Next Article in Journal
A Pre-Separation and All-Neural Beamformer Framework for Multi-Channel Speech Separation
Next Article in Special Issue
A Novel GDMD-PROMETHEE Algorithm Based on the Maximizing Deviation Method and Social Media Data Mining for Large Group Decision Making
Previous Article in Journal
Constraining Coupling Constants’ Variation with Supernovae, Quasars, and GRBs
Previous Article in Special Issue
Novel Complex Pythagorean Fuzzy Sets under Aczel–Alsina Operators and Their Application in Multi-Attribute Decision Making
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Confidence Levels-Based Cubic Fermatean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators and Their Application to MCDM Problems

1
School of Mathematics, Thapar Institute of Engineering & Technology, Deemed University, Patiala 147004, Punjab, India
2
Department of Mathematics, Graphic Era Deemed to be University, Dehradun 248002, Uttarakhand, India
3
Applied Science Research Center, Applied Science Private University, Amman 11931, Jordan
4
Department of Mathematics, Hazara University Mansehra, Mansehra 21120, Pakistan
5
College of Vestsjaelland South, Herrestraede 11, 4200 Slagelse, Denmark
6
Department of Statistics & Operations Research, College of Sciences King Saud University, Riyadh 11451, Saudi Arabia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Symmetry 2023, 15(2), 260; https://doi.org/10.3390/sym15020260
Submission received: 25 December 2022 / Revised: 7 January 2023 / Accepted: 13 January 2023 / Published: 17 January 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Research on Fuzzy Logic and Mathematics with Applications II)

Abstract

:
Assessment specialists (experts) are sometimes expected to provide two types of information: knowledge of rating domains and the performance of rating objects (called confidence levels). Unfortunately, the results of previous information aggregation studies cannot be properly used to combine the two categories of data covered above. Additionally, a significant range of symmetric/asymmetric events and structures are frequently included in the implementation process or practical use of fuzzy systems. The primary goal of the current study was to use cubic Fermatean fuzzy set features to address such situations. To deal with the ambiguous information of the aggregated arguments, we defined information aggregation operators with confidence degrees. Two of the aggregation operators we initially proposed were the confidence cubic Fermatean fuzzy weighted averaging (CCFFWA) operator and the confidence cubic Fermatean fuzzy weighted geometric (CCFFWG) operator. They were used as a framework to create an MCDM process, which was supported by an example to show how effective and applicable it is. The comparison of computed results was carried out with the help of existing approaches.

1. Introduction

Researchers working in the general area of fuzzy decision-making have drawn inspiration from the Bellman–Zadeh conception of a symmetrical decision model in an uncertain environment, with complete symmetry between constraints and decision variables. A significant range of symmetric/asymmetric events and structures is frequently included in the implementation process or practical use of fuzzy systems. Multi-criteria decision-making (MCDM) is one of the fast-developing active research problems for obtaining conclusive results in a reasonable time. However, due to different restrictions, it is not always possible to express the requirements precisely, hence the corresponding solutions are not always optimal. The intuitionistic fuzzy set (IFS) [1] theory is one of the most effective and promising strategies scholars usually apply to manage the ambiguity and imprecision of information. In this context, different scholars focus more on IFSs for integrating the different alternatives using various aggregation algorithms. The performances of the criteria for alternatives are aggregated throughout the data synthesis process using weighted and ordered weighted aggregation operators (AOs) [2,3]. In an IFS environment, Xu and Yager [4] presented a geometric aggregation operator (GAO) while Xu [5] proposed a weighted averaging aggregation operator (AAO). Wang and Liu [6] proposed Einstein aggregation operators by using Einstein norm operations in the IFS context. Lai et al. [7] presented a matching algorithm based on similarity measures and adaptive weights. Ye [8] proposed an accuracy function (ac) for interval-valued IFS to compare them to interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy numbers. Garg [9] presented a series of communicating AOs for IFSs. Garg [10,11] introduced interacting geometric operators employing Einstein t-norm and Einstein t-conorm operations to aggregate intuitionistic fuzzy data. Xu et al. [12] introduced the intuitionistic fuzzy Einstein–Choquet integral-based operators for decision-making (DM) problems. According to the results of the research mentioned above, they are legitimate as long as the sum of the membership grades does not exceed one. However, in real life, it is not always possible to communicate one’s preferences within this restriction. For instance, if someone were to review an option according to their preferences, they would give it a satisfaction rating of 0.7 and an unsatisfaction rating of 0.6. As a result, the review would be unable to meet the IFS condition, as 0.7 + 0.6 > 1 . Because the effectiveness cannot be tested under these circumstances, the IFS theory has some limits and disadvantages. To address these issues, Yager [13,14] introduced Pythagorean fuzzy sets (PFSs) as an extension of the IFS theory. PFSs relax the limitations of IFS. Furthermore, it has been demonstrated that all intuitionistic fuzzy values are part of Pythagorean fuzzy values, which specifies that PFSs have superior ability to manage ambiguous issues (See Figure 1). Following his pioneering work, scholars are continually attempting to improve PFSs. According to Yager and Abbasov [15], Pythagorean fuzzy grades are subclasses of complex numbers. Moreover, Zhang and Xu [16] provided a method for determining the optimal alternative based on an ideal solution in a Pythagorean fuzzy environment. Yager [14] presented a series of aggregation operators in a PFS environment. Peng and Yang [17] defined some basic operational laws and their related properties for Pythagorean fuzzy numbers. Garg presented correlation and correlation coefficients for PFSs. Geo and Deng [18] proposed a Pythagorean fuzzy generation technique based on probability negativity to handle MCDM problems. Zhang [19] presented the notions of interval-valued PFSs (IVPFSs) by extending PFSs. Some important properties of IVPFSs were presented by Peng and Yang [20]. To relax the limitations of PFSs, Senapati and Yager [21] proposed Fermatean fuzzy sets (FFSs) and some operational laws of FFSs. Senapati and Yager [22] proposed weighted averaging and weighted geometric aggregation operators under an FFS environment. Rani and Mishra proposed interval-valued FFSs.
According to the available research, fuzzy sets, IFS, PFS, and their corresponding implementations are the main topics of all current research. Later on, Jun et al. proposed cubic sets (CSs) by integrating fuzzy sets and interval-valued fuzzy sets. Kaur and Garg [23] presented cubic IFSs and a series of AOs based on t-norm operations. Khan et al. [24,25] suggested CS operations and their characteristics. Abbas et al. [26] proposed cubic PFSs (CPFSs) by combining PFSs and IVPFSs for solving MCDM problems. The flaws and ambiguities of CPFSs were investigated by Amin et al. [27]. Rahim et al. [28] proposed Bonferroni mean aggregation operators under a CPFS environment. Rong and Mishra [29] proposed cubic FFSs and their application in MCDM problems.
Despite the popularity of the aforementioned work, the level of confidence in the criteria was not assessed in any of the studies described above. To put it another way, every researcher has approached the studies with the premise that decision-makers are unquestionably competent in the subjects being investigated. However, these types of prerequisites are only partially accomplished in real-world situations. To compensate for this limitation, decision-makers may examine the alternatives in terms of cubic Fermatean fuzzy numbers (CFFNs) and their associated confidence levels based on their familiarity with the evaluation. As a result, during the evaluation of the alternative in terms of CFFNs, the present study proposes the concept of confidence levels in the optimization processes. First, some basic operations such as P-union (rep. P-intersection), R-union (rep. R-intersection) and so on are defined. Based on these investigations a series of weighted and geometric operators and are proposed in this paper. Additionally, a method to address MCDM issues is suggested. The following is a summary of the study’s primary goals:
(1)
Define some basic operations of CFFSs and their properties.
(2)
Based on these operational laws, propose a series of aggregation operators with confidence levels in a CFFS environment.
(3)
Develop a new approach to solve MCDM problems under CFFSs.
(4)
Provide an example to evaluate the accuracy and reliability of the proposed approach.
(5)
Compare the results of the proposed framework with some existing approaches.

2. Preliminaries

In this section, we briefly present some concepts of PFS, IVPFS, and others to understand the paper.

2.1. PFSs, IVPFSs, and CPFSs

Definition 1
Ref. [13]. Let F be a non-empty finite set. A PFS over element t F is defined as
A = { t ,   φ A ( t ) ,   ψ A ( t ) | t F } ,
where φ A ( t ) [ 0 ,   1 ] and ψ A ( t ) [ 0 , 1 ] are the membership and non-membership function of an element t F such that  ( φ A ( t ) ) 2 + ( ψ A ( t ) ) 2 1 .
For convenience, Zhang and Xu [16] called φ A ( t ) ,   ψ A ( t ) a PFN denoted by φ A , ψ A . The score function of A can be calculated as s c ( A ) = φ A 2 ψ A 2 .
Definition 2
Ref. [19]. For a non-empty set F , an IVPFS over an element t F is defined as follows:
B = { t , φ ˜ B ( t ) ,   ψ ˜ B ( t ) | t F } ,
where φ ˜ B ( t ) and ψ ˜ B ( t ) are interval-valued fuzzy numbers representing the interval membership and non-membership grades of set B , respectively. Let φ ˜ B ( t ) = [ φ ˜ B L ( t ) , φ ˜ B U ( t ) ] and ψ ˜ B ( t ) = [ ψ ˜ B L ( t ) , ψ ˜ B U ( t ) ] then IVPFS can be written as B = { t , [ φ ˜ B L ( t ) , φ ˜ B U ( t ) ] , [ ψ ˜ B L ( t ) , ψ ˜ B U ( t ) ] | t F } .
For convenience, we denote these pairs as [ φ ˜ B L , φ ˜ B U ] , [ ψ ˜ B L , ψ ˜ B U ] and call this an interval-valued PFN (IVPFN). We also set, 0 φ ˜ B L , φ ˜ B U , ψ ˜ B L , ψ ˜ B U 1 such that ( φ ˜ B U ) 2 + ( ψ ˜ B U ) 2 1 . The score function of B can be calculated as s c ( B ) = 1 2 ( ( φ ˜ B L ) 2 + ( φ ˜ B U ) 2 ( ψ ˜ B L ) 2 ( φ ˜ B U ) 2 ) .
Definition 3
Refs. [26,27]. Let F be a non-empty finite set. A CPFS over an element t F is defined as
C = { t , ˜ C ( t ) , A C ( t ) | t F } ,
where ˜ C ( t ) = ( [ φ ˜ ˜ c L ( t ) , φ ˜ ˜ c U ( t ) ] , [ ψ ˜ ˜ c L ( t ) , ψ ˜ ˜ c U ( t ) ] ) represents an IVPFS while A C ( t ) = ( φ ˜ C ( t ) , ψ ˜ C ( t ) ) represents a PFS. We also set, 0 φ ˜ ˜ c L ( t ) , φ ˜ ˜ c U ( t ) , ψ ˜ ˜ c L ( t ) , ψ ˜ ˜ c U ( t ) 1 such that ( φ ˜ ˜ c U ( t ) ) 2 + ( ψ ˜ ˜ c U ( t ) ) 2 1 .
For convenience, we denote the pairs as [ φ ˜ ˜ c L , φ ˜ ˜ c U ] , [ ψ ˜ ˜ c L , ψ ˜ ˜ c U ] , φ ˜ C , ψ ˜ C and call this a CPFN.
Definition 4
Ref. [28]. Let C 1 = ( [ φ C 1 L ,   φ C 1 U ] ,   [ ψ C 1 L , ψ C 1 U ] ,   φ C 1 ,   ψ C 1 ) be a CPFN, then the score function is defined under R-order as
s c ( C 1 ) = ( φ C 1 L ) 2 + ( φ C 1 L ) 2 ( ψ C 1 L ) 2 ( ψ C 1 L ) 2 2 + ( ψ C 1 ) 2 ( φ C 1 ) 2 ,
and for P-order as
s c ( C 1 ) = ( φ C 1 L ) 2 + ( φ C 1 L ) 2 ( ψ C 1 L ) 2 ( ψ C 1 L ) 2 2 + ( φ C 1 ) 2 ( ψ C 1 ) 2 ,
where  2 s c ( β 1 ) 2 .
Definition 5
Ref. [28]. Let C 1 = ( [ φ C 1 L ,   φ C 1 U ] ,   [ ψ C 1 L , ψ C 1 U ] ,   φ C 1 ,   ψ C 1 ) be a CPFN, then the accuracy function is defined as
a c ( C 1 ) = ( φ C 1 L ) 2 + ( φ C 1 L ) 2 + ( ψ C 1 L ) 2 + ( ψ C 1 L ) 2 2 + ( φ C 1 ) 2 + ( ψ C 1 ) 2 ,
where  0 a c ( C 1 ) 2 .
Definition 6
Ref. [28]. Let  C 1 = ( [ φ C 1 L ,   φ C 1 U ] ,   [ ψ C 1 L , ψ C 1 U ] ,   φ C 1 ,   ψ C 1 )  and C 2 = ( [ φ C 2 L ,   φ C 2 U ] ,   [ ψ C 2 L , ψ C 2 U ] ,   φ C 2 ,   ψ C 2 )  be two CPFSs in F . Then:
  • (Equality): C 1 = C 2 , if and only if  [ φ C 1 L ,   φ C 1 U ] = [ φ C 2 L ,   φ C 2 U ] , ψ C 1 L , ψ C 1 U = ψ C 2 L , ψ C 2 U , φ C 1 = φ C 2  and  ψ C 1 = ψ C 2 ;
  • (P-order): C 1 P C 2 if [ φ C 1 L ,   φ C 1 U ] [ φ C 2 L ,   φ C 2 U ] , [ ψ C 1 L ,   ψ C 1 U ] [ ψ C 2 L ,   ψ C 2 U ] ,   φ C 1 φ C 2  and  ψ C 1 ψ C 2 ;
  • (R-order): C 1 R C 2 if [ φ C 1 L ,   φ C 1 U ] [ φ C 2 L ,   φ C 2 U ] , [ ψ C 1 L ,   ψ C 1 U ] [ ψ C 2 L ,   ψ C 2 U ] ,   φ C 1 φ C 2  and  ψ C 1 ψ C 2 .
Definition 7
Ref. [27]. For the CPFNs  C i = ( [ φ C i L ,   φ C i U ] ,   [ ψ C i L , ψ C i U ] ,   φ C i ,   ψ C i )   ( 1 ,   2 ,   3 ,   4 )  we have:
(a)
If C 1 P C 2 and C 2 P C 3 then C 1 P C 3 ;
(b)
If C 1 P C 2 then C 2 c P C 1 c :
(c)
If C 1 P C 2   and C 1 P C 3 then C 1 P C 2 C 3 ;
(d)
If C 1 P C 2 and C 3 P C 4 then C 1 C 3 P C 2 C 4 and C 1 C 3 P C 2 C 4 ;
(e)
If C 1 P C 2 and C 3 P C 2 then C 1 C 3 P C 2 ;
(f)
If C 1 R C 2 and C 2 R C 3 then C 1 R C 3 ;
(g)
If C 1 R C 2 then C 2 c R C 1 c ;
(h)
If C 1 R C 2   and C 1 R C 3 then C 1 R C C 3 ;
(i)
If C 1 R C 2 and C 3 R C 4 then C 1 C 3 R C 2 C 4 and C 1 C 3 R C 2 C 4 ;
(j)
If C 1 R C 2 and C 3 R C 2 then C 1 C 3 R C 2 .

2.2. FFSs, IVFFSs, and CFFSs

Definition 8
Ref. [21]. Let F be a non-empty set and t F . The FFS over element t is defined as
= { t , φ ( t ) , ψ ( t ) | t F } ,
where φ ( t ) [ 0 ,   1 ] and ψ ( t ) [ 0 , 1 ] are the membership and non-membership function of an element t F such that ( φ ( t ) ) 3 + ( ψ ( t ) ) 3 1 .
For convenience, Senapati and Yager [21] called φ ( t ) ,   ψ ( t ) an FFN denoted by φ , ψ . The score function of A can be calculated as s c ( A ) = φ 3 ψ 3 .
Definition 9
Ref. [30]. For a non-empty set F , an interval-valued FFS (IVFFS) over an element t F is defined as follows:
G = { t , φ ˜ G ( t ) ,   ψ ˜ G ( t ) | t F } ,
where φ ˜ G ( t ) and ψ ˜ G ( t ) are interval-valued fuzzy numbers representing the interval membership and non-membership grades of the set G repectively. Let φ ˜ G ( t ) = [ φ ˜ G L ( t ) , φ ˜ G U ( t ) ] and ψ ˜ G ( t ) = [ ψ ˜ G L ( t ) , ψ ˜ G U ( t ) ] then IVPFS can be written as G = { t , [ φ ˜ G L ( t ) , φ ˜ G U ( t ) ] , [ ψ ˜ G L ( t ) , ψ ˜ G U ( t ) ] | t F } .
For convenience, we denote these pairs as [ φ ˜ G L , φ ˜ G U ] , [ ψ ˜ G L , ψ ˜ G U ] and call this an interval-valued FFN (IVFFN). We also set, 0 φ ˜ G L , φ ˜ G U , ψ ˜ G L , ψ ˜ G U 1 such that ( φ ˜ G U ) 3 + ( ψ ˜ G U ) 3 1 . The score function of G can be calculated as s c ( B ) = 1 2 ( ( φ ˜ B L ) 3 + ( φ ˜ B U ) 3 ( ψ ˜ B L ) 3 ( φ ˜ B U ) 3 ) .
Definition 10
Ref. [29]. Let F be a non-empty finite set. A CPFS over an element t F is defined as
= { t , G ( t ) , ( t ) | t F } ,
where  G ( t ) = ( [ φ ˜ L ( t ) , φ ˜ U ( t ) ] , [ ψ ˜ L ( t ) , ψ ˜ U ( t ) ] )  represents an IVFFS while  ( t ) = ( φ ( t ) , ψ ( t ) )  represents PFS. We also set,  0 φ ˜ L ( t ) , φ ˜ U ( t ) , ψ ˜ L ( t ) , ψ ˜ U ( t ) 1  such that  ( φ ˜ U ( t ) ) 2 + ( ψ ˜ U ( t ) ) 2 1 .
For convenience, we denote the pairs as [ φ ˜ L , φ ˜ U ] , [ ψ ˜ L , ψ ˜ U ] , φ , ψ and call this a CPFN.

3. New Operational Laws and Aggregation Operators under CFFSs with Confidence Levels

In this section, the existing operations defined by Rong et al. [29] are modified. Furthermore, the order relations such as P-order and R-order of CFFNs are presented. Finally, based on these modified operations some series aggregation operators with confidence levels are proposed.

