Next Article in Journal
Equity Return Dispersion and Stock Market Volatility: Evidence from Multivariate Linear and Nonlinear Causality Tests
Next Article in Special Issue
Comparative Analysis of the Energy Sector Development Trends and Forecast of Final Energy Demand in the Baltic States
Previous Article in Journal
A Vulnerability Assessment of Urban Emergency in Schools of Shanghai
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Economic and Efficiency Analysis of China Electricity Market Reform Using Computable General Equilibrium Model

1
School of Information, Beijing Wuzi University, Beijing 101149, China
2
School of Economic and Management, North China Electric Power University, Beijing 102206, China
3
DongGuan Power Supply Bureau, GuangDong Power Grid Corp., DongGuan 523008, China
4
Lithuanian Institute of Agrarian Economics, Vilnius 01113, Lithuania
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2019, 11(2), 350; https://doi.org/10.3390/su11020350
Submission received: 4 December 2018 / Revised: 27 December 2018 / Accepted: 3 January 2019 / Published: 11 January 2019
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Sustainable Energy Economics and Policy)

Abstract

:
China’s electricity industry has been undergoing a process of regulatory reform. This study aims to analyse the impact of liberalization on the electricity market assuming different degrees of scope of the reforms by applying a computable general equilibrium (CGE) model. In this paper, we consider the three sub-sectors of the electricity industry, namely generation, transmission and distribution. We assume that the reform will phase out the entry barriers on the generation side and allow for competition on the distribution side, while keeping the transmission side under regulation. The results showed that the reform could enhance efficiency in the electricity sector and reduce energy prices for households. Introduction of a complete competition model would decrease welfare by 5.394 billion yuan, if contrasted to a limited competition model. The composite energy price would decline under both scenarios, whereas the quantity of energy consumed by the households would go up. This research, thus, contributes to literature on the economic effects of China’s electric power market reform, and can be used as a case study to support policy decisions for the decision-makers.

1. Introduction

Being an important basic industry for national economic development, the electric power industry acts as a strong natural monopoly. This mode of operation lacks competitive pressure and may induce a lower level of the operation efficiency. In order to move away from the monopolistic electricity market structure towards a more competitive one, various countries have embarked on electricity market reforms introducing competitiveness there. The objectives of climate change mitigation have also played a role in shaping the energy policy [1,2,3,4,5,6]. China’s electric power industry reform began in 1985 and has gone through the three stages: Fund collection for electricity, separating the functions of the government from those of enterprises, and introduction of competition in the power generation industry [7,8]. In March 2015, the State Council of People’s Republic of China released Opinions Regarding the Deepening of the Power Sector’s Reform (Document No. 9). The document put forward a power industry reform structure of “regulating the middle, opening both ends", which marks a new stage of the market-oriented reform of China’s electric power industry.
Regulating the middle means that the profit of the power grid no longer depends on the difference purchase and sale price of the electricity but rather to charge for transmission and distribution. The price of transmission and distribution is approved by the government so that it covers grid operation costs and generates a reasonable profit margin. Therefore, the pricing system introduced during the reform ensures the profit of power grid enterprises. However, state control is required to eliminate unreasonable costs. Opening both ends means that power generation enterprises and power retailing enterprises are allowed to enter the market and facilitate direct transactions with power consumers. Through competition, the enterprises determine the quantity and price of electricity.
Given the trend of economic growth in China, the annual rate of growth in electricity consumption was 3.61% in 2013–2016, while the annual growth of the installed capacity (the total amount of power available from generating units) was 9.69%, i.e., the growth in generation capacity (the amount of the power produced by generating units) was much faster than the growth of social demand for electricity (see Figure 1). At the same time, the utilisation hours of thermal power units have been reduced from 5012 h to 4165 h. Under the effect of a market price competition mechanism, the direct transaction price between power generation enterprises and power users naturally tends to decline.
China’s electricity retail industry has developed rapidly since the promulgation of Document No. 9 of the electric power reform (see Figure 2). As of March 2017, more than 6000 electric power sales companies have been established nationwide. This has affected previously monopolistic power transmission, distribution and retail sectors. According to the 13th Five-Year Plan for Electric Power Development, the establishment of power trading institutions was completed by the end of 2016 and the cultivation of market competition subjects on the selling side will be completed by the end of 2018. In the retail electricity market, 35 kW and above users are free to choose their retailer in 1 to 3 years after 2018, 10 kW and above users will be able to do so in the next 5–10 years. This suggests the scale of the electricity trade in the competitive market will continue to expand in China. The schedule of electricity market liberalization in China is shown in Table 1.
The electricity market liberalization in China is likely to pose multifaceted consequences for both power producers and consumers. Therefore, it is important to identify the major effects and their implications. In this paper, we assess the potential impacts of electric power market reform in China by employing the CGE model. The novelty of this paper is that we consider subsectors of the electricity sector (generation, transmission, distribution and retail) rather than the electricity sector as a whole. This kind of analysis allows one to obtain more detailed insights into the effects of the electricity market liberalization in China for different agents.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes the relevant literature. Section 3 constructs the CGE model for Chinese economy and electricity sector. Section 4 presents assumptions and results associated with the simulations. Section 5 proceeds with the discussion of the policy implications stemming from results of the modelling.

