing analysis provide decision-makers with suggestions for setting reduction targets for carbon emissions. Decision-makers should set higher reduction targets for carbon emissions in provinces with lower environmental efficiency, smaller per capita GDP, larger population scales, and higher energy intensity. These findings indicate that the realities of each province should be considered when setting reduction targets for carbon emissions. Considering that provinces have different environmental efficiency levels, per capita GDPs, and population scales, a uniform reduction target for carbon emissions would require certain provinces to incur relatively large losses in economic growth when implementing carbon emissions reduction policies.
Finally, to ensure that our results are robust to model selection, we conduct several robustness checks. We find that the model showed heteroscedasticity, serial correlation, and cross-sectional dependence. In the case of heteroscedasticity, serial correlation, and cross-sectional dependence, the fixed-effects model estimator is biased. In order to obtain unbiased estimators, we use panel-corrected standard error (PCSE) estimators (a panel-corrected when the errors are assumed to be contemporaneously correlated and panel heteroscedastic) as suggested by Beck and Katz [
66]. For a better comparison, Driscoll and Kraay [
67] standard errors for coefficients estimated by fixed-effects (within) regression is utilized. The Driscoll and Kraay [
67] standard errors are robust to disturbances being heteroscedastic, autocorrelated, and cross-sectionally dependent. The results are shown in
Table 6 and
Table 7.
As we can see in
Table 6 and
Table 7, comparing to
Table 5, although the significance level of some coefficients, such as PGDP in
Table 6 with the Driscoll-Kraay estimator is decreasing, but the main results still remain consistent, so we could say with strong evidence the results show that the choice of the estimation methods does not affect the robustness of our results. Our results can rule out the heteroscedasticity, serial correlation, and cross-sectional independence.