3.1. Modified Operations of CFFSs

Definition 11.
For a family of CFFS { i ,   i Δ } , it follows that
(a)
(P-union): i Δ P i = ( [ m a x i Δ ( φ i L ) ,   m a x i Δ ( φ i U ) ] ,   [ m i n i Δ ( ψ i L ) ,   m i n i Δ ( ψ i U ) ] , m a x i Δ μ i , m i n i Δ ν i ) ;
(b)
(P-intersection): i Δ R i = ( [ m i n i Δ ( φ i L ) ,   m i n i Δ ( φ i U ) ] ,   [ m a x i Δ ( ψ i L ) ,   m a x i Δ ( ψ i U ) ] , m i n i Δ μ i , m a x i Δ ν i ) ;
(c)
(R-union): i Δ R i = ( [ m a x i Δ ( φ i L ) ,   m a x i Δ ( φ i U ) ] ,   [ m i n i Δ ( ψ i L ) , m i n i Δ ( ψ i U ) ] , m i n i Δ μ i , m a x i Δ ν i ) ;
(d)
(R-intersection): i Δ P i = ( [ m a x i Δ ( φ i L ) ,   m a x i Δ ( φ i U ) ] ,   [ m i n i Δ ( ψ i L ) ,   m i n i Δ ( ψ i U ) ] , m i n i Δ φ i , m a x i Δ ψ i ) .
Definition 12.
Let  1 = ( [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] ,   [ ψ 1 L , ψ 1 U ] ,   φ 1 ,   ψ 1 )  and 2 = ( [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] ,   [ ψ 2 L , ψ 2 U ] ,   φ 2 ,   ψ 2 )  be two CFFSs in F . Then
(a)
(Equality): 1 = 2 , if and only if  [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] = [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] , [ ψ 1 L ,   ψ 1 U ] = [ ψ 2 L ,   ψ 2 U ] , φ 1 = φ 2  and  ψ 1 = ψ 2 :
(b)
(P-order): 1 P 2  if  [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] , [ ψ 1 L ,   ψ 1 U ] [ ψ 2 L ,   ψ 2 U ] , φ 1 φ 2  and  ψ 1 ψ 2 ;
(c)
(R-order): 1 R 2  if  [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] , [ ψ 1 L ,   ψ 1 U ] [ ψ 2 L ,   ψ 2 U ] , φ 1 φ 2  and  ψ 1 ψ 2 .
Definition 13.
Let  1 = ( [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] ,   [ ψ 1 L , ψ 1 U ] ,   φ 1 ,   ψ 1 )  be a CFFN, then the score function is defined under R-order as
s c ( 1 ) = ( φ 1 L ) 3 + ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( ψ 1 L ) 3 ( ψ 1 U ) 3 2 + ( ψ 1 3 φ 1 3 ) ,
and for P-order as
s c ( 1 ) = ( φ 1 L ) 3 + ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( ψ 1 L ) 3 ( ψ 1 U ) 3 2 + ( φ 1 3 ψ 1 3 ) ,
where  2 s c ( 1 ) 2 .
Definition 14.
Let  1 = ( [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] ,   [ ψ 1 L , ψ 1 U ] ,   φ 1 ,   ψ 1 )  be a CFFN, then the accuracy function is defined under R-order as
a c ( 1 ) = ( φ 1 L ) 3 + ( φ 1 U ) 3 + ( ψ 1 L ) 3 + ( ψ 1 U ) 3 2 + ( φ 1 3 + ψ 1 3 ) ,
where  0 a c ( 1 ) 2 .
Theorem 1.
For the CPFNs i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i )   ( 1 ,   2 ,   3 ,   4 ) we have:
(a)
If 1 P 2 and 2 P 3 then 1 P 3 ;
(b)
If 1 P 2 then 2 c P 1 c ;
(c)
If 1 P 2   and 1 P 3 then 1 P 2 3 ;
(d)
If 1 P 2 and 3 P 4 then 1 3 P 2 4 and 1 3 P 2 4 ;
(e)
If 1 P 2 and 3 P 2 then 1 3 P 2 ;
(f)
If 1 R 2 and 2 R 3 then 1 R 3 ;
(g)
If 1 R 2 then 2 c R 1 c ;
(h)
If 1 R 2   and 1 R 3 then 1 R 2 3 ;
(i)
If 1 R 2 and 3 R 4 then 1 3 R 2 4 and 1 3 R 2 4 ;
(j)
If 1 R 2 and 3 R 2 then 1 3 R 2 .
Proof. 
(a) Since 1 = ( [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] ,   [ ψ 1 L , ψ 1 U ] ,   φ 1 ,   ψ 1 ) , 2 = ( [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] ,   [ ψ 2 L , ψ 2 U ] ,   φ 2 ,   ψ 2 ) , and 3 = ( [ φ 3 L ,   φ 3 U ] ,   [ ψ 3 L , ψ 3 U ] ,   φ 3 ,   ψ 3 ) be CPFNs. Using Definition 12, if 1 P 2 then [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] , [ ψ 1 L ,   ψ 1 U ] [ ψ 2 L ,   ψ 2 U ] , φ 1 φ 2 , and ψ 1 ψ 2 . Similarly, if 2 P 3 , then [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] [ φ 3 L ,   φ 3 U ] , [ ψ 2 L ,   ψ 2 U ] [ ψ 3 L ,   ψ 3 U ] , φ 2 φ 3 , and ψ 2 ψ 3 which implies that [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] [ φ 3 L ,   φ 3 U ] ; [ ψ 1 L ,   ψ 1 U ] [ ψ 2 L ,   ψ 2 U ] [ ψ 3 L ,   ψ 3 U ] ; φ 1 φ 2 φ 3 ; and ψ 1 ψ 2 ψ 3 and hence [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] [ φ 3 L ,   φ 3 U ] ; [ ψ 1 L ,   ψ 1 U ] [ ψ 3 L ,   ψ 3 U ] ; φ 1 φ 3 ; and ψ 1 ψ 3 . Therefore, if 1 P 2 and 2 P 3 , then 1 P 3 . Similarly, for the others. □
Definition 15.
Let  = ( [ φ L , φ U   ] ,   [ ψ L ,   ψ U ] ,   φ , ψ ) and  i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i )   ( i = 1 , 2 ) be the collections of CFFNs, and ζ 0 be a real number then
(a)
1 2 = ( [ 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) 3 , 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) 3 ] ,   [ i = 1 2 ψ i L ,   i 2 ψ i U ]   , i = 1 2 φ i , 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 )   3 ) ;
(b)
1 2 = ( [ i = 1 2 φ i L ,   i 2 φ i U ] ,   [ 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( ψ i L ) 3 ) 3 , 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( ψ i U ) 3 ) 3 ] , 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( φ i ) 3 ) 3 , i = 1 2 ψ i ) ;
(c)
ζ = ( [ 1 ( 1 ( φ L ) 3 ) ζ 3 ,   1 ( 1 ( φ U ) 3 ) ζ 3 ] ,   [ ( ψ L ) ζ ,   ( ψ U ) ζ ] , φ ζ , 1 ( 1 ψ 3 ) ζ 3 ) ;
(d)
ζ = ( [ ( φ L ) ζ ,   ( φ U ) ζ ] ,   [ 1 ( 1 ( ψ L ) 3 ) ζ 3 ,   1 ( 1 ( ψ U ) 3 ) ζ 3 ] , 1 ( 1 φ 3 ) ζ 3 , φ ζ ) .
Theorem 2.
For two CFFNs 1 = ( [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] ,   [ ψ 1 L , ψ 1 U ] ,   φ 1 ,   ψ 1 )  and 2 = ( [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] ,   [ ψ 2 L , ψ 2 U ] ,   φ 2 ,   ψ 2 ) , provided ζ 0 is a real number, then 1 2 , 1 2 , ζ , and ζ 1 are also CFFNs.
Proof. 
Since 1 = ( [ φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U ] ,   [ ψ 1 L , ψ 1 U ] ,   φ 1 ,   ψ 1 ) and 2 = ( [ φ 2 L ,   φ 2 U ] ,   [ ψ 2 L , ψ 2 U ] ,   φ 2 ,   ψ 2 ) are two CFFNs such that 0 φ 1 L ,   φ 1 U , ψ 1 L , ψ i U ,   φ 2 L , φ 2 U ,   ψ 2 L , ψ 2 U 1 and ( φ 1 U ) 3 + ( ψ 1 U ) 3 1 this implies that 0 ( 1 ( φ 1 L ) 3 ) ( 1 ( φ 1 L ) 3 ) 1 and hence 0 ( φ 1 L ) 3 + ( φ 2 L ) 3 ( φ 1 L ) 3 ( φ i L ) 3 3 1 . Similarly, we can prove that 0 ( φ 2 L ) 3 + ( φ 2 L ) 3 ( φ 2 L ) 3 ( φ 2 L ) 3 3 1 , 0 ψ 1 L ψ 2 L 1 and 0 ψ 1 U ψ 2 U 1 . We also set, 0 φ 1 ,   ψ 2 ,   φ 1 , ψ 2 1 and φ 1 3 + ψ 1 3 1 , φ 2 3 + ψ 2 3 1 , which implies that φ 1 φ 2 1 and φ 1 3 + φ 2 3 φ 1 3 μ 2 3 3 1 .
Finally, we have
( φ 1 U ) 3 + ( φ 2 U ) 3 ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( φ 2 U ) 3 + ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( φ 2 U ) 3 3 = 1 ( 1 ( φ 1 U ) 3 ) ( 1 ( φ 2 U ) 3 ) + ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( φ 2 U ) 3 3 1 ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( φ 2 U ) 3 + ( φ 1 U ) 3 ( φ 2 U ) 3 3 1 ,
and
φ 1 φ 2 + ψ 1 3 + ψ 2 3 ( ψ 1 U ) 3 ( ψ 1 U ) 3 3 = φ 1 φ 2 + 1 ( 1 ( φ 1 U ) 3 ) ( 1 ( φ 2 U ) 3 ) 3 φ 1 φ 2 + 1 φ 1 φ 2 3 1 .
Therefore, 1 2 is a CFFN. Furthermore, for any positive real number ψ and CFFN β = ( [ φ L ,   φ U ] ,   [ ψ L ,   ψ U ] ,   φ , ψ ) , we have 0 φ ζ 1 , 0 1 ( 1 ( φ ) 3 ) ζ 3 1 , 0 ( ψ L ) ζ ( ψ U ) ζ 1 and 0 1 ( 1 ( φ L ) 3 ) ζ ( 1 ( φ U ) 3 ) ζ 3 1 . Hence ζ is also a CFFN. Similarly, we can prove that 1 2 and ζ are also CFFNs. □

3.2. Cubic Fermatean AOs with Confidence Levels

In the available studies, all scholars have approached the studies by taking the postulation that decision-makers are confident in using the estimated objects. However, these kinds of prerequisites are only partially met in real-world situations. To address this problem, in this section we propose a set of averaging and geometric operators with different confidence levels in a cubic Fermatean fuzzy environment. Those are named confidence cubic Fermatean fuzzy weighted averaging (CCFFWA) operator and confidence cubic Fermatean fuzzy weighted geometric (CCFFWG) operator.