2. Literature Review

Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models can be applied to measure sector- and economy-wide effects of (shifts in) regulation and the economic situation in general. The theoretical foundation of the CGE model rests on the Warlas’s general equilibrium theory, which describes a cyclical economic process as follows: Production generates income, income triggers demand, demand further induces production and the quantities and prices of goods marketed vary until demand and supply are balanced in the economic system (i.e., equilibrium is reached). The model originates from the 1960s and has been widely applied in the areas of global trade [9,10], environmental protection [11,12], economic policy reform [13] and tax reform [14].
Indeed, the CGE models can also focus on the energy sector and thus quantify the effects of external and internal factors there. Scaramucci et al. [15] used a CEG model to estimate the economic impacts of constraining the supply of electric energy in Brazil. Hosoe [16] simulated the liberalization of electricity market in Japan with a CGE model. Akkemik and Oguz [17] examined potential outcomes of full liberalization policy on efficiency and competition in the Turkish electricity market by means of an applied computable general equilibrium model and the counter-factual simulation. Rodrigues and Linares [18,19] used a CGE model to assess the impacts of a Demand Response program in the Spanish electricity market. Hwang and Lee [20] looked into the shifts within the Korean electricity market by using a CGE model. Farajzadeh and Bakhshoodeh [21] analysed economic and environmental consequences of the phasing out of energy subsidies in Iran by employing a CGE model. Capros et al. [22] focused on the macroeconomic and sector-level effects induced by changes in electricity and gas prices in the EU by means of a CGE model. Bataille and Melton [23] applied a CGE model to estimate the impacts of energy efficiency improvements in Canada by considering indicators related to GDP, employment, economic structure for the period of 2002-2012. Melnikov et al. [24] applied the dynamic CGE model to appraise the effects of carbon taxes on household consumption and carbon emissions. Mu et al. [25] modelled the possible reductions in global greenhouse gas emission following the Paris Agreement by means of a CGE model. Therefore, the applications of CGE models are versatile in terms of geographical area, level of aggregation, and factors covered.
Due to the reform of China’s economic system and the lack of statistical data, the studies applying a general equilibrium model appeared at a relatively late stage in China. However, there have been recent applications of CGE models for Chinese economy. Liu et al. [26] applied an environmentally extended CGE model to assess environmental and economic impacts of the new emission standard for thermal power plants. Li et al. [27] construct a dynamic CGE model to explore the impacts of EVs and CCS respectively on China’s economics, environmental quality and energy demand based on the six simulation scenarios. Zhang et al. [28] applied CGE and a social accounting matrix for 2012 to analyse the impacts of the natural gas industry reform in China. Zhang et al. [29] utilized CGE models to assess the outcomes of the inclusion of different fuel types (shale gas and non-grain bioethanol) in the energy-mix. Liu et al. [30] employed a CGE methodology to quantify the outcomes of implementation of the fuel economy requirements for vehicles in China in the sense of economy and environment. Similarly, the effects on the different dimensions of sustainability arising due to the possible expansion of the bioethanol production were analysed by Ge and Lei [31] via CGE modelling. Xiao et al. [32] proposed a modified CGE model for China incorporating risk analysis for identifying the prospective pathways for promotion of the renewables. Liu and Zhou [33] applied a CGE model to explore the impact of a 5% ad valorem coal resource tax on the Chinese economy under four scenarios involving distinguished electricity pricing mechanisms and a tax revenue recycling scheme by deducting consumption tax.
However, the applications of CGE modelling on Chinese power sector are rather limited. Yang and Cui [34] established a CGE model with 39 sectors which subdivides the power sector into coal-fired, hydropower, nuclear, gas-fired and oil-fired generation. The model was applied to analyse the impact of replacing coal-fired power generation technology with gas-fired power generation technology on the economy, power generation and pollutant emissions in China. Zhang [35] analysed the linkages between electricity price and industrial structure in China by means of a CGE model. The results showed that though the impact of price changes on the output was very low across industries, the ones featuring higher electricity consumption appeared to be more sensitive to changes in electricity price. Tan et al. [36] constructed a CGE model to analyse the impacts of exchange rate change on electric power industry. Following the declines in the exchange rate of RMB by 1% and 3%, both industrial and household electricity consumption is expected to go down, with a more important impact on the electricity-intensive sectors. He et al. [37] set up a CGE model to analyse the impacts of changes in coal price on the electric power industry and the impacts of adjustments in electricity price on the macro-economic situation in China. The latter study showed the electricity price increase exerts an adverse influence on the total output, GDP, and the CPI. Song and Cui [38] employed a dynamic CGE model for China (CDECGE) to quantify the effects of the electricity market reform in China. The results showed that reform is likely to be desirable in the sense of the targets regarding energy savings and mitigation of carbon emissions.
However, the abovementioned studies only discussed the impact of electricity price change without breaking down the electricity industry into sub-sectors to discuss the impact of deregulation on different parts of the power supply chain. The latter issue is particularly important when assessing the outcomes of the different stages of the electricity market reform that are likely to have different impacts on different sub-sectors. We address this literature gap by estimating the potential impacts of electricity market reform by employing a more detailed CGE model.
In order to analyse the impacts of liberalization on the industries with respect to different scopes of the electricity market reform, we set up an electricity and economy CGE model. Contrasted with the earlier literature, we break down the electricity sector into the three sub-sectors (generation, transmission and distribution) in this study. It should be noted that, under the complete competition model, the power sector should be divided into four sub-sectors: power generation, transmission, distribution and retail sales. Due to the lack of relevant data on the retail sale side, it is assumed that the distribution and retail sale of electricity will comprise an integral part of the market.
The present study, therefore, contributes to literature in a number of ways. First, the impacts of electricity regulatory reforms in China are assessed. This provides a piece of evidence on the economic effects of such reforms. These findings might be important when shaping regulatory reforms in different countries. Second, the application of a CGE model offers a contribution to literature on economic modelling and identifies possible directions for further research in the area both in China and internationally. Third, the application of a CGE model in the case of electricity market reform might provide guidelines for similar applications in other sectors and regions.

3. The CGE Model for Chinese Electricity and Economy Sector

In this section, we set up a CGE model for the analysis of the deregulation of China’s electricity market. We briefly discuss the major constructing modules of the model. The linkages among the different modules are also discussed.

3.1. Production Module

The production module describes the transformation of inputs into output, i.e. the process of domestic production. Figure 3 shows the structure of the production side. In CGE models, the Cobb-Douglas production function, Leontief production function and the constant elasticity of substitution (CES) type production function are commonly used.
In this paper, we assumed a CES type function for modelling the productive technology, and the level of output of each sector was determined to ensure market equilibrium. The model basically covered the five levels. At each level, the degree of substitution was defined via the elasticity of substitution. At the highest level of aggregation, we considered (substitutability between) composite energy-related input and composite non-energy input, thus modelling substitutability among energy and non-energy inputs. For the energy production sectors, such as coal, OG (Oil and gas) and electricity generation, we assumed that the energy intermediate inputs cannot be replaced, and the energy intermediate inputs were free to be replaced for the other sectors. As for the factor market, we assumed that capital and labour can replace each other in the capital market when the relative factor prices change. We further assumed that capital is fixed in all industries, whereas labour is completely mobile across sectors. In addition, we assumed that each activity produces one commodity and lower-case indexes a and c denote activities and commodities, respectively. Please refer to Table 2, Table 3, Table 4, Table 5, Table 6, Table 7, Table 8, Table 9, Table 10 and Table 11 for the notations of variables and parameters used in the model.
At the first level, the gross output QA was modelled as a CES function of capital-energy-labour composite input (Equations (1)–(3)) and non-energy intermediate input (Equations (4) and (5)) with the latter input being defined in terms of Leontief input-output relations. The characteristic of the Leontief function is zero elasticity of substitution between intermediate inputs which implies the input coefficient is fixed.
Q A a = α a A ( δ a A Q K E L a ρ A + ( 1 δ a A ) Q N D a ρ A ) 1 ρ A
P K E L a P N D a = δ a A 1 δ a A ( Q N D a Q K E L a ) 1 ρ A
P A a Q A a = P K E L a Q K E L a + P N D a Q N D a
U N D c , a = α c , a N D a
P N D a = c α c , a P Q c
At the lower level of aggregation, the capital-energy-labour composite input is specified by a CES function of labour and capital-energy composite inputs (Equations (6)–(8)):
Q K E L a = α a K E L ( δ a K E L Q K E a ρ K E L + ( 1 δ a K E L ) Q L a ρ K E L ) 1 ρ K E L
P K E a P L a = δ a K E L 1 δ a K E L ( Q L a Q K E a ) 1 ρ K E L
P K E L a Q K E L a = P K E a Q K E a + P L a Q L a
At the bottom three levels, we distinguished the capital-energy composite inputs (Equations (9)–(11)), energy composite inputs (Equations (12)–(14)) and non-electricity composite inputs (Equations (15)–(17)) by CES functions:
Q K E a = α a K E ( δ a K E Q K a ρ K E + ( 1 δ a K E ) Q E C a ρ K E ) 1 ρ K E
P K a P E C a = δ a K E 1 δ a K E ( Q E C a Q K a ) 1 ρ K E
P K E a Q K E a = P K a Q K a + P E C a Q E C a
Q E C a = α a E C ( δ a E C Q E L E C N a ρ E C + ( 1 δ a E C ) Q E L E C a ρ E C ) 1 ρ E C
P E L E C N a P E L E C a = δ a E C 1 δ a E C ( Q E L E C a Q E L E C N a ) 1 ρ E C
P E C a Q E C a = P E L E C N a Q E L E C N a + P E L E C a Q E L E C a
Q E L E C N a = α a E L E C N ( δ a E L E C N Q O G a ρ E L E C N + ( 1 δ a E L E C N ) Q C O A L a ρ E L E C N ) 1 ρ E L E C N
P O G a P C O A L a = δ a E L E C N 1 δ a E L E C N ( Q C O A L a Q O G a ) 1 ρ E L E C N
P E L E C N a Q E L E C N a = P O G a Q O G a + P C O A L a Q C O A L a
Although this paper divides the electric power industry into three sub-sectors–power generation, transmission and distribution–the three sub-sectors follow vertically integrated structure and there was no substitution relationship for the electricity composite functions. That is, the total output of the power sector is the total output of the power generation sector, which will be delivered to the end user through the transmission and distribution network. The specific equations will be given in Section 4.3. Table 2 and Table 3 present the variables and parameters of the production model, respectively.

3.2. Trade Module

The CGE model assumes that China acts as a “small country”, i.e., the world prices are exogenously determined. Equations (18) and (19) define the domestic imports and exports prices, respectively:
P E a = p w e a E X R
P M c = p w m c E X R
The trade module covers three categories of goods: Domestic output to exports (QE), domestic output to domestic market (QD) and imports supply to the domestic market (QM). The total output of domestic production (QA) is composed of QE and QD, while domestic market demand (QQ) is composed of QM and QD, the specific relationship is shown in Figure 4.
In order to maximize profit, the domestic commodity producers optimize the combination of QE and QD. Specifically, the assignment of the output for domestic and export markets is described by the constant elasticity of transformation (CET) functions (Equations (20)–(22)):
Q A a = α a q a ( δ a q a Q D a ρ q a + ( 1 δ a q a ) Q E a ρ q a ) 1 / ρ q a
P D a P E a = δ a q a 1 δ a q a ( Q E a Q D a ) 1 ρ q a
P A a Q A a = P D a Q D a + P E a Q E a
Similarly, while purchasing goods, consumers seek to optimize the combination of domestic and imported goods. Specifically, the assignment of expenditures for the latter two categories of goods is described by the CES function (Equations (23)–(25)), known as the Armington function:
Q Q c = α c q q ( δ c q q Q D c ρ q q + ( 1 δ c q q ) Q M c ρ c q q ) 1 ρ q q
P D c P M c = δ c q q 1 δ c q q ( Q M c Q D c ) 1 ρ q q
P Q c Q Q c = P D c Q D c + P M c Q M c
Please see Table 4 and Table 5 for the variables and parameters for the trade module, respectively.

3.3. Income Module

The income generated in production is allocated across three main institutions: Households, enterprises and government. The income of households is mainly composed of labour income, investment income and transfer payments. Table 6 and Table 7 present the variables and parameters for the income module, respectively. In the paper, we followed the assumption that all the transfers among the rest of the world and government, enterprise and related factors are fixed sums expressed in foreign currency, whereas other transfer payments are defined as fixed proportions of income:
Y H = P L Q L + P K Q K s h i f h + t r a n s f r h , g o v + t r a n s f r h , e n t + t r a n s f r h , r o w
The government collects taxes and receives transfers from the rest of the world. Tax revenue consists of individual income tax, export tax, import tax, the enterprise income tax and production tax.
Y G = t i h Y H + M T A X + E T A X + A T A X + t i e n t Y E + t r a n s f r g o v , r o w
The capital income of enterprises is defined as:
Y E = W K Q K s h i f e n t

3.4. Expenditure Module

Following Equation (29), households allocate disposable income for consumption and savings, where savings are defined as a fixed share of income. The government revenue is mainly used for transfer payments, commodity consumption and government savings. Government transfer payments to households and enterprises are defined as a fixed proportion of income, while the proportion of government consumption on goods ( Q G ¯ c ) is fixed (Equations (30) and (31)). Enterprise income is allocated to taxes, savings, and transfers to the households (Equations (32) and (33)). The variables and parameters used in the consumption module are presented in Table 8 and Table 9, respectively.
E H = ( 1 t i h ) Y H H S A V = ( 1 m p s h ) ( 1 t i h ) Y H
E G = c Q G c P Q c + t r a n s f r h , g o v + t r a n s f r r o w , g o v
Y G = E G + G S A V
E E = t i e n t Y E + t r a n s f r h , e n t
Y E = E E + E S A V

3.5. Macroeconomic Closure

Macroeconomic Closure is a special structure formed on the basis of macroeconomic theory, including the choice of function types, the setting of endogenous and exogenous variables. Different types of closure are referred to given the corresponding macroeconomic theories. The paper adopts the neoclassical macro closure conditions which corresponds to China’s economic development mode. The associated variables are presented in Table 10.
The CGE model considered the four macroeconomic balances: The factor market balance, the commodity market balance, the current-account balance and the savings-investment balance. In the factor markets, equilibrium requires full employment of the labour force and full utilisation of capital, i.e., the aggregate demand of is equal to the total supply of each sector. Furthermore, the supply variable QLS and QKS are assumed to be fixed:
a Q L a = Q L S
a Q K a = Q K S
In the commodity market, Equation (36) implies that the aggregate demand is equal to the aggregate supply. Among the elements of the aggregate supply, the quantity of investment ( Q I N V c ¯ ) is exogenous:
Q Q c = a Q I N T c , a + Q H c + Q I N V c + Q G c + q u s t o c
In current-account balance (Equation (37)), we chose such a closure rule that the exchange rate (EXR) was treated as an endogenous variable, while foreign savings enters the model as an exogenous variable ( F S A V ¯ ):
c p w m c Q M c + t r a n s f r r o w , f + t r a n s f r r o w , g o v = c p w e c Q E c + t r a n s f r h , r o w + t r a n s f r g o v , r o w + F S A V .
Equation (38) states that total saving and total investment have to be equal. In order to maintain the equality between the variables and equations, we added variable WALRAS to Equation (38). The solution value of WALRAS should be zero. Besides, we include Equation (39) in the model to analyse the impact of policy changes on GDP.
H S A V + G S A V + F S A V E X R + E S A V = = c P Q c Q I N V c + c P Q c q u s t o c + W A L R A S .
G D P = c P Q c ( Q H c + Q G c + Q I N V c + q u s t o c ) + c P E c Q E c c p w m c E X R Q M c .

3.6. Welfare Block

Analysis of the effects of public policy on social welfare can be based on multiple different indicators. Among these, Hicksian equivalent variation is rather common. In this paper, we considered Hicksian equivalent variation as a measure of the effect of the external policy on the households’ social welfare. In Equation (40), EV greater than zero implies that the implementation of policies enhanced the welfare of households:
E V = a P Q a o ( Q H a Q H a o )
Please see Table 11 for the variables used in the welfare module.

4. Policy Simulation

This section presents the basic assumptions for different scenarios defining electricity market liberalisation in China. The results of the simulation are then presented. The effects on different agents and sectors are discussed.

4.1. Social Accounting Matrix

Social accounting matrix (SAM) was the basic data set underlying the CGE model. It represents the system of national accounts in matrix form. The SAM applied in this paper was based on the 2012 input-output tables for China which were issued by the National Bureau of Statistics in 2016. The other data for the SAM came from China’s Statistical Yearbook, China’s Fiscal Yearbook, China’s Electric Power Yearbook, China’s Tax Yearbook, and China’s Customs Statistical Yearbook. According to the needs of the research, we reorganized the 42 sectors in the input-output tables into 11 sectors (see Table 12). In addition, the institutional accounts included government, enterprises, a representative household, and the factor accounts including capital and labour in the micro-SAM. The main purpose of this paper is to simulate the impact of liberalisation of electricity market, so there is no further disaggregation of household accounts.
Due to the lack of data availability, the initial SAM did not balance the sums of rows and columns. The two approaches are often applied to circumvent this issue (the RAS method and cross-entropy method). In this paper, we applied the cross-entropy method to balance the SAM. Table 13 presents the macro-SAM for 2012.
The electricity sector in CGE model is divided into three sectors: Power generation, transmission and distribution. Note that the latest I-O table contains only the relevant data of electricity, heat production and supply. Therefore, we needed to decompose the data for power sector when compiling the micro-SAM table.
First of all, compared with the production and supply of electric power, the production and supply of heat is a very small sector. Accordingly, we did not decompose the relevant variables, but directly use them to describe the production and supply of electric power. Secondly, we built our model on the assumption that the transmission sector takes the output of the power sector as the sole intermediate input, and the distribution sector, in turn, receives the output of the transmission sector as the only input (Akkenik, Oguz, 2011). The output of the distribution sector is then electricity sales to the end-users.

4.2. Parameter Calibration

The CGE model involved two kinds of parameters: Some could be calibrated by applying production functions (Section 3.1) and basic data, while the others had to be determined exogenously. The latter parameters contained the share parameter, scale parameter, tax rate and transfer payments. The former parameters contained the production factors substitution elasticity, Armington elasticity, and CES elasticity. The parameters can be acquired by econometric methods or literature research. Based on the earlier literature [39,40] and making appropriate adjustments, we obtained the parameter values used in this paper (Table 14).

4.3. Counter-Factual Scenarios

Opinions Regarding the Deepening of the Power Sector’s Reform pointed out that the reform should maintain a relatively stable electricity price for households, agriculture and public utilities. We carried out two kinds of simulations, assuming different scenarios for the scope of the reform of the Chinese electric power market. In Simulation 1, the scope of the market liberalization was restricted to the industrial and commercial users (except for agriculture and public utilities); we refer to this setting as the limited competition model. In China, the electricity price for households is not based on the underlying cost level and, thus, involves serious cross-subsidization. In order to maintain a stable level of electricity price for households, we assumed the electricity prices of households, agriculture and public utilities are kept at the pre-reform level which is different from the earlier literature. During such deregulation of the market, the cross-subsidization and the special funds must be maintained for adjusting the transmission electricity price, i.e., partial regulation remains in effect. In Simulation 2, we assumed the liberalisation is fully accomplished by eliminating regulation and introducing deregulation to all users, including intermediate users and end users (i.e., households); we refer to this setting as the complete competition model. Although Simulation 2 is inconsistent with the current reform framework, the simulation results can be used as a reference for further considerations.
For the power sector, there are the following conventions:
(1)
In the production module, there is no substitutability among the three sub-sectors of power generation, transmission and distribution. The total output of the power sector is the total output of the power generation sector.
(2)
In the trade module, the import and export of the electric power takes place in the power distribution sector, and the residents will purchase electricity from the power distribution sector. The trade function of the electricity sector is governed by Equations (18)–(25).
(3)
The production price of electricity in the distribution sector (PAelec-d) is determined by the commodity prices of the generation (PAelec-g) and transmission sectors (PAelec-t):
P Q e l e c - g + P Q e l e c - t = P A e l e c - d
According to different reform scenarios, this paper simulated the deregulation of power generation and distribution, analyses the effects of electric power market reform on the economic efficiency of power enterprises and discusses the changes of input and output on the user side caused by the price fluctuations. In this model, the return on investment in the generation and distribution sectors was assumed to be zero as an exogenous shock, and the return on investment in the transmission sector was maintained at the base level.
For the power transmission sector, the following relationship holds:
P Q e l e c - t = ( 1 + m a r k u p ) P Q e l e c - t
where markup represents the level of sectoral returns with the base period return of the transmission sector being 10%.
The introduction of competition in the power generation and distribution sectors has exerted shocks on the market equilibrium. According to the general equilibrium theory, the whole economy will approach another market equilibrium which will have an impact on the factor prices (including energy prices) and households’ welfare. GAMS software was used to solve the CGE problem. The macroeconomic and microeconomic changes under two simulated situations are shown in Table 15, Table 16 and Table 17. The detailed discussion proceeds in the following sub-sections.

4.4. Macroeconomic Effect Analysis

According to the general equilibrium theory, the model redistributes the existing resources to various sectors of the market economy to meet supply and demand through inter-sectoral transactions. To put it otherwise, economic entities maintain the market balance through re-allocation of resources. Therefore, the inefficiency of the power sector (X-inefficient behaviour) can be effectively eliminated through competition. As labour can move among the sectors, the deepening of electricity market reform might increase the labour income of residents by 0.024% and 0.018% (see Table 15, line 8) for limited and full competition scenarios respectively. In addition to the increase in labour income, capital gains would also increase which indicates increase in residents’ income by 0.037% and 0.031% (see Table 15, line 5) depending on the degree of market liberalisation. The increase in income affects the demand of residents which is reflected by the increase in consumption.
GDP growth of 0.612% and 0.441% (see Table 15, line 3) indicates the positive impact of electricity price decline with regards to consumption by industry, government and households in both scenarios. According to the principle of the market equilibrium, the following reasons behind the GDP growth can be identified. First, considering the supply side, the drop in electricity price induces the substitution of electricity for other energy sources, which leads to the redistribution of resources through inter-sectoral transactions and more efficient use of factor inputs (labour, capital, energy and non-energy intermediate inputs). On the demand side, the increase of residents’ income which is caused by the increase of real wages and the real capital gains results in an increasing aggregate demand (Akkemik, Oguz, 2011). According to the balance condition, the increasing aggregate demand induces expansion of the total output, which is quantified by GDP.
Under different market liberalisation settings, social welfare increases by 7.710 billion RMB and 2.316 billion RMB (see Table 15, line 4). Note that the distribution of income between capital and labour remains unchanged in the hypothesis of the factor market. Because of the positive impact of deregulation on the factor prices, the revenue of government and enterprises has increased (see Table 15, line 6, line 7).
Comparing the outcomes of the two scenarios (i.e. different columns in Table 15), suggests that the social welfare under the limited competition would be higher than that under complete competition. In addition, due to the serious cross-subsidies of electricity prices for residents, agriculture and public utilities, the abolition of their protection will lead to the rise of electricity prices in the related industries. Accordingly, the price of energy-consuming composite products in the complete competition model is 7.287% (see Table 15, line 1) higher than that in the limited competition model. Thus, the quantity of consumer energy composite products is 1.54% (see Table 15, line 2) lower if compared to the limited competition model.
In summary, the price of residential consumer energy products would decline under the two simulation scenarios, while the consumption of energy products and GDP would go up to different extents. Thus, the new power market policy can bring positive effects and meet the objectives of the reform.

4.5. Macroeconomic Effect Analysis

4.5.1. Input-Output Analysis

In the first columns of Table 16 and Table 17, we show the changes in sectoral total output under the limited competition model and complete competition model. One can note the output of the power sector could improve at different extents (1.84% and 2.72%, see Table 16 and Table 17, line 5, column 1) depending on the scenario. Because the incentive effect of complete competition model on electric power enterprises is greater than that of limited competition model, the output is 0.88% higher than that under the limited competition. However, the increase in the output of the power sector has a negative impact on the total output of other energy sectors (such as coal, oil and gas). Under the limited competition, the outputs of coal and oil and gas sectors decrease by 2.04% and 1.29% (see Table 16, line 2, 3, column 1) respectively, whereas under the complete competition mode the outputs decrease by 0.73% and 0.08% (see Table 17, line 2, 3, column 1) respectively. This shows that the new policy is to change the structure of the energy-mix and increase the possibility of substituting electricity for other energy sources which is in line with the 13th Five-Year Plan as well as the core idea of energy revolution. Besides the power sector, the increase in total output is mainly concentrated in energy intensive industries such as mining and manufacturing which rely on electricity as a major input.
However, the output of agriculture and public utilities showed different trends under the two scenarios. Under the limited competition scenario, the outputs of both sectors increase, while under the complete competition model the outputs of both sectors go down to a substantial extent. This is mainly due to the fact that in the first scenario, the electricity prices for agriculture and utilities remain at the same level, which is much lower than the level of electricity price under the complete competition. The increase in electricity price leads to a decrease in the outputs of the two sectors.
The efficiency of the generation sector can be measured by considering the reduction in the intermediate input. From Table 16 and Table 17, one can observe that the efficiency growth rate of the generation sector is about 1.08% and 1.15%. According to the equilibrium theory, the improvement in efficiency is due to the withdrawal of inefficient employees and the entry of new more efficient companies. The increase in output will inevitably lead to the increase of the intermediate input of the transmission and distribution sectors, which is 1.84% and 2.72%, respectively, under the limited competition model and the complete competition model. It is assumed that there is no energy substitution in the energy production sector. Thus, the decrease in the output of the fossil energy sector (coal, oil and gas), renders a proportional decrease in the intermediate input. For agriculture and public utilities, electricity prices and sector outputs are quite different under the two simulation scenarios, which also leads to higher differences in the intermediate inputs. Under the limited competition model, due to the electricity price protection policy, the electricity price is lower than the market price. This renders lower value of the intermediate input and higher output. However, in the compete competition model, the protection of electricity price vanishes and the intermediate input increases with the output decreasing.

4.5.2. Commodity Prices and Consumption

The liberalisation of the power distribution sector brings about changes in the price system of the market economy. The CGE model can approximate the resulting output commodity prices for each sector under the market equilibrium conditions based on the price equilibrium mechanism. Under the limited competition model, the supply price of the power generation sector drops by 6.80% (see Table 16, line 5, column 4), and the supply price of the electricity sales sector decreases by 9.61% (see Table 16, line 7, column 4). The reason behind the decline in the price of electricity supply is the increase in production efficiency of the sub-sectors. As the non-energy sectors takes the cheaper electricity as an intermediate input, the change of electricity price will inevitably lead to the price changes of non-energy products. Given the transmission sub-sector remains under government supervision, the price of the transmitted electricity does not change. Besides agriculture and public utilities, the composite energy price changes basically follow the same pattern across the sectors when comparing the cases of limited and complete competition. Overall, the impact of the liberalisation is positive for each sector. Note that the phasing out of electricity price regulation induces the growth in the price of the composite energy input in the agricultural and utility sectors.
In addition, commodity prices and domestic consumption showed an inverse relationship. Specifically, for the non-energy sectors, commodity consumption increases with price reduction under the limited competition model. In the power generation sector, non-electric energy sectors decrease their output due switching to electricity (which becomes cheaper) if opposed to fossil fuels being used as final energy. Under the completely competitive scenario, domestic consumption of coal, oil and gas sector outputs decreases to a lower extent than it is the case in partial liberalisation as output of the generation sector goes up. For agriculture and public services, domestic consumption of their outputs decreases due to higher prices, and the consumption of public services decreases to the greatest extent. For other sectors, the change is basically the same as that under the limited competition mode.

4.5.3. Factor Market Analysis

Capital is not allowed to move across the sectors which implies the rate of return on investments vary across the sectors. The results show that the rate of return on investment changes in each sector due to liberalisation of the electricity market and the direction of change is the same under the two scenarios. The return on investments declines in the electricity sector as electricity prices are no longer maintained at the higher level. Among the sub-sectors, the power generation sub-sector faces the most serious change, 8.22% and 10.09% increase in the ROI depending on the scenario assumed. These results indicate that deregulation reduces the profit margins of the power generation industry (see Table 16 and Table 17, column 5).
Regarding labour demand (Table 16 and Table 17, column 6), there are five sectors where labour demand decreases due to electricity market deregulation with the transmission sub-sector facing the most serious decline. Since this paper assumes labour mobility across the sectors, the reduced labour demand in some sectors is compensated by increasing demand in the other ones proportional to the changes in their outputs (most of the freed-up labour force is transferred to energy-intensive industries). In relative terms, the change in demand for labour force is very small if compared to the total amount of the labour force. This shows that the deregulation does not simply decrease employment in the deregulated sector, but rather triggers increase in labour demand across the other sectors and thus ensures redistribution of labour force by the market mechanisms (the invisible hand).

4.5.4. Energy Composite Commodity Analysis

Under the limited competition model, the prices of power, coal, oil and gas all decline. The changes in energy product price will inevitably lead to the price changes of energy composite commodities. In addition, the price of energy composite products decreases in non-energy sectors, except for the service sector.
Due to the inverse relationship between price and demand, the decline in energy input prices inevitably leads to an increase in consumption of energy composite commodities of 4.84% (see Table 16, column 8) in the limited competition case. Due to the abolition of electricity price protection, the price of energy composite commodity increases in agriculture and public utilities under the complete competition scenario. In addition, the prices of energy composite products decrease in most of the other sectors, which induces an increase in the demand for energy composite commodities. Thus, deregulation is likely to stimulate the demand of the energy input.

5. Conclusions

In this paper, we applied a CGE model for the assessment of the impacts of reform of China’s electricity industry. The results indicate that the reform can effectively reduce both the electricity price and composite energy price. A complete competition in the electricity sector of China would lead to an increase in electricity prices for households due to the abolishment of serious electricity cross- subsidies. The results imply reallocation of labour force across the sectors following the phase-out of the regulations. Therefore, professional training and other services should be maintained in order to ensure a smooth transition. From the perspective of sustainability, the liberalisation of the electricity market is likely to fuel the substitution of electricity for other energy sources. Thus, improving the sustainability of electricity generation (by removing backward capacity and switching to renewables) may improve the sustainability of the whole economy of China.
The present research is limited in that the CGE model was built on a rather limited dataset. Therefore, further research should address the following points. First, the CGE model constructed in this paper is a static model, which uses single-year data as the baseline data. Indeed, one can establish a dynamic CGE model to study the effects of the reform on the economy. Second, the substitution parameters used in this model are based on earlier literature. One could further calibrate the parameters involved so that they would represent China’s economic characteristics in a more accurate manner.

Author Contributions

Data curation, J.Y. and K.L.; Investigation, J.Y. and K.L.; Supervision, Q.Y.; Writing—Original Draft, J.Y.; Writing—Review & Editing, T.B. and D.S.

Funding

This work was funded by the Youth Fund Project of Beijing Wuzi University (No. 2019XJQN04), Research Base Project of Beijing Social Science Foundation (No. 16JDGLB023) and 2018 Key Projects of Philosophy and Social Sciences Research, Ministry of Education, China (No. 18JZD032).

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Song, M.; Wang, S. Market competition, green technology progress and comparative advantages in China. Manag. Decis. 2018, 56, 188–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Song, M.; Peng, J.; Wang, J.; Dong, L. Better resource management: An improved resource and environmental efficiency evaluation approach that considers undesirable outputs. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2018, 128, 197–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Chen, J.D.; Cheng, S.L.; Nikic, V.; Song, M.L. Quo vadis? Major players in global coal consumption and emissions reduction. Transform. Bus. Econ. 2018, 17, 112–132. [Google Scholar]
  4. Chaudhary, R.; Bisai, S. Factors influencing green purchase behavior of millennials in India. Manag. Environ. Qual. 2018, 29, 798–812. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Soava, G.; Mehedintu, A.; Sterpu, M.; Raduteanu, M. Impact of renewable energy consumption on economic growth: Evidence from European Union countries. Technol. Econ. Dev. Econ. 2018, 24, 914–932. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Wang, X.L.; Wu, L.H. Determinants of workers’ attitude toward low-carbon technology adoption: Empirical evidence from Chinese firms. Chin. J. Popul. Resour. Environ. 2017, 15, 80–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Xu, Y.C. Sinews of Power: The Politics of the State Grid Corporation of China; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  8. Wang, Q.; Chen, X. China’s electricity market-oriented reform: From an absolute to a relative monopoly. Energy Policy 2012, 51, 143–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Fan, M.T.; Zheng, Y.X. General equilibrium analysis of the impact of trade liberalization on China’s economy. J. World Econ. 2000, 4, 16–26. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  10. Koesler, S.T. Computable general equilibrium modelling in the context of trade and environmental policy. Chembiochem 2015, 7, 158–164. [Google Scholar]
  11. Yahoo, M.; Othman, J. Employing a CGE model in analysing the environmental and economy-wide impacts of CO2 emission abatement policies in Malaysia. Sci. Total Environ. 2017, 584, 234–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Wei, W. An analysis of China’s energy and environmental policies based on CGE model. Stat. Res. 2009, 26, 3–12. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  13. Li, S.T.; Hou, Z.Y.; Zhai, F. Medium and long term: China’s economy still has the potential for rapid growth. China Ind. Econ. 2000, 6, 15–19. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  14. Shi, J.R.; Ling, T.; Le-An, Y.U.; Bao, Q. Impacts of coal resource tax reform on China’s economy based on a CGE model. Syst. Eng. Theory Pract. 2015, 35, 1698–1707. [Google Scholar]
  15. Scaramucci, J.A.; Perin, C.; Pulino, P.; Bardoni, O.F.G.J.; da Cunha, M.P.; Cortez, L.A.B. Energy from sugarcane bagasse under electricity rationing in Brazil: A computable general equilibrium model. Energy Policy 2006, 34, 986–992. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Hosoe, N. The deregulation of Japan’s electricity industry. Jpn. World Econ. 2006, 18, 230–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Akkemik, K.A.; Oguz, F. Regulation, efficiency and equilibrium: A general equilibrium analysis of liberalization in the Turkish electricity market. Energy 2011, 36, 3282–3292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Rodrigues, R.; Linares, P. Electricity load level detail in computational general equilibrium–Part I–Data and calibration. Energy Econ. 2014, 46, 258–266. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Rodrigues, R.; Linares, P. Electricity load level detail in computational general equilibrium—Part II—welfare impacts of a demand response program. Energy Econ. 2014, 47, 52–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Hwang, W.S.; Lee, J.D. A CGE analysis for quantitative evaluation of electricity market changes. Energy Policy 2015, 83, 69–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Farajzadeh, Z.; Bakhshoodeh, M. Economic and environmental analyses of Iranian energy subsidy reform using Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model. Energy Sustain. Dev. 2015, 27, 147–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Capros, P.; Paroussos, L.; Charalampidis, I.; Fragkiadkis, K.; Karkatsoulis, P.; Tsani, S. Assessment of the macroeconomic and sectoral effects of higher electricity and gas prices in the EU: A general equilibrium modeling approach. Energy Strategy Rev. 2016, 9, 18–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Bataille, C.; Melton, N. Energy efficiency and economic growth: A retrospective CGE analysis for Canada from 2002 to 2012. Energy Econ. 2017, 24, 118–130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Melnikov, N.B.; O’Neill, B.C.; Dalton, M.G.; van Ruijven, B.J. Downscaling heterogeneous household outcomes in dynamic CGE models for energy-economic analysis. Energy Econ. 2017, 65, 87–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Mu, Y.Q.; Wang, C.; Cai, W.J. Using sectoral approach as complement to the INDC framework: An analysis based on the CGE model. Energy Procedia 2017, 105, 3433–3439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Liu, Y.; Hu, X.; Feng, K. Economic and environmental implications of raising China’s emission standard for thermal power plants: An environmentally extended CGE analysis. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2016, 121, 64–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Li, W.; Jia, Z.; Zhang, H. The impact of electric vehicles and CCS in the context of emission trading scheme in China: A CGE-based analysis. Energy 2017, 119, 800–816. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Zhang, W.; Yang, J.; Zhang, Z.; Shackam, J.D. Natural gas price effects in China based on the CGE model. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 147, 497–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Zhang, S.; Wang, C.; Cai, W. How shale gas will shape China’s future? An evaluation based on dynamic energy-CGE model. Energy Procedia 2017, 105, 3349–3354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Liu, Q.; Liu, Y.; Xu, J.T. Economic and environmental effects of improved auto fuel economy standard in china: A CGE analysis. Acta Sci. Nat. Univ. Pekin. 2016, 52, 515–527. [Google Scholar]
  31. Ge, J.; Lei, Y. Policy options for non-grain bioethanol in China: Insights from an economy-energy-environment CGE model. Energy Policy 2017, 105, 502–511. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Xiao, Y.; Wang, X.; Wang, X.; Wu, Z.; Liu, W. The Coordinated development path of renewable energy and national economy in China considering risks of electricity market and energy policy. IEEE Trans. Ind. Inform. 2017, 13, 2556–2575. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Liu, Y.; Zhou, M. The impact of coal resource tax reform on the Chinese economy: A CGE analysis. Singap. Econ. Rev. 2018, 63, 555–565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Yang, H.W.; Cui, C. Application of CGE model to analyze environmental and social benefits of gas generation in China’s power sector. Energy Environ. 2006, 1, 10–14. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  35. Zhang, Y.G. Potential Effects of electricity price change on industrial structure—empirical analysis from different angles. J. N. China Electr. Power Univ. 2006, 10, 36–41. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  36. Tan, X.D.; Zhao-Guang, H.U.; Meng, L.I. Electric policy simulation based on computable general equilibrium model. Power Syst. Technol. 2007, 31, 55–60. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  37. He, Y.X.; Zhang, S.L.; Yang, L.Y.; Wang, Y.J.; Wang, J. Economic analysis of coal price-electricity price adjustment in China based on the CGE model. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 6629–6637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Song, M.L.; Cui, L.B. Economic evaluation of Chinese electricity price marketization based on dynamic computational general equilibrium model. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2016, 101, 614–628. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. He, J.H.; Shen, K.T.; Xu, S.L. A CGE model of carbon tax and carbon dioxide emission reduction. J. Quant. Tech. Econ. 2002, 10, 39–47. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  40. Ma, S.G. Effects of sulfur tax on Chinese sulfur dioxide emission and energy consumption. China Ind. Econ. 2008, 22, 20–30. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Production and consumption related data of electric power industry.
Figure 1. Production and consumption related data of electric power industry.
Sustainability 11 00350 g001
Figure 2. Number of registered electric power sale companies in major regions of China.
Figure 2. Number of registered electric power sale companies in major regions of China.
Sustainability 11 00350 g002
Figure 3. Production structure of the CGE model.
Figure 3. Production structure of the CGE model.
Sustainability 11 00350 g003
Figure 4. Trade structure of the CGE model.
Figure 4. Trade structure of the CGE model.
Sustainability 11 00350 g004
Table 1. Electricity market liberalization schedule in China.
Table 1. Electricity market liberalization schedule in China.
StageObject
Stage 1All industrial and commercial electricity users with voltage level higher than 110 kV (66 kV)
Part of industrial and commercial electricity users with voltage level higher than 35 kV
Stage 2All industrial and commercial electricity users with voltage level higher than 35 kV
Part of industrial and commercial electricity users with voltage level higher than 10 kV
Stage 3All electricity users with voltage level higher than 10 kV
Table 2. Variables for the production module.
Table 2. Variables for the production module.
VariableVariable Definition
PAaPrice of sector output
PCOALaPrice of coal input
PECaPrice of energy composite input
PELECaPrice of electricity composite input
PELECNaPrice of non-electricity composite input
PKaPrice of capital input
PKELaPrice of capital-energy-labour composite input
PKEaPrice of capital-energy composite input
PLaPrice of labour input
PNDaPrice of non-intermediate input
POGaPrice of oil and gas composite input
QAaQuantity of sector output
QCOALaQuantity of coal input
QECaQuantity of energy composite input
QELECaQuantity of electricity composite input
QELECNaQuantity of non-electricity composite input
QKaQuantity of capital input
QKEaQuantity of capital-energy composite input
QKELaQuantity of capital-energy-labour composite input
QLaQuantity of labour input
QNDaQuantity of non-energy intermediate input
QOGaQuantity of oil and gas composite input
UNDc,aQuantity of the unit intermediate input
Table 3. Parameters for the production module.
Table 3. Parameters for the production module.
ParameterParameter Definition
α c , a Direct consumption coefficient of intermediate input
δ a A Share parameter of CES function of QA
α a A Scale parameter of CES function of QA
ρ A Substitution elasticity parameter of CES function of QA
δ a K E L Share parameter of CES function of KEL
α a K E L Scale parameter of CES function of KEL
ρ K E L Substitution elasticity parameter of CES function of KEL
δ a K E Share parameter of CES function of KE
α a K E Scale parameter of CES function of KE
ρ K E Substitution elasticity parameter of CES function of KE
δ a E C Share parameter of CES function of EC
α a E C Scale parameter of CES function of EC
ρ E C Substitution elasticity parameter of CES function of EC
δ a E L E C N Share parameter of CES function of ELECN
α a E L E C N Scale parameter of CES function of ELECN
ρ E L E C N Substitution elasticity parameter of CES function of ELECN
Table 4. Variables for the trade module.
Table 4. Variables for the trade module.
VariableVariable Definition
PMcPrice of import commodities
PEcPrice of export commodities
EXRExchange rate
PQcPrice of domestic demand commodities
PDcPrice of domestic supply commodities
QQcQuantity of domestic demand commodities
QDcQuantity of domestic supply commodities
QMcQuantity of import commodities
QEcQuantity of export commodities
pweaImport price in current units
pwecExport price in current units
Table 5. Parameters for the trade module.
Table 5. Parameters for the trade module.
ParameterParameter Definition
δ a q a Share parameter of CET function
α a q a Scale parameter of CET function
ρ E C Substitution elasticity parameter of CET function
δ c q q Share parameter of Armington function
α c q q Scale parameter of Armington function
ρ q q Substitution elasticity parameter of Armington function
Table 6. Variables for the income module.
Table 6. Variables for the income module.
VariableVariable Definition
YHHousehold income
YGGovernment income
YEEnterprise income
MTAXImport tax
ETAXExport tax
ATAXProduction tax
transfrh,govTransfer from government to the household
transfrh,entTransfer from enterprise to the household
transfrh,rowTransfer from the rest of the world to the household
Transfrgov,rowTransfer from the rest of the world to the government
Table 7. Parameters for the income module.
Table 7. Parameters for the income module.
ParameterParameter Definition
shifhProportion of household capital income
shifentProportion of enterprise capital income
tihPersonal income tax rate
tientCorporate income tax rate
Table 8. Variables for the consumption module.
Table 8. Variables for the consumption module.
VariableVariable Definition
EHHousehold expenditures
EGGovernment expenditures
EEEnterprise expenditures
HSAVHousehold savings
GSAVGovernment savings
ESAVEnterprise savings
transfrrow,govTransfer from government to the rest of the world
Table 9. Parameter for the consumption module.
Table 9. Parameter for the consumption module.
ParameterParameter Definition
mpshHousehold savings ratio coefficient
Table 10. Variables for the equilibrium module.
Table 10. Variables for the equilibrium module.
VariableVariable Definition
QLSTotal supply of labour
QKSTotal supply of capital
QINTc,aQuantity of intermediate input
QINVcQuantity of investments
transfrrow,fForeign capital investment returns
QUSTOCStock change
WALRASBalanced slack variable
GDPGross domestic product
Table 11. Variables for the resident welfare module.
Table 11. Variables for the resident welfare module.
VariableVariable Definition
EVHicksian equivalent variation
E(Us,PQb)The level of effectiveness after implementation of policies
E(Ub,PQb)The level of effectiveness before implementation of policies
Table 12. Sectors covered by the CGE model and the corresponding notations.
Table 12. Sectors covered by the CGE model and the corresponding notations.
NumberSectorsSector Codes in the Input-Output TablesAbbreviations
1agriculture1agr
2coal mining2coal
3oil, gas, refined oil products03, 11OG
4other mining04, 05mining
5electricity generation25elec-G
6electricity transmission25elec-T
7electricity distribution25elec-D
8manufacturing06–10, 12–22man
9construction28cons
10financial services23, 24, 26, 27, 29–34serv
11public utilities35–42pub
Table 13. The macro-SAM table of China in 2012 (Unit: Billion).
Table 13. The macro-SAM table of China in 2012 (Unit: Billion).
CommoditiesActivitiesFactorsHouseholdsEnterprisesGovernmentRowCapital AccountqustoTotal
Commodities 1,162,399 198,537 73,182136,666237,75130,2771,838,812
Activities1,699,199 1,699,199
Factors 463,194 463,194
Households 288,471 31,53614,764401 335,172
Enterprises 172,503 172,503
Government17,58673,606 582043,115 −19077,566 217,503
Row122,027 2220 149 124,396
Capital Account 130,81597,852129,408−12,481 345,594
qusto 30,277 30,277
Total1,838,8121,699,199463,194335,172172,503217,503124,396345,59430,277
Table 14. Substitution elasticity parameters used in CGE model.
Table 14. Substitution elasticity parameters used in CGE model.
sectorsagrcoalOGminelecmanconpub
ε E C 0.7000.700.70.70.7
ε E L E C N 1.25001.2501.251.251.25
ε q q 2.23330.9321.9
ε q a 54440.54.643.2
Table 15. Macro-level results of simulations (per cent changes from the baseline scenario).
Table 15. Macro-level results of simulations (per cent changes from the baseline scenario).
VariableChanges from Baseline Scenario (%)
Limited CompetitionFull Competition
1Energy prices for households−10.358−3.071
2Energy composite use by households2.2830.743
3GDP0.6120.441
4EV (billion yuan)7.7102.316
5Household income0.0370.031
6Enterprise income0.1730.108
7Government income0.0650.044
8Labor price0.0240.018
Note: EV is the abbreviation of Hicksian equivalent variation.
Table 16. Micro-level results of simulation for limited competition model (per cent changes from the baseline scenario).
Table 16. Micro-level results of simulation for limited competition model (per cent changes from the baseline scenario).
OutputDomestic ConsumptionIntermediate InputCommodity PriceCapital PriceLabor UsePECQEC
agr0.430.25−0.27−0.330.910.64−1.181.13
coal−2.04−0.83−0.17−1.68−1.11−4.48
OG-1.29−0.51−2.21−1.09−2.73−2.41
mining1.990.150.44−1.710.425.01−0.540.55
elec-G1.84−1.02−6.8−8.220.64
elec-T1.841.840.21−8.92
elec-D1.841.961.84−9.61−5.59
man1.320.460.83-1.340.516.11−0.240.73
cons0.220.930.65−0.870.03−7.72−0.350.24
serv0.41−0.110.340.090.840.510.020.87
pub0.540.18−0.23−0.080.370.39−0.131.32
Table 17. Micro-level results of simulation for full liberalisation (per cent changes from the baseline scenario).
Table 17. Micro-level results of simulation for full liberalisation (per cent changes from the baseline scenario).
OutputDomestic ConsumptionIntermediate InputCommodity PriceCapital PriceLabor UsePECQEC
agr−0.26−0.190.070.170.570.470.18−0.72
coal−0.73−0.28−2.04−2.04−0.78−2.38
OG−0.08−0.37−0.020.02−2.48−2.71
mining1.360.76−1.58−1.580.44.26−0.470.62
elec-G2.72−1.92−6.27−10.090.52
elec-T2.722.720.14−7.06
elec-D2.720.782.72−8.15-4.92
man0.891.720.33-1.270.363.78−0.240.65
cons0.110.460.06−0.520.01−4.66-0.270.27
serv0.210.960.110.060.730.320.020.63
pub−0.32−1.570.120.020.150.190.07−0.38

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yin, J.; Yan, Q.; Lei, K.; Baležentis, T.; Streimikiene, D. Economic and Efficiency Analysis of China Electricity Market Reform Using Computable General Equilibrium Model. Sustainability 2019, 11, 350. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11020350

AMA Style

Yin J, Yan Q, Lei K, Baležentis T, Streimikiene D. Economic and Efficiency Analysis of China Electricity Market Reform Using Computable General Equilibrium Model. Sustainability. 2019; 11(2):350. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11020350

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yin, Jieting, Qingyou Yan, Kaijie Lei, Tomas Baležentis, and Dalia Streimikiene. 2019. "Economic and Efficiency Analysis of China Electricity Market Reform Using Computable General Equilibrium Model" Sustainability 11, no. 2: 350. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11020350

APA Style

Yin, J., Yan, Q., Lei, K., Baležentis, T., & Streimikiene, D. (2019). Economic and Efficiency Analysis of China Electricity Market Reform Using Computable General Equilibrium Model. Sustainability, 11(2), 350. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11020350

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop