1. Introduction
Since the beginning of the industrial civilization era, mankind, while driving rapid global economic growth, has also accelerated the seizure of natural resources, disrupting the balance of the Earth’s ecosystem and increasingly revealing deep-seated conflicts between man and nature. According to the 2019 Global Resource Outlook report by the United Nations Environment Programme, the exploitation of natural resources has increased from 27 to 92 billion tons over the last 50 years. This has led to 90% of biodiversity loss and water scarcity and is responsible for about half of the effects of climate change. The 2022 Global Air Quality Report shows that 97.3% of the world’s population now lives in areas where air pollution exceeds health standards. Given the increase in resource and environmental problems, “developing a green economy” has become a necessary requirement for governments to break the resource and environmental constraints, accelerate the transformation of economic development, and achieve sustainable socio-economic development [
1].
A green economy is an economic development model that seeks to ensure both the natural environment and human well-being can coexist without causing ecological crises or social divisions resulting from the relentless pursuit of economic growth; it aims to avoid unsustainable socio-economic growth caused by the depletion of natural resources [
2]. Achieving green economic development hinges on finding solutions to energy use inefficiency and environmental pollution, which often accompany socio-economic development [
3]. In this regard, economist BiGu pioneered the concept of “government regulation of environmental pollution through macro taxation”. This approach involves taxing emitters based on the difference between private and social costs of emissions, thereby internalizing the negative externalities of pollution. This theoretical foundation supports governmental intervention and management of environmental problems. Environmental taxes, as a crucial tool for the government to protect the environment and conserve resources, have multiple benefits. In the short term, they directly restrict polluters’ emission behavior and encourage rational use of environmentally friendly production materials [
4]. In the long term, they incentivize technological innovation, leading to improved production efficiency and enhanced market competitiveness [
5].
A well-defined environmental taxation system can effectively curb environmental destruction and excessive resource consumption, thus promoting the development of a green economy. The Chinese government has been gradually establishing a comprehensive environmental taxation system while promoting green economic transformation. This system encompasses taxes related to environmental protection, resources, urban construction and maintenance, vehicles, vehicle purchases, urban land use, and arable land occupation.
Considering the competitive behaviors among local governments and regional economic development disparities, it is important to examine the spatial correlation between environmental taxes and the level of green economic development in each region. It is essential to determine whether the current environmental tax system in China effectively fosters the development of a green economy and whether there is heterogeneity in the impact of various environmental taxes on green economic development across regions. Clarifying these questions holds great theoretical and practical significance for the government in reforming and improving the environmental tax system while promoting the development of a green economy.
2. Literature Review
Green economic efficiency serves as a significant indicator for measuring the progress of green economic development. It addresses the limitations of traditional socio-economic development, which focuses solely on increasing factor inputs without considering environmental costs. Evaluating high-quality socio-economic development now includes the consideration of green economy efficiency, as it has become a consensus for sustainable development worldwide.
Many studies have examined green economic efficiency at various spatial scales using data envelopment analysis (DEA) within the input-output framework. For example, Zhao Jinkai et al. (2021) utilized a four-stage disaggregated DEA approach excluding the impact of external environmental variables and employed a bootstrap-DEA model to account for random shocks [
6]. Their study focused on measuring the green development efficiency of Chinese provinces and regions. Similarly, Qianqian Geng (2023) assessed industrial green total factor productivity in China from 2004 to 2020 using the slacks-based measure (SBM) approach [
7]. Zhao P.J. (2020) and Shen Y. (2022) employed a similar approach to measure green economic efficiency in 30 Chinese provinces [
8,
9]. Additionally, Fangmei Liu (2023) evaluated provincial green economic efficiency in China by employing the stochastic non-smooth data envelope (StoNED) model [
10]. Furthermore, Liu’s study examined the gradient differences in green economic efficiency among the eastern, central, and western regions of China.
The analysis of the impact mechanism of environmental tax on green economic development primarily focuses on the micro-individual level. Firstly, environmental taxes influence the production and operational behavior of enterprises, thereby promoting energy conservation and emission reduction. According to Muhammad (2021), environmental taxes encourage cleaner production in industrial enterprises, leading to sustainable economic and environmental development [
11]. Guangqiang Liu (2022) empirically examined the effects of environmental taxes on corporate environmental investment using data from Chinese listed companies between 2015 and 2019, revealing a significant increase in environmental investment due to the implementation of environmental taxes [
12]. According to Akio Yamazaki (2022), rather than diverting resources from production, environmental taxes contribute to a net increase in firm productivity by encouraging investments in environmental protection [
13]. Xu He (2022) analyzed data from a sample of listed companies in China from 2015 to 2020 and discovered that environmental tax reforms have a positive impact on corporate profitability while curbing corporate pollution behaviors [
14]. Zastempowski (2023) analyzed business survey data collected from 13 EU member states in 2014 and discovered that the implementation of environmental taxes motivated companies to replace fossil fuel with renewable energy sources [
15].