3.2.1. Weighted Averaging Operators

Definition 16.
A CCFFWA operator is a mapping  CCFFWA : Γ p Γ  defined as
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) = σ 1 ( ξ 1 1 ) σ 2 ( ξ 2 2 ) σ p ( ξ p p )
where Γ is the collection of CPFNs with confidence level i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i , σ i )   for i = 1 , 2 , , p ; ξ = ( ξ 1 ,   ξ 2 , , ξ p ) T is the weight vector of ξ i such that ξ i > 0 and i = 1 n ξ i = 1 ; and σ i are the confidence levels of the CFFNs i .
Theorem 3.
For the group of CCFFNs 1 ,   2 , , n , the value obtained via CCFFWA is a CFFN, which can be calculated as
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 p ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 p ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
Proof. 
We apply induction principle on 1 ,   2 , , P
Step 1 For p = 2 , using Definition 15, we get
CCFFWA ( 1 , 2 ) = σ 1 ξ 1 1 σ 2 ξ 2 2
= ( [ 1 ( 1 ( φ 1 L ) 3 ) σ 1 ξ 1 ( 1 ( φ 2 L ) 3 ) σ 2 ξ 2 3 , 1 ( 1 ( φ 1 U ) 3 ) σ 1 ξ 1 ( 1 ( φ 2 L ) 3 ) σ 2 ξ 2 3   ] , [ ( ψ 1 L ) σ 1 ξ 1 ( ψ 2 L ) σ 2 ξ 2 , ( ψ 1 U ) σ 1 ξ 1 ( ψ 2 U ) σ 2 ξ 2 ] , ( φ 1 ) σ 1 ξ 1 ( φ 2 ) σ 2 ξ 2 , 1 ( 1 ψ 1 3 ) σ 1 ξ 1 ( 1 ψ 1 3 ) σ 1 ξ 1 3 )
= ( [ 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 2 ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 2 ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 2 ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 2 ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
Hence, it holds for P = 2 .
Step 2 Assume Equation (14) holds for p = κ , then
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , k ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 k ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 k ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 k ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 k ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 k ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 k ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
Step 3 For p = κ + 1 , we have
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , κ , κ + 1 ) = 1 2 . κ κ + 1
= ( [ 1 i = 1 κ ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 κ ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 κ ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 κ ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 κ ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 κ ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) ( [ 1 ( 1 ( φ κ + 1 L ) 3 ) σ κ + 1 ξ κ + 1 3 , 1 ( 1 ( φ κ + 1 U ) 3 ) σ κ + 1 ξ κ + 1 3   ] , [ ( ψ κ + 1 L ) σ κ + 1 ξ κ + 1 , ( ψ κ + 1 U ) σ κ + 1 ξ κ + 1 ] , ( φ κ + 1 ) σ κ + 1 ξ κ + 1 , 1 ( 1 ( ψ κ + 1 ) 3 ) σ κ + 1 ξ κ + 1 3 ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 κ + 1 ( 1 ( φ i 3 ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 κ + 1 ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 κ + 1 ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 κ + 1 ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 κ + 1 ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 κ + 1 ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
As a result, the result is valid for p = κ + 1 , and hence
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 p ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 p ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
The proof is completed. □
Example 1.
Let  1 = ( [ 0.4 , 0.6 ] , [ 0.3.0.7 ] , ( 0.3 , 0.5 ) ; 0.8 ) , 2 = ( [ 0.5 , 0.6 ] , [ 0.4.0.5 ] , ( 0.2 , 0.4 ) ; 0.7 ) ,  and  3 = ( [ 0.2 , 0.3 ] , [ 0.4.0.5 ] , ( 0.7 , 0.2 ) ; 0.6 )  be three CFFNs with confidence levels and  ξ = ( 0.25 , 0.35 , 0.4 )  be their corresponding weight vector then
1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 1 ( 0.5 ) 3 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.2 ) 3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) ) ) 1 3 = 0.3602 ;
1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.6 ) 3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 1 ( 0.6 ) 3 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.3 ) 3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) ) ) 1 3 = 0.477 ;
i = 1 3 ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 0.4 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.4 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) = 0.5040 ;
i = 1 3 ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.7 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 0.5 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.6 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) = 0.6653 ;
i = 1 p ( φ i ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 0.2 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.7 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) = 0.4864 ;
1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.5 ) 3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 1 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.2 ) 3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) ) ) 1 / 3 = 0.3526 .
Thus, using Equation (14) we get
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , 3 ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 3 ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 3 ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 3 ( φ i ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) = ( [ 0.3602 , 0.4770 ] , [ 0.5040.0.6653 ] , 0.4864 ,   0.3526 ) .
According to Theorem 3, the CCFFWA operator fulfils the certain properties listed below.
Property 1.
For  i =   i = 1 , 2 , , p , where  = ( [ φ L ,   φ u ] ,   [ ψ L ,   ψ U ] ,   φ , ψ ) , it follows that  CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) = . This property is called idempotency.
Proof. 
As ξ i 0 , I = 1 n ξ i = 1 and ξ i = ξ for all i , then
CCFFWA ( ,   , , ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 p ( ψ L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( ψ U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 p ( φ ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) = ( [ 1 ( 1 ( φ L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i ,   1 ( 1 ( φ U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i ] ,   [ ( ψ L ) ξ i σ i , ( ψ U ) ξ i σ i   ] , ( φ ) ξ i σ i , 1 ( 1 ( ψ ) 3 ) ξ i σ i ) = ( [ φ L ,   φ u ] ,   [ ψ L ,   ψ U ] ,   φ , ψ ) = .
Property 2.
Let  i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i )  and  ˜ i = ( [ φ ˜ i L ,   φ ˜ i U ] ,   [ ψ ˜ i L , ψ ˜ i U ] ,   φ ˜ i ,   ψ ˜ i )  be CCFFNs where ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) , such that  i ˜ i , then
CPFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) CCFFWA ( ˜ 1 ,   ˜ 2 , , ˜ p ) .
This property is called monotonicity.
Proof. 
First let us express the term of CCFFN as follows:
1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = α ,   1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = β , i = 1 p ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i = γ ,   i = 1 p ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i = δ , i = 1 p ( φ i ) ξ i σ i = ε ,   1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ζ , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ ˜ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = α ˜ ,   1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ ˜ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = β ˜ , i = 1 p ( ψ ˜ i L ) ξ i σ i = γ ˜ ,   i = 1 p ( ψ ˜ i L ) ξ i σ i = δ ˜ , i = 1 p ( φ ˜ i ) ξ i σ i = ε ˜   and   1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ ˜ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ζ ˜ .
Also, i ˜ i for all i , then we have φ i L φ ˜ i L , φ i U φ ˜ i U , ψ i L ψ ˜ i L , ψ i U ψ ˜ i U ; φ i φ ˜ i and ψ i ψ ˜ i , then we have α α ˜ , β β ˜ , γ γ ˜ , δ δ ˜ , ε ε ˜ , and ζ ζ ˜ . Therefore, using the score function defined in Definition 10 and 11, we have
s c ( CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) ) = α 3 + β 3 γ 3 δ 3 2 + ( ζ 3 ε 3 ) α ˜ 3 + β ˜ 3 γ ˜ 3 δ ˜ 3 2 + ( ζ ˜ 3 ε ˜ 3 ) = s c ( CCFFWA ( ˜ 1 ,   ˜ 2 , , ˜ p ) ) .
Thus, CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) CCFFWA ( ˜ 1 ,   ˜ 2 , , ˜ p ) . □
Property 3.
For any group of CCFFNs  i   ( i = 1 ,   2 , ,   p ) . If
= ( [ m i n i ( φ i L ) ,   m i n i ( φ i U ) ] ,   [ m a x i ( ψ i L ) ,   m a x i ( ψ i U ) ] ,   m a x i ( φ i ) ,   m i n i ( ψ i ) ) and + = ( [ m a x i ( φ i L ) , m a x i ( φ i U ) ] ,   [ m i n i ( ψ i L ) ,   m i n i ( ψ i U ) ] ,   m i n i ( φ i ) ,   m a x i ( ψ i ) )
then  CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) + . This property is called Boundedness.
Proof. 
As m i n i ( φ i L ) φ i L m a x i ( φ i L ) , m i n i ( φ i U ) φ i U m a x i ( φ i U ) , m i n i ( ψ i L ) ψ i L m a x i ( ψ i L ) , m i n i ( ψ i U ) ψ i U m a x i ( ψ i U ) , m i n i ( φ i ) φ i m a x i ( φ i ) , and m i n i ( ψ i ) ψ i m a x i ( ψ i ) it follows that
1 i = 1 n ( 1 m i n i ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 m a x i ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ; 1 i = 1 n ( 1 m i n i ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 m a x i ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i ; 3 i = 1 n m a x i ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i i = 1 n ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i i = 1 n m i n i ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i ; i = 1 n m a x i ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i i = 1 n ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i i = 1 n m i n i ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i ; i = 1 n m a x i ( φ i ) ξ i σ i i = 1 n ( φ i ) ξ i σ i i = 1 n m i n i ( φ i ) ξ i σ i ; 1 i = 1 n ( 1 m i n i ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 m a x i ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3
which implies that
m i n i ( φ i L ) 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 m a x i ( φ i L ) 3 ; m i n i ( φ i U ) 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 m a x i ( φ i U ) 3 ; m a x i ( ψ i L ) i = 1 n ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i m i n i ( ψ i L ) ; m a x i ( ψ i U ) i = 1 n ( ψ i U ) ξ i σ i m i n i ( ψ i U ) ; m a x i ( φ i ) i = 1 n ( φ i ) ξ i σ i m i n i ( φ i ) ; m i n i ( ψ i ) 3 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( ψ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 m a x i ( ψ i ) 3 .
Thus, CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) + . □
Property 4.
For the CCFFNs  1 ,   2 , ,   p  and  ˜ = ( [ φ ˜ ˜ L ,   φ ˜ ˜ U ] ,   [ ψ ˜ ˜ L , ψ ˜ ˜ U ] ,   φ ˜ ˜ ,   ψ ˜ ˜ ) , we have
CCFFWA ( 1 ˜ 2 ˜ p ˜ ) = CCFFWA ( 1 , 2 , , p ) ˜ .
Proof. 
Straightforward. □
Property. 5.
For a positive real number  ζ , we have
CCFFWA ( ζ 1 , ζ   2 , , ζ p ) = ζ CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) .
Proof. 
Straightforward. □

3.2.2. Ordered weighted Averaging Operator

Definition. 17.
A CCFFOWA is a mapping defined as  CCFFOWA :   Γ n Γ  on a collection of CPFNs  i , ( i = 1 , 2 , p )  as follows
CCFFOWA ( 1 ,   2 , ,   p ) = ξ 1 σ 1 δ ( 1 ) ξ 2 σ 2 β δ ( 2 )   ξ p σ p σ ( p )
where δ is a permutation of ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) , such that δ ( i 1 ) i for i = 1 , 2 , , p and ξ = ( ξ 1 , ξ 2 , ξ n ) T is its weight vector, such that ξ 0 and i = 1 p ξ i = 1 with confidence levels 0 σ i 1 . Furthermore, theith largest CFFN among i ' s is δ ( i ) .
Theorem. 4.
The value obtained by using the CCFFOWA operator for CFFNs i   ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) is again a CFFN and given by
CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 p ( ψ δ ( i ) L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( ψ δ ( i ) U ) ξ i σ i ] , i = 1 p ( φ δ ( i ) ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ δ ( i ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
Proof. 
Similar proof as Theorem 3. □
Example 2.
Let  1 = ( [ 0.3 , 0.4 ] , [ 0.2.0.3 ] , ( 0.2 , 0.6 ) ; 0.5 ) , 2 = ( [ 0.4 , 0.5 ] , [ 0.3.0.4 ] , ( 0.6 , 0.2 ) ; 0.4 ) ,  and  3 = ( [ 0.6 , 0.7 ] , [ 0.5.0.6 ] , ( 0.4 , 0.3 ) ; 0.7 )  be three CFFNs with confidence levels, and  ξ = ( 0.5 , 0.3 , 0.2 )  be their corresponding weight vector. By using Equations (10) and (11) to calculate the score values of each CFFN it follows that
s c ( 1 ) = ( 0.3 ) 3 + ( 0.4 ) 3 ( 0.2 ) 3 ( 0.3 ) 3 2 + ( ( 0.6 ) 3 ( 0.2 ) 3 ) = 0.2360 ; s c ( 2 ) = ( 0.4 ) 3 + ( 0.5 ) 3 ( 0.3 ) 3 ( 0.4 ) 3 2 + ( ( 0.2 ) 3 ( 0.6 ) 3 ) = 0.1590 ; s c ( 3 ) = ( 0.6 ) 3 + ( 0.7 ) 3 ( 0.5 ) 3 ( 0.6 ) 3 2 + ( ( 0.3 ) 3 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) = 0.0720 .
The order of these CFFNs with respect to score values is 1 3 2 .
Arrange these CFFNs with respect to score values, i.e.,
1 = ( [ 0.3 , 0.4 ] , [ 0.2.0.3 ] , ( 0.2 , 0.6 ) ; 0.5 ) , 3 = ( [ 0.6 , 0.7 ] , [ 0.5.0.6 ] , ( 0.4 , 0.3 ) ; 0.7 ) ;
and
2 = ( [ 0.4 , 0.5 ] , [ 0.3.0.4 ] , ( 0.6 , 0.2 ) ; 0.4 ) .
Therefore, δ ( 1 ) = 1 , δ ( 2 ) = 3 , and δ ( 3 ) = 2 .
Now, we have
1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.3 ) 3 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) × ( 1 ( 0.6 ) 3 ) ( 0.3 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) ) ) 1 / 3 = 0.3942 ; 1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) × ( 1 ( 0.7 ) 3 ) ( 0.3 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.5 ) 3 ) ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) ) ) 1 / 3 = 0.4777 ; i = 1 3 ( ψ δ ( i ) L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.2 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) × ( 0.5 ) ( 0.3 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.3 ) ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) = 0.5251 ; i = 1 3 ( ψ δ ( i ) L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.3 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) × ( 0.6 ) ( 0.3 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.4 ) ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) = 0.6178 ; i = 1 p ( φ δ ( i ) ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.2 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) × ( 0.4 ) ( 0.3 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.6 ) ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) = 0.5296 ; 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ δ ( i ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.6 ) 3 ) ( 0.5 ) ( 0.5 ) × ( 1 ( 0.3 ) 3 ) ( 0.3 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.2 ) 3 ) ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) ) ) 1 / 3 = 0.4021 .
Hence,
CCFFOWA ( 1 ,   2 , 3 ) = ( [ 0.3942 , 0.4777 ] , [ 0.5251.0.6178 ] , 0.5296 ,   0.4021 ) .

3.2.3. Geometric Operator

Definition 18.
A CCFFWG operator is a mapping  CCFFWG : Γ n Γ  defined as
CCFFWG ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) = 𝓌 1 1 𝓌 2 2 𝓌 p p
where  Ω  is the collection of CPFNs  i ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) , and  ξ = ( ξ 1 ,   ξ 2 , , ξ p ) T  is the weight vector of i such that  ξ i 0  and  i = 1 n ξ i = 1 . We also set, σ p be the confidence levels of CFFN p .
Theorem 5.
For  1 ,   2 , , n , the value obtained by CCFFWG is a CFFN, which is determined by
CCFFWG ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) = ( [ i = 1 p ( φ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( φ i U ) ξ i σ i ] , [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , i = 1 p ( ψ i ) ξ i σ i ) .
Proof. 
Similar to Theorem 3, therefore omitted here. □
Example 3.
Let  1 = ( [ 0.4 , 0.6 ] , [ 0.3.0.7 ] , ( 0.3 , 0.5 ) ; 0.8 ) , 2 = ( [ 0.5 , 0.6 ] , [ 0.4.0.5 ] , ( 0.2 , 0.4 ) ; 0.7 ) ,  and  3 = ( [ 0.2 , 0.3 ] , [ 0.4.0.5 ] , ( 0.7 , 0.2 ) ; 0.6 )  be three CFFNs with confidence levels and  ξ = ( 0.25 , 0.35 , 0.4 )  be their corresponding weight vector then
i = 1 3 ( φ i L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.4 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 0.5 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) = 0.4774 ; i = 1 3 ( φ i L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.6 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 0.6 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) = 0.5967 ; 1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( ψ i L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.3 ) 3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 1 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.4 ) 3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) ) ) 1 3 = 0.3328 ; 1 i = 1 3 ( 1 ( ψ i U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.7 ) 3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 1 ( 0.5 ) 3 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.5 ) 3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) ) ) 1 3 = 0.5171 ; 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = ( 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.3 ) 3 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 1 ( 0.2 ) 3 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 1 ( 0.7 ) 3 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) ) ) 1 3 = 0.4682 : i = 1 p ( ψ i ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.5 ) ( 0.25 ) ( 0.8 ) × ( 0.4 ) ( 0.35 ) ( 0.7 ) × ( 0.2 ) ( 0.4 ) ( 0.6 ) = 0.4727 .
Hence, we have
CCFFWG ( 1 ,   2 , 3 ) = ( [ 0.4774 , 0.5967 ] , [ 0.3328 ,   0.5171 ] , 0.4682 ,   0.4727 ) .

3.2.4. Ordered Weighted Geometric Operator

Definition 19.
A CPFOWG is a mapping  CPFOWG :   Γ n Γ  defined over a collection of CCFFNs  i  with confidence levels  σ i   ( i = 1 , 2 , p )  as follows
CCFFOWG ( 1 ,   2 , ,   p ) = σ I ξ 1 σ ( 1 ) σ 2 ξ 2 σ ( 2 ) σ p ξ p δ ( p )
where  δ  is a permutation of ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) , such that δ ( i 1 ) i for i = 1 , 2 , , n and ξ = ( ξ 1 , ξ 2 , ξ p ) T is its weight vector, such that ξ 0 and i = 1 n ξ i = 1 . Moreover, theith largest CFFN among i s is δ ( i ) .
Theorem 6.
The value obtained by using the CPFOWG operator for CFFNs i   ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) is again a CFFN and given by
CCFFWG ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) = ( [ i = 1 p ( φ δ ( i ) L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( φ δ ( i ) U ) ξ i σ i ] , [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , i = 1 p ( ψ δ ( i ) ) ξ i σ i ) .
Theorem 7.
Let  i ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) , a n d   ξ = ( ξ 1 ,   ξ 2 , , ξ p ) T  be the weight vector of i such that  ξ i 0  and  i = 1 p ξ i = 1 , then we have
  • CCFFWA ( 1 c ,   2 c , , p c ) = ( CPFWG ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) ) c ;
  • CCFFWG ( 1 c ,   2 c , , p c ) = ( CPFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) ) c .
Proof. 
Since i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i ) and i c = (   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   ψ i ,   φ i ) , then using Equation (17), we have
CCFFWA ( 1 c ,   2 c , , p c ) = ( [ i = 1 n ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 n ( ψ i L ) ξ i σ i ] ,   [ 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i L ) 2 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i L ) 2 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( ψ i ) 2 ) ξ i σ i 3 , i = 1 n ( φ i ) ξ i σ i ) = ( CCFFWG ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) ) c .
Similarly, we can prove that CCFFWG ( 1 c ,   2 c , , p c ) = ( CCPFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) ) c . □
Theorem 8.
Let  i ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) , and ξ = ( ξ 1 ,   ξ 2 , , ξ p ) T  be the weight vector of i such that  ξ i 0  and  i = 1 p ξ i = 1 , then we have
CCFFWG ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) CCFFWA ( 1 ,   2 , , p )
Proof. 
Easy to prove. □
Definition. 20.
For the CFFNs  i   ( i = 1 ,   2 , , p )  the operator  CCFFHA :   Γ n Γ  is given as
CCFFHA ( 1 ,   2 , , p ) = σ 1 ξ 1 ˙ σ ( 1 ) σ 2 ξ 2 ˙ σ ( 2 ) σ p ξ p ˙ σ ( p )
where, ξ = ( ξ 1 ,   ξ 2 , , ξ p ) T  be the weight vector, such that  ξ i 0  and  i = 1 n ξ i = 1  and  ˙ i s   ( ˙ i = n ζ i i ) is ˙ σ ( i ) , where  n  is the number of CPFNs and  η = ( η 1 ,   η 2 , , η p ) T  is the vector corresponding to  i  with  ζ i 0  and  i = 1 p ζ i = 1 .
Theorem. 9.
The value obtained using the CCFFHA operator for the CFFNs  i   ( i = 1 , 2 , , p )  is again a CFFN and given by
CCFFHA ( 1 ,   2 , , n ) = ( [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ ˙ δ ( i ) L ) 2 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( μ ˙ δ ( i ) U ) 2 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ i = 1 n ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 n ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) U ) ξ i σ i ] i = 1 p ( φ ˙ δ ( i ) ) ξ i σ i , 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) ) 2 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) .
Proof. 
Easy to prove. □
Example 4.
Consider three CPFNs  β i   ( i = 1 ,   2 ,   3 ) , such that  1 = ( [ 0.30 ,   0.50 ] ,   [ 0.60 ,   0.70 ] ,   0.50 ,   0.40 , 0.3 ) , 2 = ( [ 0.60 ,   0.70 ] ,   [ 0.40 ,   0.50 ] ,   0.50 ,   0.60 , 0.4 ) ,  and  3 = ( [ 0.70 ,   0.80 ] ,   [ 0.20 ,   0.40 ] ,   0.50 ,   0.40 , 0.5 ) . Additionally, if  η = ( 0.25 ,   0.35 ,   0.40 ) T  is the weight vector of i then  ˙ i = 3 η i i = ( [ φ ˙ δ ( i ) L ,   φ ˙ δ ( i ) U ] ,   [ ψ ˙ δ ( i ) L ,   ψ ˙ δ ( i ) U ] , φ ˙ δ ( i ) ,   ψ ˙ δ ( i ) )   ( i = 1 ,   2 ,   3 )  is computed for each CFFN as
˙ 1 = ( [ 1 ( 1 ( 0.30 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.25 3 ,   1 ( 1 ( 0.50 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.2 5 3 ] , [ ( 0.60 ) 3 × 0.25 , ( 0.70 ) 3 × 0.25 ] ,   ( 0.50 ) 3 × 0.25 , 1 ( 1 ( 0.40 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.25 3 ) = ( [ 0.2729 ,   0.4568 ] , [ 0.6817 , 0.7653 ] , 0.5946 , 0.3644 ) ; ˙ 2 = ( [ 1 ( 1 ( 0.60 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.35 3 ,   1 ( 1 ( 0.70 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.35 3 ] , [ ( 0.40 ) 3 × 0.35 , ( 0.50 ) 3 × 0.35 ] ,   ( 0.50 ) 3 × 0.35 , 1 ( 1 ( 0.60 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.35 3 ) = ( [ 0.6087 ,   0.7092 ] , [ 0.3821 , 0.4830 ] , 0.4830 , 0.6087 ) ; ˙ 3 = ( [ 1 ( 1 ( 0.70 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.4 3 ,   1 ( 1 ( 0.80 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.4 3 ] , [ ( 0.20 ) 3 × 0.4 , ( 0.40 ) 3 × 0.4 ] ,   ( 0.50 ) 3 × 0.4 , 1 ( 1 ( 0.40 ) 3 ) 3 × 0.4 3 ) = ( [ 0.7343 ,   0.8326 ] , [ 0.1450 , 0.3330 ] , 0.4353 , 0.4241 ) .
The score values of these numbers are calculated as
s c ( ˙ 1 ) = ( 0.2729 ) 3 + ( 0.4568 ) 3 ( 0.6817 ) 3 ( 0.7653 ) 3 2 ( ( 0.5946 ) 3 ( 0.3644 ) 3 ) = 0.4865 ; s c ( ˙ 2 ) = ( 0.6087 ) 3 + ( 0.7092 ) 3 ( 0.3821 ) 3 ( 0.4830 ) 3 2 ( ( 0.4830 ) 3 ( 0.6087 ) 3 ) = 0.0948 ; s c ( ˙ 3 ) = ( 0.7343 ) 3 + ( 0.8326 ) 3 ( 0.1450 ) 3 ( 0.3330 ) 3 2 ( ( 0.4353 ) 3 ( 0.4241 ) 3 ) = 0.3841 .
Thus, s c ( ˙ 3 ) s c ( ˙ 2 ) s c ( ˙ 1 ) , which gives
β ˙ σ ( 1 ) = ( [ 0.7343 ,   0.8326 ] , [ 0.1450 , 0.3330 ] , 0.4353 , 0.4241 ) , β ˙ σ ( 2 ) = ( [ 0.6087 ,   0.7092 ] , [ 0.3821 , 0.4830 ] , 0.4830 , 0.6087 ) ,
and
β ˙ δ ( 3 ) = ( [ 0.2729 ,   0.4568 ] , [ 0.6817 , 0.7653 ] , 0.5946 , 0.3644 )
Let  ξ = ( 0.35 ,   0.4 ,   0.25 )  be the position vector, then by using Equation (25), we have
1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ ˙ δ ( i ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.7343 ) 3 ) 0.35 × 0.5 × ( 1 ( 0.6087 ) 3 ) 0.4 × 0.4 × ( 1 ( 0.2729 ) 3 ) 0.25 × 0.3 ) 3 = 0.4966 ; 1 i = 1 n ( 1 ( φ ˙ σ ( i ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.8326 ) 3 ) 0.35 × 0.5 × ( 1 ( 0.7092 ) 3 ) 0.4 × 0.4 × ( 1 ( 0.4568 ) 3 ) 0.25 × 0.3 ) 3 = 0.5891 ; i = 1 p ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) L ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.1450 ) 0.35 × 0.5 ( 0.3821 ) 0.4 × 0.4 ( 0.6817 ) 0.25 × 0.3 = 0.5942 ; i = 1 p ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) U ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.3330 ) 0.35 × 0.5 ( 0.4830 ) 0.4 × 0.4 ( 0.7653 ) 0.25 × 0.3 = 0.7197 ; i = 1 p ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) ) ξ i σ i = ( 0.4353 ) 0.35 × 0.5 ( 0.4830 ) 0.4 × 0.4 ( 0.5946 ) 0.25 × 0.3 = 0.7401 ; 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ ˙ δ ( i ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 = 1 ( ( 1 ( 0.4241 ) 3 ) 0.35 × 0.5 × ( 1 ( 0.6087 ) 3 ) 0.4 × 0.4 × ( 1 ( 0.3644 ) 3 ) 0.25 × 0.3 ) 3 = 0.3844 .
Therefore,
CCFFHA ( 1 , 2 , 3 ) = ( [ 0.4966 , 0.5891 ] , [ 0.5942 , 0.7197 ] , 0.7401 , 0.3844 ) .

4. Decision-Making Approach under Cubic Fermatean Fuzzy Sets with Confidence Levels

This section presents an MCDM approach to deal with MCDM problems by using the proposed aggregation operators under a cubic Fermatean fuzzy environment. The MCDM problem is presented for evaluation with a cubic Fermatean fuzzy environment with the following presumptions and abbreviations. Let X = { X 1 , X 2 , , X p } be the set of m different alternatives which have to be analyzed under the set of q different criteria C = { C 1 , C 2 , , C q } . Suppose that all these possibilities are examined by experts, which provide their choices for each X i   ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) , under a cubic Fermatean fuzzy environment, and that these values can be considered as CFFNs D = [ 𝒹 i j ] p × q where 𝒹 i j = ( [ φ i j L ,   φ i j U ] ,   [ ψ i j L , ψ i j U ] ,   φ i j ,   ψ i j ) characterizes the importance values of alternative X i given by the decision-maker such that 0 φ i j L , φ i j U , ψ i j L , ψ i j U , φ i j , ψ i j 1 , [ φ i j L ,   φ i j U ] ,   [ ψ i j L , ψ i j U ] [ 0 , 1 ] , which satisfy the conditions that ( φ i j U ) 3 + ( ψ i j U ) 3 1 and ( φ i j ) 3 + ( ψ i j ) 3 1 . Let ξ = ( ξ 1 , ξ 2 , , ξ p ) be the weight vector of the criteria such that ξ i 0 and i = 1 p ξ i = 1 . Additionally, let σ i be the confidence levels of the CFFNs i such that 0 σ i 1 . In order to identify the optimal alternative(s), the presented approach is divided into the following steps.
Step 1. Arrange the confidence and capability for each alternative X i in the form of 𝒹 i j = ( [ φ i j L ,   φ i j U ] ,   [ ψ i j L , ψ i j U ] ,   φ i j ,   ψ i j ) . These rating values are expressed as a decision matrix D as:
D = X 1 X 2 X p ( 𝒹 11 𝒹 12 𝒹 1 p 𝒹 21 𝒹 22 𝒹 2 p 𝒹 q 1 𝒹 q 2 d p q ) .
Step 2. Convert the cost-type criteria into benefit-type criteria by using the normalization formula as given below:
𝓇 i j = { ( [ φ i j L , φ i j U ] ,   [ ψ i j L , ψ i j U ] , φ i j , ψ i j ) ;   if   the   benefit type   conditions   are   met ( [ ψ i j L , ψ i j U ] , [ φ i j L , φ i j U ] , ν i j , μ i j ) ;   if   the   cost type   conditions   are   met
Step 3. Calculate the aggregated value 𝓇 i   ( i = 1 , 2 , , p ) of the alternative X i , using CCFFWA, CCFFOWA, CCFFHA, CCFFWG, or CCFFOWG operators.
(a)
Using a CCFFWA operator
𝓇 i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i ) = CCFFWA ( i 1 ,   i 2 , , i p ) = ( [ 1 j = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i j L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 j = 1 n ( 1 ( φ i j U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ j = 1 p ( ψ i j L ) ξ i σ i , j = 1 p ( ψ i j L ) ξ i σ i ] , j = 1 p ( φ i j ) ξ i σ i , 1 j = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i j ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3   ) ;
(b)
using a CCFFOWA operator
𝓇 i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i ) = CCFFOWA ( 𝓇 δ ( i 1 ) ,   𝓇 δ ( i 2 ) , , 𝓇 δ ( i p ) ) = ( [ 1 j = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i j ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 j = 1 n ( 1 ( φ δ ( i j ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ j = 1 p ( ψ δ ( i j ) L ) ξ i σ i , j = 1 p ( ψ δ ( i ) U ) ξ i σ i ] , j = 1 p ( φ δ ( i j ) ) ξ i σ i , 1 j = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ δ ( i j ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) ;
(c)
using a CCFFHA operator
𝓇 i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i ) = CPFFHA ( 𝓇 ˙ δ ( i 1 ) ,   𝓇 ˙ δ ( i 2 ) , , 𝓇 ˙ δ ( i p ) ) = ( [ 1 j = 1 p ( 1 ( φ ˙ δ ( i j ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 j = 1 n ( 1 ( μ ˙ δ ( i j ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , [ j = 1 p ( ψ ˙ δ ( i j ) L ) ξ i σ i , j = 1 p ( ψ ˙ δ ( i J ) U ) ξ i σ i ] , j = 1 p ( φ ˙ δ ( i j ) ) ξ i σ i , 1 j = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ ˙ δ ( i j ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ) ;
(d)
using a CCFFWG operator
𝓇 i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i ) = CCFFWG ( 𝓇 i 1 ,   𝓇 i 2 , , 𝓇 i p ) = ( [ i = 1 p ( φ i j L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( φ i j U ) ξ i σ i ] , [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i j L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ i j U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ i j ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , i = 1 p ( ψ i j ) ξ i σ i ) ;
(e)
using a CCFFOWG operator
𝓇 i = ( [ φ i L ,   φ i U ] ,   [ ψ i L , ψ i U ] ,   φ i ,   ψ i ) = CCFFOWG ( 𝓇 i 1 ,   𝓇 i 2 , , 𝓇 i p ) = ( [ i = 1 p ( φ δ ( i j ) L ) ξ i σ i , i = 1 p ( φ δ ( i j ) U ) ξ i σ i ] , [ 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ δ ( i j ) L ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( ψ δ ( i j ) U ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 ] , 1 i = 1 p ( 1 ( φ δ ( i j ) ) 3 ) ξ i σ i 3 , i = 1 p ( ψ δ ( i j ) ) ξ i σ i ) .
Step 4. Compute the collected score values of each alternative as follows:
s c ( 𝓇 i ) = ( φ i j L ) 3 + ( φ i j U ) 3 ( ψ i j L ) 3 ( ψ i j U ) 3 2 + ( ψ i j 3 φ i j 3 ) .
If s c ( 𝓇 i 1 ) = s c ( 𝓇 i 2 ) for any two indices i 1 and i 2 , then compute accuracy values as
a c ( 𝓇 i ) = ( φ i j L ) 3 + ( φ i j U ) 3 + ( ψ i j L ) 3 + ( ψ i j U ) 3 2 + ( φ i j 3 + ψ i j 3 ) .
Step 5. By rating all of the alternatives in order of importance of the score values choose the best alternative.

4.1. Case Study

Inventory management is a major subject these days. From an industrial standpoint, a corporation cannot achieve targeted levels of manufacturing unless its inventory is adequately maintained. Therefore, appropriate inventory management is the first stage of the ladder of suitable levels of production. Any scarcity of raw materials in stock might cause a disruption of the entire manufacturing process, which would result in a significant loss for the industry. Suppose a food corporation wishes to monitor different inventory products. The corporation primarily manufactures four different types of food: drinks ( X 1 ), palm oil ( X 2 ), pickles ( X 3 ), and sweets ( X 4 ). Three factors namely cost price ( C 1 ), storage facilities ( C 2 ), and staleness level ( C 3 ) must be taken into consideration while deciding whether to reorder ingredients for making these food products such that ξ = ( 0.25 , 0.35 , 0.4 ) is the weight vector of these factors. The presented alternatives are examined under these three factors and their values are scored in terms of CFFNs. In each CFFN, the interval-valued FFNs (IVFFNs) indicate the current stock level in the inventory, and the FFNs represent the estimate of agreement and disagreement towards the present stock level for a coming week. Since the corporation does not sacrifice product quality, reducing staleness levels is given top attention. The main objective is then to determine the food products for which the ingredient stock must be reordered frequently. The following steps of the proposed approach were carried out for it.
Step 1. As described in Table 1, the desired data for each alternative is presented in CFFNs, and the collection evaluation is provided in a decision matrix.
Step 2. Using Equation (26), it is possible to derive a normalized decision matrix which is summarized in Table 2.
Step 3. Aggregate the values of Table 2 with the proposed operators:
(a)
Using Equation (28) we get
𝓇 1 = ( [ 0.1892 , 0.2685 ] , [ 0.6790 , 0.7751 ] , ( 0.5814 , 0.2514 ) ) ; 𝓇 2 = ( [ 0.2398 , 0.3104 ] , [ 0.5205 , 0.6369 ] , ( 0.6761 , 0.3425 ) ) ; 𝓇 3 = ( [ 0.2295 , 0.3376 ] , [ 0.5715 , 0.7032 ] , ( 0.7135 , 0.5335 ) ) ; 𝓇 4 = ( [ 0.3053 , 0.4237 ] , [ 0.4579 , 0.5457 ] , ( 0.5058 , 0.4008 ) ) .
(b)
Using Equation (29) we get
𝓇 1 = ( [ 0.1757 , 0.2536 ] , [ 0.6941 , 0.7895 ] , ( 0.5603 , 0.2904 ) ) ; 𝓇 2 = ( [ 0.2773 , 0.3507 ] , [ 0.5100 , 0.6239 ] , ( 0.7056 , 0.3493 ) ) ; 𝓇 3 = ( [ 0.2855 , 0.4200 ] , [ 0.5999 , 0.6988 ] , ( 0.6441 , 0.4218 ) ) ; 𝓇 4 = ( [ 0.2766 , 0.3923 ] , [ 0.5368 , 0.6297 ] , ( 0.5933 , 0.3195 ) ) .
(c)
Using Equation (30) we get
𝓇 1 = ( [ 0.4724 , 0.5803 ] , [ 0.4016 , 0.5234 ] , ( 0.2971 , 0.5310 ) ) ; 𝓇 2 = ( [ 0.4612 , 0.5723 ] , [ 0.2154 , 0.3146 ] , ( 0.4333 , 0.6352 ) ) ; 𝓇 3 = ( [ 0.4321 , 0.5276 ] , [ 0.2311 , 0.3214 ] , ( 0.4523 , 0.5876 ) ) ; 𝓇 4 = ( [ 0.5889 , 0.6794 ] , [ 0.4023 , 0.3367 ] , ( 0.4429 , 0.6054 ) ) .
(d)
Using Equation (31) we get
𝓇 1 = ( [ 0.4686 , 0.5661 ] , [ 0.3820 , 0.5012 ] , ( 0.2873 , 0.5230 ) ) ; 𝓇 2 = ( [ 0.4582 , 0.5621 ] , [ 0.2277 , 0.3331 ] , ( 0.4352 , 0.6450 ) ) ; 𝓇 3 = ( [ 0.4872 , 0.5629 ] , [ 0.2746 , 0.3829 ] , ( 0.3932 , 0.7646 ) ) ; 𝓇 4 = ( [ 0.4163 , 0.5530 ] , [ 0.3341 , 0.4333 ] , ( 0.3323 , 0.5197 ) ) .
(e)
Using Equation (32) we get
𝓇 1 = ( [ 0.3390 , 0.4463 ] , [ 0.4369 , 0.5695 ] , ( 0.3109 , 0.4437 ) ) ; 𝓇 2 = ( [ 0.3665 , 0.4768 ] , [ 0.2426 , 0.3644 ] , ( 0.5061 , 0.5586 ) ) ; 𝓇 3 = ( [ 0.3768 , 0.4715 ] , [ 0.3237 , 0.4366 ] , ( 0.4268 , 0.6303 ) ) ; 𝓇 4 = ( [ 0.4092 , 0.5759 ] , [ 0.2921 , 0.4118 ] , ( 0.3191 , 0.4462 ) ) .
Step 4. Compute the score values by using Equation (33); the results are listed in Table 3.
Step 5. Rankings of all the alternatives based on the score values and ordering are listed in the last column of Table 3. From this analysis, it is seen that X 4 is the best one among the others.

4.2. Validity Tests

To illustrate the feasibility of the proposed strategy in a multitude of environments, we used testing procedures defined by Wang and Trianaphyllou [31] as follows:
Test 1. If we replace the rating values of the non-optimal alternatives with those of a worse alternative, the best alternative should remain stable as long as the relative weighted criteria remain fixed.
Test 2. The procedure should be transitive.
Test 3. When a specific problem is separated into smaller ones while the same decision-making approach is used, the aggregated ranking of the alternatives should be equivalent to the original ranking.
Validity test using criterion 1
The ranking order of alternatives obtained by the proposed approach is X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1 . To test the corresponding nature of the proposed approach by test criterion 1, the non-optimal alternative X 1 was replaced with the worst alternative X 1 * where rating values of X 1 * were assumed to be ( [ 0.1 , 0.2 ] , [ 0.6 , 0.7 ] , ( 0.2 , 0.6 ) ) , ( [ 0.2 , 0.3 ] , [ 0.5 , 0.6 ] , ( 0.3 , 0.5 ) ) , and ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.3 , 0.4 ] , ( 0.1 , 0.5 ) ) . Following the observations, the presented approach was used, and the aggregated score values of the alternatives were s c ( X 1 ) = 0.1606 , s c ( X 1 * ) = 0.0031 , s c ( X 3 ) = 0.3676 , and s c ( X 4 ) = 0.3646 . As a result, the ranking order was X 4 X 3 X 1 X 1 * with the best alternative remaining the same as in the proposed approach. Thus, the presented approach yielded consistent findings in term of test criterion 1.
Validity test using criteria 2 and 3
For testing validity according to criteria 2 and 3, the fragmented decision-making subcases are taking as { X 1 , X 2 , X 4 } , { X 2 , X 3 , X 4 } , and { X 2 , X 3 , X 1 } . Then, using the described process, their rank order is as follows: X 4 X 2 X 1 , X 4 X 2 X 3 and X 2 X 3 X 1 , for criterion 2 and 3, respectively. When all of the results are combined, the overall ranking is X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1 which is the same as the outcomes of the original decision-making approach. Hence, our proposed approach is valid under test criteria 2 and 3.

4.3. Comparative Analysis

In the literature, there are numerous types of fuzzy sets that are used for specific situations based on their properties. The fuzzy sets, intuitionistic fuzzy sets, Pythagorean fuzzy sets, and Fermatean fuzzy sets are some of the most popular sets of fuzzy set theory. Cubic Fermatean fuzzy sets with confidence levels are an innovative variation of the fuzzy set theory that we introduce in this study. Table 4 compares each of these fuzzy sets with respect to a number of attributes. Each of them has a graded membership value and the capacity to describe uncertainty across multiple attributes.

4.4. Comparison with Some Existing Approaches

An evaluation was conducted to examine the performance of the new method compared to existing approaches [23,27,28,32] in the context of CPFSs and CIFSs. Sacrificing flexibility, we examined the situation by using the weight of decision-makers as ξ = ( 0.25 , 0.35 , 40 ) which allows for the existing approaches to be used with the original dataset. The results obtained with different methods are summarized in Table 5 and we conclude that the ranking order of the given alternatives is X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1 , hence the best alternative is X 4 which coincides with the proposed approach results given in Table 3, which validates the stability of our approach. Furthermore, the structure of the relative score values follows the same pattern, demonstrating that the presented approach is conservative in nature.
According to the comparative study described above, the presented strategy for handling decision-making problems has significant improvements over existing ones.
(1)
Cubic Fermatean fuzzy sets are a new development in fuzzy set theory, which can handle the uncertainty more accurately in real situations. Therefore, the proposed approach is more suitable than existing approaches to solve real-life and engineering decision problems.
(2)
Furthermore, Table 4 demonstrates that the findings calculated using the different available methods are performed without taking the confidence levels of the attributes into account throughout the analysis. In other words, all of these techniques examined their theories on the premise that decision-makers are completely confident in the analyzed objects. However, in practice these sorts of prerequisites are only partially met.
(3)
The existing aggregation operators are a special case of the presented operators. As a result, we conclude that the presented aggregation operators are more general in nature and more appropriate to solve real-world issues than the existing ones.

5. Conclusions

The main purpose of this research was to modify the existing operational laws of cubic Fermatean fuzzy sets, and propose a number of aggregation operators by taking into account the degree of confidence levels of each decision-maker during evaluation. Previously, all decision-makers were considered to express their opinions of numerous alternatives with a same level of certainty. However, this issue has been solved in the current article by factoring in the decision- maker’s confidence levels. We introduced a number of aggregating operators under the cubic Fermatean fuzzy framework, including CCFFWA, CCFFOWA, CCFFWG, and CCFFHA, by taking confidence levels into account. A few significant traits of each were also described. Additionally, the standard cubic Fermatean fuzzy weighted averaging and cubic Fermatean fuzzy weighted geometric operators were transformed into the provided aggregation operators when σ = 1 for all preferences. A comparison with several existing operators was performed to show that the provided operators offer a reducible approach to the MCDM problem.
Future research may further develop the outlined technique to support a wider range of applications and address a variety of uncertain programming difficulties, such as K-mean clustering [33] and fuzzy controllers [34,35]. The application will also be expanded to include neural networks and convolutional networks [36,37,38,39].

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, H.G., M.R., F.A. and S.J.; Methodology, H.G., M.R. and F.A.; Software, H.G.; Formal analysis, H.G., M.R., F.A. and I.M.H.; Investigation, S.J.; Writing—original draft, H.G., M.R. and F.A.; Writing—review & editing, H.G.; Visualization, S.J. and I.M.H.; Funding acquisition, H.G. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This paper was supported by the Researchers Supporting Project (project number RSP2023R389), King Saud University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia.

Institutional Review Board Statement

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Data Availability Statement

Data sharing is not applicable to this article as no datasets were generated or analyzed during the current study.

Acknowledgments

This paper was supported by the Researchers Supporting Project (project number RSP2023R389), King Saud University, Riyadh, Saudi Arabia.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Atanassov, K.T. Intuitionistic fuzzy sets. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 1986, 20, 87–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Yager, R.R. Heavy OWA operators. Fuzzy Optim. Decis. Mak. 2002, 1, 379–397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Yager, R.R. On ordered weighted averaging aggregation operators in multicriteria decisionmaking. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. 1988, 18, 183–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Xu, Z.; Yager, R.R. Some geometric aggregation operators based on intuitionistic fuzzy sets. Int. J. Gen. Syst. 2006, 35, 417–433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. ZXu, Z. Intuitionistic Fuzzy Aggregation Operators. IEEE Trans. Fuzzy Syst. 2007, 15, 1179–1187. [Google Scholar]
  6. Wang, W.; Liu, X. Intuitionistic fuzzy geometric aggregation operators based on einstein operations. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2011, 26, 1049–1075. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Lai, X.; Yang, B.; Ma, B.; Liu, M.; Yin, Z.; Yin, L.; Zheng, W. An Improved Stereo Matching Algorithm Based on Joint Similarity Measure and Adaptive Weights. Appl. Sci. 2022, 13, 514. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ye, J. Multicriteria fuzzy decision-making method based on a novel accuracy function under interval-valued intuitionistic fuzzy environment. Expert Syst. Appl. 2009, 36, 6899–6902. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Garg, H. Some series of intuitionistic fuzzy interactive averaging aggregation operators. SpringerPlus 2016, 5, 999. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Garg, H. Generalized intuitionistic fuzzy multiplicative interactive geometric operators and their application to multiple criteria decision making. Int. J. Mach. Learn. Cybern. 2015, 7, 1075–1092. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Garg, H. Generalized intuitionistic fuzzy interactive geometric interaction operators using Einstein t-norm and t-conorm and their application to decision making. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2016, 101, 53–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Xu, Y.; Wang, H.; Merigó, J.M. Intuitionistic fuzzy einstein choquet integral operators for multiple attribute decision making. Technol. Econ. Dev. Econ. 2014, 20, 227–253. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Yager, R.R. Pythagorean fuzzy subsets. In Proceedings of the 2013 Joint IFSA World Congress and NAFIPS Annual Meeting (IFSA/NAFIPS), Edmonton, AB, Canada, 24–28 June 2013; pp. 57–61. [Google Scholar]
  14. Yager, R.R. Properties and applications of Pythagorean fuzzy sets. In Imprecision and Uncertainty in Information Representation and Processing; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2016; pp. 119–136. [Google Scholar]
  15. Yager, R.R.; Abbasov, A.M. Pythagorean membership grades, complex numbers, and decision making. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2013, 28, 436–452. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zhang, X.; Xu, Z. Extension of TOPSIS to Multiple Criteria Decision Making with Pythagorean Fuzzy Sets. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2014, 29, 1061–1078. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Peng, X.; Yang, Y. Pythagorean Fuzzy Choquet Integral Based MABAC Method for Multiple Attribute Group Decision Making. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2016, 31, 989–1020. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Gao, X.; Deng, Y. Generating method of Pythagorean fuzzy sets from the negation of probability. Eng. Appl. Artif. Intell. 2021, 105, 104403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Zhang, X. Multicriteria Pythagorean fuzzy decision analysis: A hierarchical QUALIFLEX approach with the closeness index-based ranking methods. Inf. Sci. 2016, 330, 104–124. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Peng, X.; Yang, Y. Fundamental Properties of Interval-Valued Pythagorean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators. Int. J. Intell. Syst. 2015, 31, 444–487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Senapati, T.; Yager, R.R. Fermatean fuzzy sets. J. Ambient. Intell. Humaniz. Comput. 2020, 11, 663–674. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Senapati, T.; Yager, R.R. Fermatean fuzzy weighted averaging/geometric operators and its application in multi-criteria decision-making methods. Eng. Appl. Artif. Intell. 2019, 85, 112–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Kaur, G.; Garg, H. Generalized cubic intuitionistic fuzzy aggregation operators using t-norm operations and their applications to group decision-making process. Arab. J. Sci. Eng. 2019, 44, 2775–2794. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Khan, F.; Khan, M.S.A.; Shahzad, M.; Abdullah, S. Pythagorean cubic fuzzy aggregation operators and their application to multi-criteria decision making problems. J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst. 2019, 36, 595–607. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Khan, F.; Abdullah, S.; Mahmood, T.; Shakeel, M.; Rahim, M.; Amin, N.U. Pythagorean cubic fuzzy aggregation information based on confidence levels and its application to multi-criteria decision making process. J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst. 2019, 36, 5669–5683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Abbas, S.Z.; Khan, M.S.A.; Abdullah, S.; Sun, H.; Hussain, F. Cubic Pythagorean fuzzy sets and their application to multi-attribute decision making with unknown weight information. J. Intell. Fuzzy Syst. 2019, 37, 1529–1544. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Amin, F.; Rahim, M.; Ali, A.; Ameer, E. Generalized Cubic Pythagorean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators and their Application to Multi-attribute Decision-Making Problems. Int. J. Comput. Intell. Syst. 2022, 15, 92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Rahim, M.; Amin, F.; Ali, A.; Shah, K. An Extension of Bonferroni Mean under Cubic Pythagorean Fuzzy Environment and Its Applications in Selection-Based Problems. Math. Probl. Eng. 2022, 2022, 9735100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Rong, Y.; Yu, L.; Niu, W.; Liu, Y.; Senapati, T.; Mishra, A.R. MARCOS approach based upon cubic Fermatean fuzzy set and its application in evaluation and selecting cold chain logistics distribution center. Eng. Appl. Artif. Intell. 2022, 116, 105401. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Jeevaraj, S. Ordering of interval-valued Fermatean fuzzy sets and its applications. Expert Syst. Appl. 2021, 185, 115613. [Google Scholar]
  31. Wang, X.; Triantaphyllou, E. Ranking irregularities when evaluating alternatives by using some ELECTRE methods. Omega 2008, 36, 45–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Garg, H.; Kaur, G. Cubic Intuitionistic Fuzzy Sets and its Fundamental Properties. J. Mult.-Valued Log. Soft Comput. 2019, 33, 507–537. [Google Scholar]
  33. Talib, R. How we can use Energy Efficiency built upon the method of K-means clustering to extend the lifetime of WSN. Al-Salam J. Eng. Technol. 2022, 2, 40–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Wang, S.; Sun, Y.; Yang, C.; Yu, Y. Advanced design and tests of a new electrical control seeding system with genetic algorithm fuzzy control strategy. J. Comput. Methods Sci. Eng. 2021, 21, 703–712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Mercorelli, P. Using Fuzzy PD Controllers for Soft Motions in a Car-like Robot. Adv. Sci. Technol. Eng. Syst. J. 2018, 3, 380–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Qin, X.; Liu, Z.; Liu, Y.; Liu, S.; Yang, B.; Yin, L.; Liu, M.; Zheng, W. User OCEAN Personality Model Construction Method Using a BP Neural Network. Electronics 2022, 11, 3022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Yi, Y.; Wang, J.; Ding, X.; Li, C. A convolutional neural network model of multi-scale feature fusion: MFF-Net. J. Comput. Methods Sci. Eng. 2022, 22, 2217–2225. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Alajanbi, M.; Malerba, D.; Liu, H. Distributed Reduced Convolution Neural Networks. Mesop. J. Big Data 2021, 2021, 26–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Nentwig, M.; Mercorelli, P. Inversion of Fuzzy Neural Networks for the Reduction of Noise in the Control Loop. IFAC Proc. Vol. 2008, 41, 157–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Space analysis between IFS, PFS and FFS.
Figure 1. Space analysis between IFS, PFS and FFS.
Symmetry 15 00260 g001
Table 1. Assessment values of alternatives in terms of CFFNs with confidence levels.
Table 1. Assessment values of alternatives in terms of CFFNs with confidence levels.
Alternatives C 1 C 2 C 3
X 1 ( [ 0.55 , 0.65 ] , [ 0.15 , 0.25 ] , ( 0.45 , 0.25 ) ; 0.4 ) ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.45 , 0.55 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.25 ) ; 0.6 ) ( [ 0.45 , 0.65 ] , [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , ( 0.25 , 0.40 ) ; 0.5 )
X 2 ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.45 , 0.55 ] , ( 0.45 , 0.65 ) ; 0.5 ) ( [ 0.20 , 0.30 ] , [ 0.35 , 0.40 ] , ( 0.25 , 0.35 ) ; 0.4 ) ( [ 0.25 , 0.45 ] , [ 0.15 , 0.25 ] , ( 0.45 , 0.55 ) ; 0.6 )
X 3 ( [ 0.55 , 0.65 ] , [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , ( 0.25 , 0.45 ) ; 0.3 ) ( [ 0.45 , 0.65 ] , [ 0.30 , 0.40 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.45 ) ; 0.3 ) ( [ 0.55 , 0.75 ] , [ 0.15 , 0.20 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.55 ) ; 0.7 )
X 4 ( [ 0.35 , 0.55 ] , [ 0.15 , 0.35 ] , ( 0.15 , 0.35 ) ; 0.5 ) ( [ 0.45 , 0.60 ] , [ 0.20 , 0.25 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.45 ) ; 0.7 ) ( [ 0.45 , 0.55 ] , [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , ( 0.50 , 0.40 ) ; 0.8 )
Table 2. Normalized decision matrix.
Table 2. Normalized decision matrix.
Alternatives C 1 C 2 C 3
X 1 ( [ 0.15 , 0.25 ] , [ 0.55 , 0.65 ] , ( 0.25 , 0.45 ) ; 0.4 ) ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.45 , 0.55 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.25 ) ; 0.6 ) ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.45 , 0.65 ] , ( 0.40 , 0.25 ) ; 0.5 )
X 2 ( [ 0.45 , 0.55 ] , [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , ( 0.65 , 0.45 ) ; 0.5 ) ( [ 0.20 , 0.30 ] , [ 0.35 , 0.40 ] , ( 0.25 , 0.35 ) ; 0.4 ) ( [ 0.15 , 0.25 ] , [ 0.25 , 0.45 ] , ( 0.55 , 0.45 ) ; 0.6 )
X 3 ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.55 , 0.65 ] , ( 0.45 , 0.25 ) ; 0.3 ) ( [ 0.45 , 0.65 ] , [ 0.30 , 0.40 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.45 ) ; 0.3 ) ( [ 0.15 , 0.20 ] , [ 0.55 , 0.75 ] , ( 0.55 , 0.35 ) ; 0.7 )
X 4 ( [ 0.15 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.35 , 0.55 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.15 ) ; 0.5 ) ( [ 0.45 , 0.60 ] , [ 0.20 , 0.25 ] , ( 0.35 , 0.45 ) ; 0.7 ) ( [ 0.25 , 0.35 ] , [ 0.45 , 0.55 ] , ( 0.40 , 0.50 ) ; 0.8 )
Table 3. Score values and ranking order of alternatives with different operators.
Table 3. Score values and ranking order of alternatives with different operators.
Operators s c ( 𝓻 1 ) s c ( 𝓻 2 ) s c ( 𝓻 3 ) s c ( 𝓻 4 ) Ranking
CCFFWA 0.5569 0.4467 0.4533 0.1420 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
CCFFOWA 0.5538 0.4202 0.4221 0.3376 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
CCFFHA 0.1698 0.1971 0.2014 0.3423 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
CCFFWG 0.1650 0.2948 0.1707 0.4732 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
CCFFOWG 0.0128 0.1932 0.0922 0.2387 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
Table 4. Different type of fuzzy sets and their features.
Table 4. Different type of fuzzy sets and their features.
Characteristics Different Types of Fuzzy Sets
Fuzzy SetIFSPFSFFSCFFSCFFSCL
Membership value
Describe ambiguityMGMG and NMGMG and NMGMG and NMGMG and NMGMG and NMG with confidence levels
Unknown parameters
Ability of multi-attribute modeling
Modeling of increasing uncertainty
Taking reluctance into account while making decisions
Abbreviations: IFS: intuitionistic fuzzy set; PFS: Pythagorean fuzzy set; FFS: Fermatean fuzzy set; CFFS: Cubic Fermatean fuzzy set; CFFSCL: Cubic Fermatean fuzzy set with confidence levels; MG: membership grade; NMG: Non-membership grade.
Table 5. Comparison with existing studies.
Table 5. Comparison with existing studies.
Existing Approaches s c ( X 1 ) s c ( X 2 ) s c ( X 3 ) s c ( X 4 ) Ranking Order
Garg and Kaur [32] 0.6294 0.4567 0.5321 0.2310 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
Amin et al. [27] 0.7312 0.5438 0.4877 0.3421 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
Rahim et al. [28] 0.3643 0.3241 0.3575 0.2783 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
Kaur and Garg [23] 0.5666 0.4763 0.5198 0.3417 X 4 X 2 X 3 X 1
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Garg, H.; Rahim, M.; Amin, F.; Jafari, S.; M. Hezam, I. Confidence Levels-Based Cubic Fermatean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators and Their Application to MCDM Problems. Symmetry 2023, 15, 260. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym15020260

AMA Style

Garg H, Rahim M, Amin F, Jafari S, M. Hezam I. Confidence Levels-Based Cubic Fermatean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators and Their Application to MCDM Problems. Symmetry. 2023; 15(2):260. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym15020260

Chicago/Turabian Style

Garg, Harish, Muhammad Rahim, Fazli Amin, Saeid Jafari, and Ibrahim M. Hezam. 2023. "Confidence Levels-Based Cubic Fermatean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators and Their Application to MCDM Problems" Symmetry 15, no. 2: 260. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym15020260

APA Style

Garg, H., Rahim, M., Amin, F., Jafari, S., & M. Hezam, I. (2023). Confidence Levels-Based Cubic Fermatean Fuzzy Aggregation Operators and Their Application to MCDM Problems. Symmetry, 15(2), 260. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym15020260

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop