Sustainable Collective Action in High-Rise Gated Communities: Evidence from Shanxi, China Using Ostrom’s Design Principles
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Theoretical Framework
2.1. Human Factors
- Bounded rationality: Bounded rationality refers to the behavioral characteristics that stem from pursuing rationality subjectively. However, from an objective perspective, this can only be carried out in a limited way. In other words, generally speaking, although an individual’s motivation to undertake economic activities is purposeful and rational, it is only a rational behavior under limited conditions. Before the transaction, the traders cannot fully collect the information relevant to the prior contract arrangement, nor can they predict various possible changes in the future. Therefore, the contractual man should bear some risks when executing the transaction.
- Opportunism: Opportunism refers to how an individual will seek to further their interests through improper means while pursuing the maximization of personal interests in the transaction process, to the detriment of other individuals’ interests.
2.2. Factors Related to Specific Transactions
- Asset specificity: Williamson explained that asset specificity is “the extent to which assets can be used for different purposes and different users without sacrificing production value. It is related to sunk costs” [28]. When one or both of the transaction parties have invested in special assets, the continuity of the contractual relationship is of great significance. If the transaction is terminated in advance, it will cause a significant loss in terms of the net value of the assets of one or both parties.
- Transaction uncertainty: Koopmans [29] divides uncertainty into two categories. The first is primary uncertainty, which is caused by natural disordered behavior and unpredictable changes in consumer preferences. The second is secondary uncertainty, which stems from the lack of information communication when a person makes a decision. When the transaction is affected by uncertainty, individuals will choose those contractual arrangements that incur the lowest transaction cost possible. Transaction uncertainty is inseparable from bounded rationality; if there is no bounded rationality, there will be no uncertainty.
- Frequency of exchange: Frequency of exchange refers to the number of transactions. To be precise, it only impacts the relative costs of various transactions, not the absolute terms of transaction costs. The establishment and operation of a governance structure incur costs, and the extent to which these costs can be offset by the benefits depends on the frequency of transactions within the specific governance structure. Transactions that occur more frequently are easier to offset against the cost of the governance structure than transactions that occur less frequently.
2.3. Transaction Market Environmental Factors
- The transaction market environment refers to the number of potential counterparties. Williamson noted that there is a large number of suppliers who can participate in the bidding conditions at the beginning of the transaction. Even so, this does not mean that such conditions will exist in the future. When a transaction monopoly forms, the possibility of the monopolistic party engaging in opportunistic behavior increases significantly.
3. Materials and Method
3.1. Study Area
3.2. Data Collection
3.3. Data Analysis
4. Results and Discussion
4.1. Well-Defined Gated Communities’ Boundaries
“It is very important to define the rights of participants of commons management in gated communities. If there are no well-defined rights for commons management participants, some residents and managers would harm the common interests for their interests; for example, residents privately occupy the public green space in a community to grow vegetables”.
“There is some public welfare low-cost housing in our community. Therefore, the property rights of commons in the community are not completely owned by residents, but this does not entail those residents living in low-cost housing would not participate in commons management in communities and fail to follow commons management rules. To make every member of the community bear the responsibility of commons management and abide by the community commons management rules, we registered the homeowners’ association, formulated the commons management rules, and defined the rights and obligations of different participants. It is unrealistic to rely on a single group to manage the commons in our type of community”.
4.2. Matching Rules Governing the Use of Common Goods to Local Needs and Conditions
“It is very important to ensure that residents’ costs and benefits are equal, the management of our community had been troubled by this issue. In the past, our community installed a public hot water supply system. After five years of operation, the residents of our community thought that the maintenance cost of the public hot water supply system was high, and they preferred to install private water heaters. Finally, we dismantled the public hot water supply system. Moreover, in the past, the right of using public basketball courts in our community often led to conflicts among residents. Some residents thought they had the priority to use the basketball courts because they play basketball on the courts. However, other residents that although they do not play basketball, they invested in the maintenance of basketball courts, they had the right to do what they wanted on the basketball courts. Finally, we revised the rules of the right to use basketball courts, residents must pay additional fees to use the basketball courts”.
“After the closure of the Textile Mill Company Community, some common properties in the community were preserved, such as the workers’ cultural center and cinema. We lost our jobs and lacked a stable source of income. Therefore, we charge the users of the workers’ cultural center and open it to the public. On the one hand, this strategy can protect the common heritage and avoid disrepair, and part of the profits can also be used to maintain other common property in the community”.
4.3. Ensuring That Participants Related to Commons Management Can Participate in Modifying the Rules
“In the past, the neglect of the manager for community hygiene caused the owners’ dissatisfaction with the community hygiene. More and more residents expressed their dissatisfaction with community hygiene to property management companies. After that, we organized a decision-making meeting. Finally, more than half of the owners expressed dissatisfaction with community hygiene. Then we hired new cleaners, and up to now, there are no more complaints from the owners about community hygiene”.
“Our community holds regular house-owner conventions to ask our employees if there are any problems in community life, and we will take some improvement measures in response to these problems. We believed that this is beneficial to common property management in gated communities”.
4.4. Developing a System for Monitoring Members’ Behaviors to Be Carried Out by Community Members
“It is important to monitor the behaviors of community members. Commons management in gated communities is not only the behaviors of residents being monitored by managers, but also residents’ monitor of managers’ behaviors is equally important. Because residents and owners are the main participants and beneficiaries of commons management in gated communities, poor commons management performance would cause a greater loss to residents than other participants. When either party has more power than the other, the party with more power will infringe on the interests of the party with less power to seek more interests”.
“Every resident in our community is a participant and supervisor in the common property management. When residents find that the managers have the behaviors of evading management responsibilities, residents will report to the homeowners’ association. The homeowners’ association will sanction the managers who failed to fulfill management obligations”.
4.5. Using Graduated Sanctions for Rule Violators
“It is important to use graduated sanctions for rule violators, the initial severe sanction is difficult to implement. According to our experience, the severe sanction is difficult to solve the issues, and it would intensify the conflicts among residents, and even leads to conflicts between residents and community managers. Initial severe sanction is not conducive to the harmonious relationship among commons management participants in gated communities”.
“The progressive sanction rules can enable residents to continuously learn and accumulate management experience in the process of common property management in gated communities, build a sense of mutual trust among residents and improve their collective action ability. The initial strict rules will cause the disgust of some residents, whether they intentionally or unintentionally violate the rules of common property management. When a resident illegally parks for the first time, we will warn about illegal parking behaviors by posting a warning strip. When residents park illegally many times, we will impose fines on violators. If violators still do not correct their wrong behaviors, we will seek the help of the sub-district office. For more serious violators, we will seek the corresponding law-enforcing departments or take other legitimate legal means to sanction the violator’s behaviors”.
4.6. Dispute Resolution Mechanism
“Accessible, low-cost dispute resolution rules are important. On the one hand, such rules can make our work easier. On the other hand, inaccessible dispute resolution rules often cause more disputes”.
“Most of the conflicts among residents in communities are resolved through intercession or sanction. The most difficult problems to resolve in the community are conflicts caused by violations that are vaguely defined by common property management rules. It is difficult for us to decide on this kind of conflict; because if we do not have enough persuasion to solve these conflicts, some residents will question our professionalism, avoid the rules and make some violations that are not conducive to the common interest. When we have problems that are difficult to deal with by existing rules, we usually seek the help of the sub-district office, which is more experience in resolving disputes in gated communities. They have more resources and ways to help solve community disputes”.
4.7. Minimal Recognition of Residents’ Rights to Organize Commons Management in Gated Communities
“It is important to protect the rights of residents from being interfered with by external forces. Part of the common properties in our community belong to the government, but the main users of these common properties are residents living in low-cost housing. If there is no homeowners’ association to safeguard the rights of these low-income residents, we cannot guarantee that some government managers seek their interests privately through some corrupt behaviors and harm the interests of residents”.
“Part of the land assets in our community belong to the Boiler Installation Company, which has bankrupt at the end of last century. However, the original company leaders want to seek personal interests through external leasing and sales of land assets. Together with the powerful residents in our community, the original company leaders privately occupied part of the common space, which caused negative impacts on our daily lives, such as daily travel and rest. Then, we mobilized all owners to safeguard our rights, and even though legal intervention, after a series of effective actions, our common property management rules can run properly”.
4.8. Nested/Layered Community Management Structure (Polycentricity)
“Our community is large and uneasy to manage. Therefore, with our mobilization, the residents of each building spontaneously elect a resident with rich community management experience and management ability to be elected as the building head. When residents need help, the building head will help them solve the problems or further convey the needs and opinions of residents to the property management company. I believe that it can bond residents’ relationships, and residents can express opinions freely better, and our management pressure will be less”.
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Shi, X.; Ling, G.H.T. Factors Influencing High-Rise Gated Community Collective Action Effectiveness: Conceptualization of the Social-Ecological System (SES) Framework. Buildings 2022, 12, 307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E.; Janssen, M.A.; Anderies, J.M. Going beyond panaceas. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2007, 104, 15176–15178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Shi, X.; Ling, G.H.T. Factors influencing collective action of gated communities: A systematic review using an SES framework. Open House Int. 2022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Blakely, E.J.; Snyder, M.G. Fortress America: Gated communities in the United States; Brookings Institution Press: Washington, DC, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Grant, J.; Mittelsteadt, L. Types of gated communities. Environ. Plan. B Plan. Des. 2004, 31, 913–930. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Douglass, M.; Wissink, B.; Van Kempen, R. Enclave urbanism in China: Consequences and interpretations. Urban Geogr. 2012, 33, 167–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Webster, C.; Glasze, G.; Frantz, K. The global spread of gated communities. Environ. Plan. B Plan. Des. 2002, 29, 315–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Atkinson, R.; Blandy, S. Introduction: International perspectives on the new enclavism and the rise of gated communities. Hous. Stud. 2005, 20, 177–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Glasze, G.; Webster, C.; Frantz, K. Private Cities: Global and Local Perspectives, 1st ed.; Routledge: London, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Manzi, T.; Smith-Bowers, B. Gated communities as club goods: Segregation or social cohesion? Hous. Stud. 2005, 20, 345–359. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Caldeira, T.P.R. Fortified enclaves: The new urban segregation. In The Urban Sociology Reader; Lin, J., Mele, C., Eds.; Routledge: London, UK, 2012; pp. 419–427. [Google Scholar]
- Low, S. Behind the Gates: Life, Security, and the Pursuit of Happiness in Fortress America; Routledge: London, UK, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Miao, P. Deserted streets in a jammed town: The gated community in Chinese cities and its solution. J. Urban Des. 2003, 8, 45–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lum, T. Social Unrest in China; Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Foster, S.R. Collective action and the urban commons. Notre Dame Law Rev. 2011, 87, 57. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Yip, N.M. Walled without gates: Gated communities in Shanghai. Urban Geogr. 2012, 33, 221–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, H.K.; Ling, G.H.T.; Shi, X. Collective Action Components of Low-Cost Housing: An Empirical Analysis Using Ostrom’s SES Framework. Property Management. Available online: https://www.emerald.com/insight/content/doi/10.1108/PM-07-2021-0053/full/html (accessed on 1 February 2022).
- Gao, W. Collective actions for the management of multi-owned residential building: A case of Hong Kong. Habitat Int. 2015, 49, 316–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Williamson, O.E. Transaction-cost economics: The governance of contractual relations. J. Law Econ. 1979, 22, 233–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Foster, S.R.; Laione, C. The city as a commons. Yale Law Policy Rev. 2015, 34, 281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ling, G.H.T. Ostrom’s collective-action in neighbourhood public open space: Evidence from Sabah, Malaysia. Inst. Econ. 2019, 11, 103–134. [Google Scholar]
- Williamson, O.E. The new institutional economics: Taking stock, looking ahead. J. Econ. Lit. 2000, 38, 595–613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Quinn, C.H.; Huby, M.; Kiwasila, H.; Lovett, J.C. Design principles and common pool resource management: An institutional approach to evaluating community management in semi-arid Tanzania. J. Environ. Manag. 2007, 84, 100–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wilson, D.S.; Ostrom, E.; Cox, M.E. Generalizing the core design principles for the efficacy of groups. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2013, 90, S21–S32. [Google Scholar]
- Coase, R.H. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 1937, 4, 386–405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Williamson, O.E. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting; University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign’s Academy for Entrepreneurial Leadership Historical Research Reference in Entrepreneurship: Urbana, IL, USA, 1985. [Google Scholar]
- Schwartz, B. The Sunk Costs Fallacy: Bush Falls Victim to A Bad New Argument for The Iraq War. Slate. 2005. Available online: https://slate.com/news-and-politics/2005/09/bush-is-a-sucker-for-the-sunk-cost-fallacy.html (accessed on 1 February 2022).
- Koopmans, T.C. Three essays on the state of economic science. Br. J. Philos. Sci. 1959, 10, 58–69. [Google Scholar]
- Olson, M. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1965. [Google Scholar]
- Crawford, K.M. Developing the Whole Teacher: A Phenomenological Case Study of Student Teachers’ Emotional Experiences in One Teacher Education Program. Ph.D. Thesis, Georgia Southern University, Statesboro, GA, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Merriam, S.B.; Tisdell, E.J. Qualitative Research: A Guide to Design and Implementation; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2015; ISBN 978-0470283547. [Google Scholar]
- Alsaawi, A. A critical review of qualitative interviews. Eur. J. Bus. Soc. Sci. 2014, 3, 2819536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Braun, V.; Clarke, V. Thematic Analysis; American Psychological Association: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E.; Walker, J.; Gardner, R. Covenants with and without a sword: Self-governance is possible. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 1992, 86, 404–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ostrom, E. Building trust to solve commons dilemmas: Taking small steps to test an evolving theory of collective action. In Games, Groups, and The Global Good; Levin, S., Ed.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2009; pp. 207–228. ISBN 978-3-540-85435-7. [Google Scholar]
- Ling, G.H.T.; Ho, C.S.; Ali, H.M.; Tu, F. Do institutions matter in neighbourhood commons governance? A two-stage relationship between diverse property-rights structure and residential public open space (POS) quality: Kota Kinabalu and Penampang, Sabah, Malaysia. Int. J. Commons 2016, 10, 294–333. [Google Scholar]
- Hamama, B.; Liu, J. What is beyond the edges? Gated communities and their role in China’s desire for harmonious cities. City Territ. Archit. 2020, 7, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Breitung, W. Enclave urbanism in China: Attitudes towards gated communities in Guangzhou. Urban Geogr. 2012, 33, 278–294. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lu, T.; Zhang, F.; Wu, F. The meaning of “private governance” in urban China: Researching residents’ preferences and satisfaction. Urban Policy Res. 2019, 37, 378–392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lu, T.; Zhang, F.; Wu, F. The variegated role of the state in different gated neighbourhoods in China. Urban Stud. 2020, 57, 1642–1659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yip, N.M. Housing activism in urban China: The quest for autonomy in neighbourhood governance. Hous. Stud. 2019, 34, 1635–1653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Ostrom’s Principles | Relevance to Transaction Costs | Relevance to Common Property Management |
---|---|---|
1st: Defining clear group boundaries. | Gated communities with clear group boundaries have lower transaction costs related to commons management. As per transaction uncertainty, clearly defined commons management rights can build trust among residents, meaning that individuals are less inclined to engage in opportunistic behavior (i.e., seeking to reduce the costs they incur as much as possible). | Individual residents have the right to use the commons in gated communities and community boundaries must be clearly defined. Who has the right to govern commons in gated communities? What rights should they have? |
2nd: Matching rules governing the use of common goods with local needs and conditions. | Rules matching residents’ needs and conditions can reduce the disparity amongst residents’ benefits in collective action, thereby reducing the divergence of residents and reducing the commons management costs. | Appropriation rules restricting time, place, and technology are related to local conditions. In other words, appropriate collective action rules should be designed taking account of the community context. Moreover, the costs and benefits of commons management and use rules must be proportionate. |
3rd: Ensuring that those affected by the rules can participate in modifying the rules. | According to bounded rationality, commons management rules were initially developed under limited conditions. Therefore, the commons management rules in gated communities can be modified at any time according to the specific conditions of gated communities. If the commons management rules cannot be modified in time, there would be certain risks to the individual community members participating in commons management, resulting in higher transaction costs. | Residents affected by the collective action rules can participate in modifying and devising the rules. |
4th: Developing a system, carried out by community members, for monitoring members’ behavior. | Monitoring the behavior of community members can reduce opportunistic behavior and transaction uncertainty. Monitoring the managers of commons management can prevent managers from monopolizing commons management and partaking in opportunistic behavior. | Effective monitoring of the managers’ resource management and maintenance behavior of commons management. The resource condition is monitored by residents or property owners in the gated community. |
5th: Using graduated sanctions for rule violators. | The graduated sanctions system is conducive to reducing collective action costs. On the one hand, sanctions can reduce the uncertainty of commons management and the opportunistic behavior of free-riders. On the other hand, a graduated sanction system can build trust among community members, reduce the uncertainty of commons management, and thus reduce commons management costs. | Residents who violate commons management rules will be sanctioned by other residents. The intensity of sanctions depends on the seriousness and context of the offense of the violators, although the sanction should not initially be severe. |
6th: Providing accessible, low-cost means for dispute resolution. | Low-cost dispute resolution is a commons management method that incurs low transaction costs. | Property owners, residents, and relevant officials have rapid access to low-cost local arenas in which they can resolve conflicts among residents or between residents and officials. |
7th: Making sure the rule-making rights of community members are respected by outside authorities. | The impact of stronger external forces on commons management will incur higher transaction costs. When external forces intervene in commons management, due to the lack of rule constraints for external participants, the possibility of opportunistic behavior stemming from external forces will increase. | The rights of residents or property owners to design commons management rules are not challenged by external forces. |
8th: Building responsibility for governing the common resource in nested tiers from the lowest level up to the entire interconnected system. | The nested tiers management structure can divide the large-sized commons into small units to reduce the transaction costs relating to commons management. | The collective actions in gated communities are organized in multiple layers of nested enterprises. Especially for large-sized gated communities, multi-center management is required. |
Codes | |
---|---|
1 | Different community members in community management (government, residents, property management agents), homeowners’ association defining rights of community members |
2 | Equal costs and benefits, fairly distributing commons, unfair commons distribution causing disputes |
3 | Modification of commons management rules through homeowners’ convention, avoiding the monopoly of managers, solving commons management problems in time |
4 | Mutual supervision between managers and residents, equal rights of community members, monitoring managers’ behavior through homeowners’ association |
5 | Initial severe sanctions intensifying conflicts, graduated sanction rules building trust, handling ordinary violations within the community, handling tough violations through government and legal departments |
6 | Low-cost dispute resolution rules, disputes are caused by free-riding, government, and legal departments involved in conflict solution |
7 | Homeowners’ association protecting residents’ rights, legal aid for infringed residents’ rights |
8 | Hierarchical management through the election of building heads or unit heads |
Codes | Sub-Themes | Themes |
---|---|---|
Different community members in community management (government, residents, property management agents), homeowners’ association defining rights of community members | Different members in a gated community, the role of homeowners’ association | Defining clear group boundaries |
Equal costs and benefits, fairly distributing commons, unfair commons distribution causing disputes | Equal costs and benefits, prevention and resolution of conflicts | Matching rules governing the use of common goods with local needs and conditions |
Modification of commons management rules through homeowners’ convention, avoiding the monopoly of managers, solving commons management problems in time | Role of homeowners’ association, monopoly of managers | Ensuring that those affected by the rules can participate in modifying the rules |
Mutual supervision between managers and residents, equal rights of community members, monitoring managers’ behavior through homeowners association | Role of homeowners’ association, equal rights, and community members, prevention and resolution of conflicts | Developing a system, carried out by community members, for monitoring members’ behavior |
Initial severe sanctions intensifying conflicts, graduated sanction rules building trust, handling ordinary violations within the community, handling tough violations through government and legal departments | Prevention and resolution of conflicts, the role of government and legal department | Using graduated sanctions for rule violators |
Low-cost dispute resolution rules, disputes are caused by free-riding, government, and legal departments involved in conflict solution | Prevention and resolution of conflicts, the role of government and legal department | Providing accessible, low-cost means for dispute resolution |
Homeowners’ association protecting residents’ rights, legal aid for infringed residents’ rights | Role of homeowners’ association, the role of government, and legal department | Making sure the rule-making rights of community members are respected by outside authorities |
Hierarchical management through the election of building heads or unit heads | Building responsibility for governing the common resource in nested tiers from the lowest level up to the entire interconnected system |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Shi, X.; Ling, G.H.T.; Wang, H.K. Sustainable Collective Action in High-Rise Gated Communities: Evidence from Shanxi, China Using Ostrom’s Design Principles. Sustainability 2022, 14, 14432. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142114432
Shi X, Ling GHT, Wang HK. Sustainable Collective Action in High-Rise Gated Communities: Evidence from Shanxi, China Using Ostrom’s Design Principles. Sustainability. 2022; 14(21):14432. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142114432
Chicago/Turabian StyleShi, Xuerui, Gabriel Hoh Teck Ling, and Hong Kok Wang. 2022. "Sustainable Collective Action in High-Rise Gated Communities: Evidence from Shanxi, China Using Ostrom’s Design Principles" Sustainability 14, no. 21: 14432. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142114432
APA StyleShi, X., Ling, G. H. T., & Wang, H. K. (2022). Sustainable Collective Action in High-Rise Gated Communities: Evidence from Shanxi, China Using Ostrom’s Design Principles. Sustainability, 14(21), 14432. https://doi.org/10.3390/su142114432