Secondly, environmental taxes can drive firms to innovate green technologies and enhance resource efficiency. Greaker (2018) explored how environmental policies can guide firms toward technological innovation, achieving both environmental and economic benefits [
16]. Vitenu-Sackey (2021) argued that a significant increase in environmental taxes can incentivize firms to adopt green technologies, mitigating environmental pollution and improving their total factor productivity [
17,
18]. Zhangsheng Jiang (2023) and Xiaomin Zhao (2023) demonstrated that the implementation of environmental taxes stimulated firms to engage in green innovation, consequently driving business performance [
19,
20]. Min Fan (2022) discovered that environmental taxes indirectly contribute to regional green total factor productivity by fostering higher levels of green technological innovation among firms [
21]. Johan Albrecht (2023) confirmed that environmental taxes largely determine the adoption of energy-efficiency-related technological innovations by small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) [
22]. Zhao X. (2022), using China’s urban panel data from 2007 to 2018, studied the positive impact of green innovation on green economic efficiency [
23].
Empirical studies on the impact of environmental taxes on green economic development have primarily focused on the influence of environmental regulations on green economy development. For example, Shuai S. and Fan Z. (2020) performed an empirical analysis using panel data from China’s regions spanning from 2007 to 2018 [
24]. They measured China’s green economy efficiency using a super-efficient DEA model and found a nonlinear relationship between environmental regulation and green economy efficiency. Shang Y. et al. (2022) investigated the effect of environmental regulation on circular economy performance and discovered that it receives a linear contribution from environmental regulation [
25]. Shen Y. and Zhang X. (2022) utilized provincial-level panel data from China spanning from 2004 to 2020 and employed a two-way fixed-effects model to analyze the impact of environmental taxes on industrial green transformation [
8]. They found that broad environmental taxes such as taxes on vehicles and boats, resources, and urban land use had a significant positive impact on industrial green transformation. Zhao Xin (2023) tested the impact of environmental policies on energy use by using provincial panel data from 2005 to 2019 [
26]. Syed Abdul (2022) identified a significant positive relationship between environmental policies and green total factor productivity through empirical analysis of data from a sample of 12 cities in China [
17].
Upon reviewing the existing literature, it is evident that there is a wealth of research on measuring green economy efficiency and analyzing the micro-mechanisms of environmental taxes on green economy development. This body of work has laid a strong foundation for our study. However, there are certain limitations in the existing research that need to be addressed. Firstly, most studies primarily focus on analyzing the impact of environmental regulations or policies on green economy efficiency, with fewer studies examining the influence of environmental taxes on green economy development. Furthermore, there is a scarcity of research exploring the differential effects of various environmental taxes on green economy development across different regions. Secondly, in terms of research methodology, many studies rely on general panel models to empirically analyze the relationship between environmental taxes and the green economy. However, it is crucial to consider the spillover effects of environmental taxes on green economy development, especially considering the strong geographical and economic correlations observed in local environmental tax policies and the green economy (C. Cindy Fan, 2004) [
27].
Taking into account these shortcomings in the existing research, our study assumes that environmental taxes have a spatial spillover effect on green economic efficiency and aims to contribute in the following ways: Firstly, in terms of methodology, we employed a spatial econometric model to empirically analyze the impact of environmental taxes on green economic efficiency. This approach allowed us to consider the spatial relationships and potential spillover effects in our analysis. Secondly, in terms of content, we comprehensively analyzed the impact of environmental taxes as a policy tool on green economic development. Moreover, we explicitly examined the diverse effects of different environmental taxes on green economic development across different regions. This provides valuable insights for formulating region-specific environmental tax policies that are conducive to promoting sustainable and green economic growth.
5. Research Findings and Policy Recommendations
5.1. Research Conclusion
This research utilized panel data encompassing 30 Chinese provinces, including autonomous regions and municipalities directly controlled by the central government. The data cover the period from 2006 to 2020, providing a comprehensive temporal scope for the analysis. The study measured the efficiency of each province’s green economy by utilizing a super-efficiency model. To investigate the impact of environmental tax policies on green economic development, a spatial lag model was employed, and three spatial weighting matrices were used. The following conclusions were drawn: (1) Environmental taxation exhibits a strong positive correlation with green economic efficiency and also has a positive spatial spillover effect on regional green economic efficiency. (2) The analysis of tax heterogeneity showed that vehicle and vessel taxes can promote improved green economic efficiency. Nevertheless, the implementation of taxes such as those for environmental protection, arable land occupation, and urban land use may hinder the growth of green economic ventures. Urban maintenance and construction taxes can also adversely affect green economic efficacy on an economic scale within the region. Conversely, resource taxation does not appear to significantly impact local green economic development. Further examination of regional heterogeneity revealed that the spatial ramifications of environmental taxation on green economic advancement vary among regions. (3) In light of China’s current economic development, population distribution, and level of openness to external trade, favorable conditions exist for the advancement of the green economy. However, the industrial structure exhibits a negative correlation with green economic efficacy at the 1% level of significance. In addition, no correlation exists between pollution control efforts and green economic efficacy. This study has several limitations that should be considered. Firstly, the analysis primarily focuses on data from 30 provinces and autonomous regions in China, which may limit the generalizability of the findings to other countries. Economic development levels, population sizes, and national policies vary across countries, and therefore, the findings may not be directly applicable elsewhere. To address this limitation, future studies could expand the sample size to include a broader range of countries, specifically examining the impact of environmental tax policies on green economy development in five East Asian countries or sixteen East and Southeast Asian countries. By conducting such analyses and exploring the heterogeneity among countries at different stages of development, more comprehensive and general conclusions can be drawn.
5.2. Recommendations
Drawing from the aforementioned research results, we present the subsequent policy suggestions. Firstly, based on the spatial characteristics of environmental taxation and green economic efficiency, coordination and cooperation among governments should be strengthened. The spatial spillover effect of environmental taxation could potentially provoke neighboring governments into either free riding or blindly imitating such policies. Building a perfect information-communication and interest-coordination mechanism among governments can prompt local governments to target their policies, understand key points, and clarify targets, thus realizing inter-governmental cooperation in pollution control and accelerating the green transformation and development of enterprises. From a different perspective, it is clear that green economic efficiency exhibits positive autocorrelation; therefore, governments at all levels should understand the scientific basis of economic efficiency under current resource and environmental constraints, clarify the key industries in each region, form regional characteristics, and cooperate with neighboring regions to guide the development of industrial layout in the region to achieve green economic growth. Governments at all levels can play a crucial role by creating a platform for regional exchange and cooperation. This allows them to coordinate efforts with other regions and develop tailored environmental tax strategies that align with the specific attributes of each region. By doing so, governments can maximize the guiding potential and fiscal leverage of environmental taxes, leading to more effective and targeted outcomes in promoting sustainable development.
Secondly, environmental tax policy should be improved and a comprehensive environmental tax system constructed. We found that the environmental tax presently imposed encourages environmentally sustainable economic growth. However, some pre-existing environmental tax measures have yet to yield noticeable results, or they may have even led to adverse effects. Local governments should follow the current status of economic development and resource endowment of each region to further develop and improve the content of environmental tax policies suitable for local areas. After careful analysis, it is recommended that the resource tax levy be broadened, tax burden be increased for arable land occupation and urban land use, and environmental protection tax levy standards be adjusted to reflect the actual pollution emissions and economic development level of the region. It is advisable to levy taxes on all forms of pollutants to provide effective policy support. Simultaneously, consideration can be given to reducing the tax burden of other taxes such as VAT and corporate income tax in the form of green innovation incentives to reduce the cost effect of environmental taxes and thus promote development of the green economy. In response to this scenario, it is essential for nations worldwide, particularly those that have recently implemented or reformed environmental tax policies, to conduct a comprehensive analysis of the effects of these taxes on various regions and industries. This analysis will enable them to identify any necessary adjustments that need to be made in a timely manner, ensuring that environmental tax strategies effectively achieve their intended outcomes. By closely monitoring and adapting these strategies, governments can maximize the positive impact of environmental taxes and ensure their continued effectiveness in promoting sustainable development.
Thirdly, based on the results of the heterogeneity tests for different taxes and considering the negative impact of the industrial structure on green economy efficiency, it is crucial to focus on upgrading the industrial structure and enhancing the efficiency of local governments in environmental pollution control. By prioritizing these areas, policymakers can effectively address the challenges and improve the overall performance of the green economy. Although the current industrial structure of most Chinese provinces has entered the “three-two-one” mode because of the high level of pollution emissions in China’s secondary industry, in order to promote economic development, there remains a need to prioritize the expansion of the tertiary sector while gradually diminishing the significance of the secondary sector. At the same time, in secondary industry, it is important to strengthen the capacity constraints of high-pollution and high-energy-consumption enterprises and use environmental tax policy to urge them to enhance their production technology and speed up transformation and upgradation. Regarding the issue of unremarkable pollution control effectiveness, in order to enhance the effectiveness of pollution control investment funds, local authorities must intensify their evaluations of investment projects, tailor investment plans to the unique characteristics of the region, and augment their oversight and monitoring of plan execution. Simultaneously, it is imperative to contemplate integrating the pollution mitigation level into the all-encompassing appraisal framework of economic and societal progress in every locality. This would ensure that the impact of pollution control investment is one of the pivotal assessment benchmarks for regional authorities. To prevent local officials from being trapped in the “GDP growth” mindset, it is essential to introduce measures that discourage industries with high pollution and energy consumption even if they offer economic benefits. As mentioned earlier, countries can customize their environmental tax objectives and standards to suit their specific circumstances and implement these policies nationwide. A cohesive national environmental tax strategy can effectively deter businesses from exploiting regional tax and policy differences to relocate their polluting industries. Additionally, the central government plays a crucial role in coordinating efforts and managing potential competition among regional governments. By adopting these approaches, countries can strike a balance between economic development and environmental protection, avoiding the negative impacts that unsustainable industries may have on the green economy.