Next Article in Journal
High-Performance Carrier Phase Recovery for Local Local Oscillator Continuous-Variable Quantum Key Distribution
Next Article in Special Issue
The Space of Continuous Linear Functionals on 1 Approximated by Weakly Symmetric Continuous Linear Functionals
Previous Article in Journal
On the Horizontal Divergence Asymmetry in the Gulf of Mexico
Previous Article in Special Issue
Parametrized Half-Hyperbolic Tangent Function-Activated Complex-Valued Neural Network Approximation
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

On Symmetrically Stochastic System of Fractional Differential Equations and Variational Inequalities

1
Department of Mathematics, Shanghai Normal University, Shanghai 200234, China
2
Research Center for Interneural Computing, China Medical University Hospital, China Medical University, Taichung 404327, Taiwan
3
Academy of Romanian Scientists, 50044 Bucharest, Romania
4
Department of Computer Science, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, Champaign, IL 61820, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Symmetry 2025, 17(1), 138; https://doi.org/10.3390/sym17010138
Submission received: 8 December 2024 / Revised: 27 December 2024 / Accepted: 14 January 2025 / Published: 17 January 2025

Abstract

:
In this work, we are devoted to discussing a system of fractional stochastic differential variational inequalities with Lévy jumps (SFSDVI with Lévy jumps), that comprises both parts, that is, a system of stochastic variational inequalities (SSVI) and a system of fractional stochastic differential equations(SFSDE) with Lévy jumps. Here it is noteworthy that the SFSDVI with Lévy jumps consists of both sections that possess a mutual symmetry structure. Invoking Picard’s successive iteration process and projection technique, we obtain the existence of only a solution to the SFSDVI with Lévy jumps via some appropriate restrictions. In addition, the major outcomes are invoked to deduce that there is only a solution to the spatial-price equilibria system in stochastic circumstances. The main contributions of the article are listed as follows: (a) putting forward the SFSDVI with Lévy jumps that could be applied for handling different real matters arising from varied domains; (b) deriving the unique existence of solutions to the SFSDVI with Lévy jumps under a few mild assumptions; (c) providing an applicable instance for spatial-price equilibria system in stochastic circumstances affected with Lévy jumps and memory.
MSC:
60H20; 34A08; 49J40

1. Introduction

Let · and · , · be the norm and inner product in R n (or R m ), respectively. We also use · and · , · to denote the norm and inner product in the product space R n 1 × R n 2 , respectively, that is,
y = y 1 2 + y 2 2 and y , x = y 1 , x 1 + y 2 , x 2 , y , x R n 1 × R n 2 ,
with y = ( y 1 , y 2 ) and x = ( x 1 , x 2 ) . In the same way, the norm and inner product in R m 1 × R m 2 could be formulated, respectively.
Let DVI and SDE represent a differential variational inequality and a stochastic differential equation, respectively. Suppose { B ι } is standard Brownian motion of l-dimension. Recently, stochastic differential VI was proposed and discussed in [1], outlined as follows:
d y ( s ) = b ( s , y ( s ) , h ( s ) ) d s + σ ( s , y ( s ) , h ( s ) ) d B s , s [ 0 , T ] , y ( 0 ) = y 0 , F ( ω , s , y ( ω , s ) , h ( ω , s ) ) , x h ( ω , s ) 0 , x K , a . s . ω Ω , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] ,
where y 0 is a fixed random vector, K R m is of both convexity and closedness, and single-valued mappings F , σ , b are measurable.
It was shown in [1] that there is only a solution to the above stochastic DVI and the solution is continue to parametric stochastic DVI. Their outcomes were also applied to treat some practical problems such as the spatial-price equilibria problems in stochastic circumstances. Meanwhile, Euler iterative approach is applied in [2] for settling stochastic DVI and the major results are exploited to handle some practical problems such as the circuits with electrical diodes in stochastic circumstances.
It is noteworthy that the above stochastic DVI is actually the classical DVI considered in [3] with stochastic circumstance effects. In accordance with [3], it is known that DVI furnishes an efficient modeling pattern to different applicable matters. So, stochastic differential VI could be exploited to address varied practical matters arising in different fields such as mechanics, finance and economy in stochastic circumstances. A range of theoretic results, iteration processes and computational instances had been acquired broadly for classical differential VI; refer to [4,5,6,7,8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17].
To the best of our awareness, in past decade, many scholars had found that there are jump and memory features for certain systems to display. Moreover, these features could not be enough explained by SDEs driven just by Brownian motions. As a result, on the basis of fractional calculus and Lévy jumps, certain academics captured memorability and instability of systems, independently; refer to [8,9,18,19,20,21,22]. With the help of the matters related to the stochastic systems effected with memory and jumps, Zeng et al. [23] presented and discussed a fractional stochastic DVI with Lévy jump (FSDVI with Lévy jump), formulated as follows:
d y ( s ) = b ( s , y ( s ) , h ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 ( s , y ( s ) , h ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ ( s , y ( s ) , h ( s ) ) d B s + y < c G ( s , y ( s ) , h ( s ) , y ) N ˜ ( d s , d y ) , α ( 1 2 , 1 ) , y ( 0 ) = y 0 , F ( ω , s , y ( ω , s ) , h ( ω , s ) ) , x h ( ω , s ) 0 , x K , a . s . ω Ω , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] .
To estimate the above fractional differential part, we realize that it serves as a special term for which it is not hard to reckon fractional differentiation expressed as ( d s ) α for α ( 1 2 , 1 ) ; refer to [20].
Taking into account the matters relevant to these stochastic systems effected by memory and jumps with α ( 1 2 , 1 ) we now introduce and explore a system of fractional stochastic DVIs with Lévy jumps (SFSDVI with Lévy jumps), specified as follows:
d x 1 ( s ) = b 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ 0 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 1 ( s ) + x 1 < c 1 G 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) , x 1 ) N ˜ 1 ( d s , d x 1 ) , d x 2 ( s ) = b 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ 0 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 2 ( s ) + x 2 < c 2 G 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) , x 2 ) N ˜ 2 ( d s , d x 2 ) , x ( 0 ) = x 0 ,
and
F 1 ( ω , s , x 2 ( ω , s ) , u 1 ( ω , s ) ) , v 1 u 1 ( ω , s ) 0 , v 1 K 1 , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω , F 2 ( ω , s , x 1 ( ω , s ) , u 2 ( ω , s ) ) , v 2 u 2 ( ω , s ) 0 , v 2 K 2 , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω ,
in which x 0 , x R n 1 × R n 2 and u R m 1 × R m 2 , with x 0 = ( x 1 , 0 , x 2 , 0 ) , x = ( x 1 , x 2 ) and u = ( u 1 , u 2 ) . Here it is noteworthy that the SFSDVI with Lévy jumps consists of both sections that possess a mutual symmetry structure. Under making no misleading, we could employ x k ( s ) and u k ( s ) instead of x k ( ω , s ) and u k ( ω , s ) in the subsequent statement for k = 1 , 2 . Refer to the further description for more notations and detailed information.
A few special cases of the issue (3) and (4) are released as follows.
(i) In case G k = 0 for each k, the issue (3) and (4) reduces to
d x 1 ( s ) = b 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ 0 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 1 ( s ) , d x 2 ( s ) = b 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ 0 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 2 ( s ) , x ( 0 ) = x 0 ,
and
F 1 ( ω , s , x 2 ( ω , s ) , u 1 ( ω , s ) ) , v 1 u 1 ( ω , s ) 0 , v 1 K 1 , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω , F 2 ( ω , s , x 1 ( ω , s ) , u 2 ( ω , s ) ) , v 2 u 2 ( ω , s ) 0 , v 2 K 2 , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω .
Issue (5) and (6) serves as a new matter.
(ii) In case σ 1 k = 0 and G k = 0 for each k, the issue (3) and (4) reduces to a generalization of SDVI (1) studied in [1,2,23].
(iii) In case σ 0 k = 0 and G k = 0 for each k, the issue (3) and (4) reduces to a generalization of a special situation of FDVI presented and considered by varied academics; refer to [8,9,19,24,25,26].
Precisely speaking, through suitable selections of the measurability mappings σ 0 k , σ 1 k , b k , G k and the set K k for k = 1 , 2 , one could derive a range of prominent (stochastic) DVIs and their systems as special examples in terms of SFSDVI with Lévy jumps (3) and (4). Resembling FSDVI with Lévy jump (2), employed for treating numerous matters in stochastic circumstances, SFSDVI with Lévy jumps (3) and (4) could be exploited for expressing different systems of realistic stochastic problems, with memory and jumps. We shall in Section 4 provide an application of (3) and (4) to the spatial-price equilibria systems in stochastic circumstances influenced with memory and Lévy jumps.
As well as we know, there is no research work for one to study the symmetrical SFSDVI with Lévy jumps like (3) and (4). So, it will be interesting and valuable to investigate (3) and (4).
The main contributions of the article over other ones (see e.g., [11,23]) are listed as follows: (a) putting forward the SFSDVI with Lévy jumps (3) and (4) that could be applied for handling different real matters arising from varied domains; (b) deriving the unique existence of solutions to (3) and (4) under a few mild assumptions; (c) providing an applicable instance for spatial-price equilibria system in stochastic circumstances affected with Lévy jumps and memory.

2. Basic Concepts and Formulations

To deal with the symmetrical SFSDVI with Lévy jumps (3) and (4), one first releases some preliminaries, including some notions and basic tools.
  • ( Ω , F , { F s } s 0 , P ) denotes a complete probability space with filtration { F s } .
  • B ( s ) denotes Brownian motion that is l-dimensional and F s -adapted.
  • N : R + × ( R n { 0 } ) and B ( s ) are independent of each other, with N being jump F s -adapted measure; and the associated compensation is martingale measure, specified as follows:
    N ˜ ( d s , d x ) : = N ( d s , d x ) ν ( d x ) d s ,
    whose intensity measure ν ( · ) meets
    R n { 0 } x 2 1 + x 2 ν ( d x ) < .
  • L 2 ( Ω , R n ) denotes the Hilbert space of R n -valued squared-integrable random variables, equipped with norm · L 2 = ( E · 2 ) 1 / 2 .
  • H m [ b , c ] = L a d 2 ( Ω × [ b , c ] , R m ) denotes the Hilbert space of R m -valued F s -adapted stochastic processes, fulfilling b c E f ( ω , τ ) 2 d τ < , f H m [ b , c ] , whose inner product is endowed by
    h , v H m [ b , c ] = b c E ( h ( ω , s ) , v ( ω , s ) ) d s , h , v H m [ b , c ] ,
    with [ b , c ] [ 0 , T ] .
  • U m [ b , c ] = { h ( ω , τ ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ b , c ] , R m ) : h ( ω , τ ) K , a . s . ω Ω , a . e . τ [ b , c ] } , with K R m being both convex and closed.
    Let K k R m k be convex and closed. We specify the spatial-products X = R n 1 × R n 2 and V = R m 1 × R m 2 . In what follows, we furnish the specific details for (3) and (4). For i = 1 , 2 , assume the following conditions hold throughout.
  • 0 s x i < c i G i ( ι , x ( ι ) , u ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) is an R n i -valued martingale of square integrability, satisfying
    P ( x i < c i G i ( ι , x ( ι ) , u ( ι ) , x i ) ν i ( d x i ) d ι < ) = 1
    in which the constant c i > 0 denotes the jump size of allowable maximality.
  • x 0 is the starting datum fulfilling E x 0 2 < .
  • b i : [ 0 , T ] × X × V R n i .
  • σ 0 i : [ 0 , T ] × X × V R n i × l i .
  • G i : [ 0 , T ] × X × V × R n i R n i .
  • F 1 : Ω × [ 0 , T ] × R n 2 × K 1 R m 1 and F 2 : Ω × [ 0 , T ] × R n 1 × K 2 R m 2 .
  • σ 1 i : [ 0 , T ] × X × V R n i is of continuity with respect to s.
Next, we provide vital notion involving solutions of (3) and (4), and other concepts that will be useful to demonstrate the major results.
Definition 1.
Let 1 2 < α < 1 . The pair ( x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) is said to be a solution of (3) and (4) if x ( s ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , X ) satisfying
d x 1 ( s ) = b 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ 0 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 1 ( s ) + x 1 < c 1 G 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) , x 1 ) N ˜ 1 ( d s , d x 1 ) , d x 2 ( s ) = b 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + σ 1 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) ( d s ) α + σ 0 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 2 ( s ) + x 2 < c 2 G 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) , x 2 ) N ˜ 2 ( d s , d x 2 ) , x ( 0 ) = x 0 ,
and
u 1 ( s ) SOL ( U m 1 [ 0 , T ] , F 1 ( ω , s , x 2 ( ω , s ) , u 1 ( ω , s ) ) ) , u 2 ( s ) SOL ( U m 2 [ 0 , T ] , F 2 ( ω , s , x 1 ( ω , s ) , u 2 ( ω , s ) ) ) ,
in which SOL ( U m i [ 0 , T ] , F i ( ω , s , x j ( ω , s ) , u i ( ω , s ) ) ) is the solution set of the SVI: seek u i U m i [ 0 , T ] s.t.
F i ( ω , s , x j ( ω , s ) , u i ( ω , s ) ) , v i u i ( ω , s ) 0 , v i K i , a . s . ω Ω , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] .
If the pair ( x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) is unique in the almost everywhere sense, we say that there holds the unique existence of solutions to (3) and (4).
Take a fixed f L 1 ( [ b , c ] ; R d ) arbitrarily. In terms of [20], we recall the left Riemann-Liouville α -order fractional integral, specified below
( I a + α f ) ( t ) = 1 Γ ( α ) b t ( t s ) α 1 f ( s ) d s , t > b ,
with Γ ( α ) = 0 t α 1 e t d t . In addition, from [27] we known that if f is also absolutely continuous, then left Riemann-Liouville α -order fractional derivative is specified below
( D b + α f ) ( s ) = 1 Γ ( 1 α ) d d s b s ( s t ) α f ( t ) d t , s > b .
Next, it is noteworthy to mention that we are concentrated on the situation of b = 0 in the formulation above, that is,
( D 0 + α f ) ( s ) = 1 Γ ( 1 α ) d d s 0 s ( s t ) α f ( t ) d t .
According to [28], one has D 0 + α = d α ( d s ) α and ( d α f ) ( s ) = Γ ( 1 + α ) ( d f ) ( s ) = ( D 0 + α f ) ( s ) ( d s ) α . Setting g ( s ) = ( D 0 + α f ) ( s ) , one obtains
0 t g ( s ) ( d s ) α = Γ ( 1 + α ) f ( t ) = Γ ( 1 + α ) D 0 + α g ( t ) = Γ ( 1 + α ) Γ ( α ) 0 t ( t s ) α 1 g ( s ) d s = α 0 t ( t s ) α 1 g ( s ) d s .
Therefore, the system of fractional stochastic differential equations (3) could be rephrased as
x 1 ( t ) = x 1 , 0 + 0 t b 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + α 0 t ( t s ) α 1 σ 1 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + 0 t σ 0 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 1 ( s ) + 0 t x 1 < c 1 G 1 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) , x 1 ) N ˜ 1 ( d s , d x 1 ) , x 2 ( t ) = x 2 , 0 + 0 t b 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + α 0 t ( t s ) α 1 σ 1 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d s + 0 t σ 0 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) ) d B 2 ( s ) + 0 t x 2 < c 2 G 2 ( s , x ( s ) , u ( s ) , x 2 ) N ˜ 2 ( d s , d x 2 ) .
For detailed information, refer to [18,20,28].
In what follows one releases the following lemmas for the subsequent usage.
Lemma 1
([1]). Let [ b , c ] [ 0 , T ] and K R m where K is closed and convex. Then U m [ b , c ] L a d 2 ( Ω × [ b , c ] , R m ) where U m [ b , c ] is closed and convex.
Let K be a nonempty closed convex subset of a real Hilbert space H. We then know from [23] that for each x in H, there exists the unique y in K, denoted by P K ( x ) , that is y = P K ( x ) , s.t. dist ( x , K ) = min v K x v H = x y H . Moreover, for a point y K , it holds that: y = P K ( x ) x y , v y H 0 , v K . In addition, let A : H H be a mapping. It then follows from [23] that there holds the equivalence of the relations below:
(a)
v K is a solution to the VI: A v , y v H 0 for all y K ;
(b)
v = P K ( v μ A v ) with coefficient μ > 0 .
Lemma 2
([1]). Take an element x L a d 2 ( Ω × [ b , c ] , R n ) arbitrarily. One then has that, for v U m [ b , c ] , the following relations are equivalent:
(i) v ( ω , s ) K solves the SVI:
F ( ω , s , x ( ω , s ) , v ( ω , s ) ) , y v ( ω , s ) 0 , y K , a . s . ω Ω , a . e . s [ b , c ] ;
(ii) v U m [ b , c ] solves the VI:
F ˜ ( x , v ) , w v H m [ b , c ] 0 , w U m [ b , c ] ,
in which F ˜ ( x , v ) ( ω , s ) : = F ( ω , s , x ( ω , s ) , v ( ω , s ) ) for all ( x , v ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ b , c ] , R n ) × U m [ b , c ] and ( ω , s ) Ω × [ b , c ] .
Lemma 3
([29], Doob-type Inequality). Suppose that q [ 1 , ) and the martingale ( s ) is right-continuous s.t. E ( s ) q < for all s 0 . Then
P ( sup s [ 0 , T ] ( s ) > ϵ ) E ( T ) q ϵ q for all T > 0
and for q > 1 ,
E ( sup s [ 0 , T ] ( s ) q ) ( q q 1 ) q E ( T ) q for all T > 0 .
Lemma 4
([30], Itô-type Isometry). Take a positive number T arbitrarily. Then
E [ ( 0 T h ( ω , s ) d B s ) 2 ] = E [ 0 T h 2 ( ω , s ) d s ] , for all h V ( 0 , T ) ,
in which V ( 0 , T ) denotes the family of functions h : Ω × [ 0 , T ] R satisfying:
(a)
h is B × F measurable, in which B denotes Borel-σ-algebra on [ 0 , T ] ;
(b)
h is F s -adapted;
(c)
E [ 0 T h 2 ( ω , s ) d s ] < .

3. Solvability of Problem (3) and (4)

We are now ready to present and demonstrate that there holds the unique existence of solutions of the symmetrical SFSDVI with Lévy jumps (3) and (4). For i = 1 , 2 , assume the following conditions hold throughout.
Assumption 1.
Take s , ι [ 0 , T ] arbitrarily, with constant T > 0 , x 2 , x 1 , x X , u 2 , u 1 , u V , x ˜ i , 2 , x ˜ i , 1 , x ˜ i L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n i ) and u ˜ i , 2 , u ˜ i , 1 U m i [ 0 , T ] . Suppose throughout that there exist positive constants C ¯ i , L b i , L σ 1 i , L σ 0 i , L G i , K b i , K σ 1 i , K σ 0 i , K G i , and L F i with L F i > C ¯ i s.t.
(i)
b i ( s , x , u ) 2 K b i ( 1 + x 2 + u 2 ) ;
σ 0 i ( s , x , u ) R n i × l i 2 K σ 0 i ( 1 + x 2 + u 2 ) ;
σ 1 i ( s , x , u ) 2 K σ 1 i ( 1 + x 2 + u 2 ) ;
x ˜ i < c i G i ( s , x , u , x ˜ i ) 2 ν i ( d x ˜ i ) K G i ( 1 + x 2 + u 2 ) ;
(ii)
b i ( ι , x 2 , u 2 ) b i ( ι , x 1 , u 1 ) 2 L b i ( u 1 u 2 2 + x 1 x 2 2 ) ;
σ 0 i ( ι , x 2 , u 2 ) σ 0 i ( ι , x 1 , u 1 ) R n i × l i 2 L σ 0 i ( u 1 u 2 2 + x 1 x 2 2 ) ;
σ 1 i ( ι , x 2 , u 2 ) σ 1 i ( ι , x 1 , u 1 ) 2 L σ 1 i ( u 1 u 2 2 + x 1 x 2 2 ) ;
x ˜ i < c i G i ( ι , x 2 , u 2 , x ˜ i ) G i ( ι , x 1 , u 1 , x ˜ i ) 2 ν i ( d x ˜ i ) L G i ( u 1 u 2 2 + x 1 x 2 2 ) ;
(iii)
for j = 1 , 2 and j i
L F i ( u ˜ i , 1 u ˜ i , 2 H m i [ 0 , T ] + x ˜ j , 1 x ˜ j , 2 H n j [ 0 , T ] ) F ˜ i ( x ˜ j , 1 , u ˜ i , 1 ) F ˜ i ( x ˜ j , 2 , u ˜ i , 2 ) H m i [ 0 , T ] ;
C ¯ i u ˜ i , 1 u ˜ i , 2 H m i [ 0 , T ] F ˜ i ( x ˜ j , u ˜ i , 1 ) F ˜ i ( x ˜ j , u ˜ i , 2 ) , u ˜ i , 1 u ˜ i , 2 H m i [ 0 , T ] .
Because of the associated inferences with [2], one hence obtains two consequences below.
Lemma 5
([2]). If condition (iii) of Assumption 1 holds, then, x j L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) , | u i U m i [ 0 , T ] s.t.
F i ( ω , s , x j ( ω , s ) , u i ( ω , s ) ) , v i u i ( ω , s ) 0 , v i K i , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω .
Lemma 6
([2]). If condition (iii) in Assumption 1 holds, then, x j , 1 L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) (resp., x j , 2 L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) ), | u i , 1 U m i [ 0 , T ] (resp., u i , 2 U m i [ 0 , T ] ) s.t.
F i ( ω , s , x j , 1 ( ω , s ) , u i , 1 ( ω , s ) ) , v i u i , 1 ( ω , s ) 0 , v i K i , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω , F i ( ω , s , x j , 2 ( ω , s ) , u i , 2 ( ω , s ) ) , v i u i , 2 ( ω , s ) 0 , v i K i , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω .
In addition, one has that M i > 0 s.t.
E 0 t u i , 1 ( ω , s ) u i , 2 ( ω , s ) 2 d s M i E 0 t x j , 1 ( ω , s ) x j , 2 ( ω , s ) 2 d s , t [ 0 , T ] .
In order to achieve the main results, we now analyze the convergent behavior of { ( x k ( s ) , u k ( s ) } , with x k ( s ) = ( x 1 , k , x 2 , k ) and u k ( s ) = ( u 1 , k , u 2 , k ) , constructed below:
x 1 ( τ ) = x 0 , u i , k ( τ ) = P U m i [ 0 , T ] ( u i , k ( τ ) ρ i F ˜ i ( x j , k ( τ ) , u i , k ( τ ) ) ) , x i , k + 1 = x i , 0 + 0 τ b i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d ι + α 0 τ ( τ ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d ι + 0 τ σ 0 i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d B i ( ι ) + 0 τ x i < c i G i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) .
Meanwhile, we will establish a few natures of { x k } .
Lemma 7.
For i = 1 , 2 , if ( x i , k 1 , u i , k 1 ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n i ) × U m i [ 0 , T ] , then E ( sup s [ 0 , T ] x i , k ( s ) 2 ) < .
Proof. 
For convenience, one puts k = ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) and Λ k = u k ( ι ) 2 + x k ( ι ) 2 + 1 . Using (9) and the relation below,
( j = 1 r j ) 2 r j = 1 r j 2 ,
one has
E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] x i , k ( τ ) 2 ) 5 E ( x i , 0 2 ) + 5 E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] 0 τ b i ( k 1 ) d ι 2 ) + 5 E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] 0 τ σ 0 i ( k 1 ) d B i ( ι ) 2 ) + 5 E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] 0 τ x i < c i G i ( k 1 , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) 2 ) + 5 α 2 E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] 0 τ ( τ s ) α 1 σ 1 i ( k 1 ) d ι 2 ) = 5 E ( x i , 0 2 ) + 5 I i , 1 + 5 I i , 2 + 5 I i , 3 + 5 α i 2 I i , 4 .
Noticing Lemmas 3 and 4 and Hölder-type inequality, by condition (i) of Assumption 1, one obtains
I i , 1 E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] τ 0 τ b i ( k 1 ) 2 d ι ) T E 0 T K b i Λ k 1 d ι < ,
I i , 2 ( 2 2 1 ) 2 E ( 0 T σ 0 i ( k 1 ) 2 d ι ) 4 E 0 T K σ 0 i Λ k 1 d ι < ,
I i , 3 ( 2 2 1 ) 2 E ( 0 T x i < c i G i ( k 1 , x i ) 2 ν i ( d x i ) d ι ) 4 E 0 T K G i Λ k 1 d ι < ,
I i , 4 E ( sup t [ 0 , T ] [ 0 t ( t ι ) 2 α 2 d ι 0 t σ 1 i ( k 1 ) 2 d ι ] ) E ( T 2 α 1 2 α 1 0 T K G i Λ k 1 d ι ) < .
So, we conclude from the above inequalities that
E ( sup τ [ 0 , T ] x i , k ( τ ) 2 ) 5 E ( x i , 0 2 ) + 5 I i , 1 + 5 I i , 2 + 5 I i , 3 + 5 α 2 I i , 4 < .
Obviously, the above lemma ensures that: if ( x i , k 1 , u i , k 1 ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n i ) × U m i [ 0 , T ] , then E ( sup s [ 0 , T ] x i , k ( s ) 2 ) < . This arrives at x i , k L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n i ) . □
We are now in a position to state and demonstrate that there holds the unique existence of solutions of issue (3) and (4).
Theorem 1.
There holds the unique existence of solutions of issue (3) and (4) provided that that Assumption 1 is satisfied.
Proof. 
For i = 1 , 2 , one defines x i , 1 ( τ ) : = x i , 0 τ [ 0 , T ] . Hence it is easily known from Lemma 5 and Lemmas 1 and 2 that | u i , 1 U m i [ 0 , T ] such that
u i , 1 ( τ ) = P U m i [ 0 , T ] ( u i , 1 ( τ ) ρ i F ˜ i ( x j , 1 ( τ ) , u i , 1 ( τ ) ) ) .
Also, we set
x i , k + 1 = x i , 0 + 0 τ b i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d ι + α 0 τ ( τ ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d ι + 0 τ σ 0 i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d B i ( ι ) + 0 τ x i < c i G i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) .
Then for any given ( x j , 1 , u i , 1 ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) × U m i [ 0 , T ] , it follows that x j , 2 L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) (because of Lemma 7). By Lemma 5 and Lemmas 1 and 2, we deduce that | u i , 2 U m i [ 0 , T ] such that
u i , 2 ( τ ) = P U m i [ 0 , T ] ( u i , 2 ( τ ) ρ i F ˜ i ( x j , 2 ( τ ) , u i , 2 ( τ ) ) ) .
Conducting such process persistently, we could fabricate { ( x k ( τ ) , u k ( τ ) } , in which x k ( τ ) = ( x 1 , k , x 2 , k ) and u k ( τ ) = ( u 1 , k , u 2 , k ) , satisfying the following:
u i , k ( τ ) = P U m i [ 0 , T ] ( u i , k ( τ ) ρ i F ˜ i ( x j , k ( τ ) , u i , k ( τ ) ) ) , x i , k + 1 = x i , 0 + 0 τ b i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d ι + α 0 τ ( τ ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d ι + 0 τ σ 0 i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) d B i ( ι ) + 0 τ x i < c i G i ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) ,
where 0 < ρ i < 2 C ¯ i L F i 2 .
Now let us show the convergence of { ( x k , u k ) } k 1 in L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , X ) × U m 1 + m 2 [ 0 , T ] , where
U m 1 + m 2 [ 0 , T ] : = { u ( ω , s ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , V ) : u ( ω , s ) K 1 × K 2 , a . s . ω Ω , a . e . s [ 0 , T ] } .
Indeed, for convenience, one puts k = ( ι , x k ( ι ) , u k ( ι ) ) , ξ k = x k 1 ( ι ) x k ( ι ) 2 , ζ k = u k 1 ( ι ) u k ( ι ) 2 , ξ i , k = x i , k 1 ( ι ) x i , k ( ι ) 2 and ζ i , k = u i , k 1 ( ι ) u i , k ( ι ) 2 . Noticing condition (ii) of Assumption 1, from Lemma 3 and Hölder-type inequality we get
E sup s [ 0 , τ ] x i , k ( s ) x i , k + 1 ( s ) 2 4 E T 0 τ b i ( k 1 ) b i ( k ) 2 d ι + 4 E sup s [ 0 , τ ] ( 0 s σ 0 i ( k 1 ) σ 0 i ( k ) d B i ( ι ) ) 2 + 4 E sup s [ 0 , τ ] ( 0 s x i < c i G i ( k 1 , x i ) G i ( k , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) ) 2 + 4 α 2 E sup t [ 0 , τ ] ( 0 t ( t ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( k 1 ) σ 1 i ( k ) d ι ) 2 = I ¯ i , 1 + I ¯ i , 2 + I ¯ i , 3 + I ¯ i , 4 .
According to Hölder-type inequality and Lemma 3, one gets
I ¯ i , 1 4 T L b i E 0 τ ξ k + ζ k d ι ,
I ¯ i , 2 4 × 4 E 0 τ σ 0 i ( k 1 ) σ 0 i ( k ) 2 d ι 16 L σ 0 i E 0 τ ξ k + ζ k d ι ,
I ¯ i , 3 4 × 4 E 0 τ x i < c i G i ( k 1 , x i ) G i ( k , x i ) 2 ν i ( d x i ) d ι 16 L G i E 0 τ ξ k + ζ k d ι ,
I ¯ i , 4 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 E 0 τ σ 1 i ( k 1 ) σ 1 i ( k ) 2 d ι 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i E 0 τ ξ k + ζ k d ι .
Using the above inequalities, we obtain
E sup s [ 0 , τ ] x i , k ( s ) x i , k + 1 ( s ) 2 ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) E 0 τ ξ k + ζ k d ι ,
that along with Lemma 6, leads to
E sup s [ 0 , τ ] x i , k ( s ) x i , k + 1 ( s ) 2 ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) × E 0 τ ξ k + ζ 1 , k + ζ 2 , k d ι ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) × E 0 τ ξ k + M 1 ξ 2 , k + M 2 ξ 1 , k d ι ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) × ( 1 + M 1 + M 2 ) E 0 τ ξ k d ι = β i E 0 τ ξ k d ι ,
where β i = ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) ( 1 + M 1 + M 2 ) . Therefore,
E sup ι [ 0 , τ ] x k ( ι ) x k + 1 ( ι ) 2 E sup ι [ 0 , τ ] x 1 , k ( ι ) x 1 , k + 1 ( ι ) 2 + E sup ι [ 0 , τ ] x 2 , k ( ι ) x 2 , k + 1 ( ι ) 2 β 1 E 0 τ ξ k d ι + β 2 E 0 τ ξ k d ι = ( β 1 + β 2 ) E 0 τ ξ k d ι β E 0 τ sup ι [ 0 , s ] x k 1 ( ι ) x k ( ι ) 2 d s ,
where β = β 1 + β 2 .
When k = 1 , we obtain from x 1 ( τ ) = x 0
E sup t [ 0 , τ ] x i , 2 ( t ) x i , 1 ( t ) 2 E sup t [ 0 , T ] x i , 2 ( t ) x i , 0 ( t ) 2 4 T E 0 T K b i ( 1 + x 0 2 + u 1 ( s ) 2 ) d s + 4 × 4 E 0 T K σ 0 i ( 1 + x 0 2 + u 1 ( s ) 2 ) d s + 4 × 4 E 0 T K G i ( 1 + x 0 2 + u 1 ( s ) 2 ) d s + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 E 0 T K σ 1 i ( 1 + x 0 2 + u 1 ( s ) 2 ) d s = η i .
This hence arrives at
E sup ι [ 0 , τ ] x 2 ( ι ) x 1 ( ι ) 2 E sup ι [ 0 , T ] x 1 , 2 ( ι ) x 1 , 0 2 + E sup ι [ 0 , T ] x 2 , 2 ( ι ) x 2 , 0 2 η 1 + η 2 = η ,
where
η = i = 1 2 4 ( T K b i + 4 K σ 0 i + 4 K G i + α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 K σ 1 i ) E 0 T ( 1 + x 0 2 + u 1 ( s ) 2 ) d s .
Thus, if k = 2 , then by (21) one gets
E sup ι [ 0 , τ ] x 3 ( ι ) x 2 ( ι ) 2 β E 0 τ sup μ [ 0 , s ] x 2 ( μ ) x 1 ( μ ) 2 d s β η τ .
Similarly, if k = 3 , we get
E sup t [ 0 , τ ] x 4 ( t ) x 3 ( t ) 2 β E 0 τ sup μ [ 0 , s ] x 3 ( μ ) x 2 ( μ ) 2 d s β 0 τ β η s d s = β 2 η τ 2 2 ! .
Conducting such process persistently, we could infer that
E sup t [ 0 , τ ] x k + 1 ( t ) x k ( t ) 2 η β k 1 τ k 1 ( k 1 ) ! 0 for each τ .
Utilizing the similar reasoning to that of the proof in [30], (Theorem 5.2.1), one has that for 1 k < m ,
( 0 T E x m ( s ) x k ( s ) 2 d s ) 1 / 2 l = k m 1 ( 0 T E x l + 1 ( s ) x l ( s ) 2 d s ) 1 / 2 l = k m 1 ( 0 T E sup t [ 0 , s ] x l + 1 ( t ) x l ( t ) 2 d s ) 1 / 2 l = k m 1 ( η β · β l T l l ! ) 1 / 2 0 ( k ) .
This ensures that { x k } is a Cauchy sequence in L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , X ) . So it follows that { x j , k } is Cauchy sequence in L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) , and so is { u i , k } in U m i [ 0 , T ] (by Lemma 6). Therefore, one infers that { ( x j , k , u i , k ) } is Cauchy sequence in L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) × U m i [ 0 , T ] . As a result, ( x j * , u i * ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n j ) × U m i [ 0 , T ] such that ( x j , k , u i , k ) ( x j * , u i * ) as n . Whereby, we obtain that x k x * and u k u * , with x * = ( x 1 * , x 2 * ) and u * = ( u 1 * , u 2 * ) . Because P U m i [ 0 , T ] is of continuity, it could be readily seen that
u i * ( ι ) = P U m i [ 0 , T ] ( u i * ( ι ) ρ i F ˜ i ( x j * ( ι ) , u i * ( ι ) ) ) .
We now define x ¯ = ( x ¯ 1 , x ¯ 2 ) as follows
x ¯ i ( τ ) : = x i , 0 + 0 τ b i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d ι + α 0 τ ( τ ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d ι + 0 τ σ 0 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d B i ( ι ) + 0 τ x i < c i G i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) ,
that along with (21), arrives at
E sup ι [ 0 , τ ] x ¯ ( ι ) x k ( ι ) 2 i = 1 2 ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) ( 1 + M 1 + M 2 ) × E 0 τ x * ( s ) x k 1 ( s ) 2 d s = β E 0 τ x * ( s ) x k 1 ( s ) 2 d s ,
where
β = j = 1 2 ( 4 T L b j + 16 L σ 0 j + 16 L G j + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 j ) ( 1 + M 1 + M 2 ) .
Thanks to x k x * , it is easily known that x k x ¯ . Thus, one deduces that x ¯ is equal to x * . Consequently, from (22) and (23) we obtain
u i * ( ι ) = P U m i [ 0 , T ] ( u i * ( ι ) ρ i F ˜ i ( x j * ( ι ) , u i * ( ι ) ) ) , x i * ( ι ) = x i , 0 + 0 ι b i ( τ , x * ( τ ) , u * ( τ ) ) d τ + α 0 ι ( ι τ ) α 1 σ 1 i ( τ , x * ( τ ) , u * ( τ ) ) d τ + 0 ι σ 0 i ( τ , x * ( τ ) , u * ( τ ) ) d B i ( τ ) + 0 ι x i < c i G i ( τ , x * ( τ ) , u * ( τ ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d τ , d x i ) .
Next, let us show the uniqueness of solutions to issue (3) and (4). Indeed, assume that ( x 1 ( t ) , u 1 ( t ) ) and ( x 2 ( t ) , u 2 ( t ) ) are both solutions of issue (3) and (4), with x i = ( x 1 , i , x 2 , i ) and u i = ( u 1 , i , u 2 , i ) . Utilizing the similar reasoning to that of the above proof, one gets
E sup s [ 0 , T ] x 1 ( s ) x 2 ( s ) 2 β E 0 T sup ι [ 0 , s ] x 1 ( ι ) x 2 ( ι ) 2 d s ,
where
β = i = 1 2 ( 4 T L b i + 16 L σ 0 i + 16 L G i + 4 α 2 T 2 α 1 2 α 1 L σ 1 i ) ( 1 + M 1 + M 2 ) .
Putting f ( τ ) = E sup s [ 0 , τ ] x 1 ( s ) x 2 ( s ) 2 τ [ 0 , T ] , one has
f ( T ) 0 T β f ( s ) d s ,
that along with Gronwall-type inequality, arrives at f ( τ ) = 0 τ [ 0 , T ] . For j = 1 , 2 , it then follows that
E sup s [ 0 , T ] x j , 1 ( s ) x j , 2 ( s ) 2 E sup s [ 0 , T ] x 1 ( s ) x 2 ( s ) 2 = f ( T ) = 0 .
Thus, by Lemma 6 we get
E sup s [ 0 , T ] x j , 1 ( s ) x j , 2 ( s ) 2 = 0 x j , 1 ( s ) x j , 2 ( s ) H n j [ 0 , T ] 2 = 0 and u i , 1 ( s ) u i , 2 ( s ) H m i [ 0 , T ] 2 = 0 .
It is noteworthy that, setting G i = 0 and σ 1 i = 0 in the above theorem, we can derive an extension of ([2], Theorem 3.1) since it incorporates the SSDE and SSVI. In what follows, for achieving the valuable property of solutions, we now furnish a basic tool.
Lemma 8.
For q ( 1 , ) , the following holds
t q τ q ( t τ ) q , t τ 0 .
For q ( 0 , 1 ) , the following holds
t q τ q ( t τ ) q , t τ 0 .
Whereby, we are ready to show the result below.
Theorem 2.
For u * U m 1 + m 2 [ 0 , T ] , x * L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , X ) and α ( 1 2 , 1 ) , one has that (nonnegative constants) C 1 , C 2 and C 3 , s.t.
C 3 + C 2 ( t ι ) 2 α 1 + C 1 ( t ι ) E x * ( t ) x * ( ι ) 2 , 0 ι t T .
Proof. 
For s , t [ 0 , T ] with t s , one obtains from (9),
x i * ( t ) x i * ( s ) = s t b i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d ι + s t σ 0 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d B i ( ι ) + s t x i < c i G i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) + α 0 s [ ( t ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( s ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ] d ι + α s t ( t ι ) α 1 σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d ι ,
which together with (10), leads to
x i * ( t ) x i * ( s ) 2 4 s t b i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d ι 2 + 4 s t σ 0 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) d B i ( ι ) 2 + 4 s t x i < c i G i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) , x i ) N ˜ i ( d ι , d x i ) 2 + 4 α 2 0 s [ σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( t ι ) 1 α σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( s ι ) 1 α ] d ι + s t σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( t ι ) 1 α d ι 2 = 4 J i , 1 + 4 J i , 2 + 4 J i , 3 + 4 α 2 J i , 4 .
Utilizing condition (i) in Assumption 1, from Hölder-type inequality and Lemmas 3 and 4 one gets
E 4 ( J i , 1 + J i , 2 + J i , 3 ) 4 ( T s ) E s t K b i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι + 4 E s t K σ 0 i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι + 4 E s t K G i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι [ 4 ( T s ) K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] [ ( t s ) + E s t x * ( τ ) 2 + u * ( τ ) 2 d τ ] [ 4 ( T s ) K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] [ ( t s ) + E s t x * ( τ ) 2 d τ + 2 E s t u * ( τ ) u 1 ( τ ) 2 + u 1 ( τ ) 2 d τ ] [ 4 ( T s ) K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] [ ( t s ) + E s t x * ( τ ) 2 d τ + 2 ( M 1 + M 2 ) E s t x * ( τ ) x 0 2 d τ + 2 E s t u 1 ( τ ) 2 d τ ] [ 4 ( T s ) K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] [ ( t s ) + E s t x * ( τ ) 2 d τ + 4 ( M 1 + M 2 ) E s t x 0 2 + x * ( τ ) 2 d τ + 2 E s t u 1 ( τ ) 2 d τ ] 4 [ ( T s ) K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] [ ( t s ) + ( 1 + 4 ( M 1 + M 2 ) ) E sup ι [ 0 , T ] x * ( ι ) 2 ( t s ) + ( M 1 + M 2 ) 4 E x 0 2 ( t s ) + 2 E s t u 1 ( ι ) 2 d ι ] C i , 1 ( t s ) + C i , 3 ,
where
C i , 1 = 4 [ T K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] [ 1 + ( 1 + 4 ( M 1 + M 2 ) ) E sup ι [ 0 , T ] x * ( ι ) 2 + ( M 1 + M 2 ) 4 E x 0 2 ] ,
and
C i , 3 = 8 [ T K b i + K σ 0 i + K G i ] E 0 T u 1 ( ι ) 2 d ι .
Utilizing condition (i) in Assumption 1, from Hölder-type inequality and Lemma 8 one has
E J i , 4 2 E 0 s [ σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( t ι ) 1 α σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( s ι ) 1 α ] d ι 2 + 2 E s t σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) ( t ι ) 1 α d ι 2 2 E 0 s σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) 2 d ι 0 s [ ( t ι ) α 1 ( s ι ) α 1 ] 2 d ι + 2 E s t σ 1 i ( ι , x * ( ι ) , u * ( ι ) ) 2 d ι s t ( t ι ) 2 α 2 d ι 2 E 0 T K σ 1 i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι × [ 0 s ( s ι ) 2 α 2 ( t ι ) 2 α 2 d ι + s t ( t ι ) 2 α 2 d ι ] 2 E 0 T K σ 1 i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι × [ 2 2 α 1 ( t s ) 2 α 1 + s 2 α 1 t 2 α 1 2 2 α 1 ] 2 E 0 T K σ 1 i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι × 3 2 α 1 ( t s ) 2 α 1 .
Let
C i , 2 = 24 α 2 2 α 1 E 0 T K σ 1 i ( u * ( ι ) 2 + x * ( ι ) 2 + 1 ) d ι .
Then
4 α 2 E J i , 4 C i , 2 ( t s ) 2 α 1 .
From the inequalities above, it follows that for s , ι [ 0 , T ] with ι s ,
C i , 3 + C i , 2 ( ι s ) 2 α 1 + C i , 1 ( ι s ) E x i * ( ι ) x i * ( s ) 2 .
Therefore,
E x * ( t ) x * ( s ) 2 = E x 1 * ( t ) x 1 * ( s ) 2 + E x 2 * ( t ) x 2 * ( s ) 2 ( C 1 , 1 + C 2 , 1 ) ( t s ) + ( C 1 , 2 + ( C 2 , 2 ) ( t s ) 2 α 1 + ( C 1 , 3 + C 2 , 3 ) = C 1 ( t s ) + C 2 ( t s ) 2 α 1 + C 3 ,
where C 1 = C 1 , 1 + C 2 , 1 , C 2 = C 1 , 2 + C 2 , 2 and C 3 = C 1 , 3 + C 2 , 3 . □
It is noteworthy that, if u 1 ( t ) is bounded, then for s , ι [ 0 , T ] with ι s , (3.22) can be changed into
E x * ( ι ) x * ( s ) 2 C ¯ 1 ( ι s ) + C ¯ 2 ( ι s ) 2 α 1 .

4. Applications to Stochastic SPE Systems

In the rest of this paper, we denote by the FSDE, SPE, APP, AP and BM the fractional stochastic differential equation, spatial price equilibria, asset price process, asset price and Brownian motion, respectively. Also, let the SC, DM, SM, PC and SS represent the stochastic circumstance, demand market, supply market, price of commodity and stochastic system, respectively.
It is well known that, the spatial-price equilibria models have played an important role in solving some practical problems arising from energy markets, agriculture, economics, and finance; see e.g., [1,5,23,31]. In 2024, Zeng et al. [23] exploited a FSDE driven by BM to indicate APP and modeled SPE in SC using FSDVI (2). Note that, for FSDVI (2), they had explained that the APP reveals the jumps [21] and memory [32] features, and BM is not strong enough to acquire the dynamics of AP changes. Accordingly, they had utilized the FSDVI (2) possessing Lévy jump to express stochastic SPE possessing jumps and memory.
Inspired by the study [23], we introduce and discuss a system of stochastic spatial-price equilibria, where each stochastic spatial-price equilibrium involves a commodity possessing jumps and memory in the time term of [ 0 , T ] . In what follows, we release certain symbols. Let n 1 = n 2 = n , m 1 = m 2 = n and l 1 = l 2 = n in the above section. Then for each l = 1 , 2 ,
  • S l , i : the ith-SM, i .
  • D l , j : the jth-DM, j .
  • a i j l ( ω , ι ) : the number of commodities transported from the SM S l , i to the DM D l , j at ι-time, and a l ( ω , ι ) = ( a i j l ( ω , ι ) ) R n × n .
  • S ¯ l , i ( ω , ι ) = j = 1 n a i j l ( ω , ι ) : the number of commodities supplied by SM S l , i at ι-time, and S ¯ l ( ω , ι ) = ( S ¯ l , 1 ( ω , ι ) , , S ¯ l , n ( ω , ι ) ) R n .
  • D ¯ l , j ( ω , ι ) = i = 1 n a i j l ( ω , ι ) : the demand for commodities in DM D l , j at ι-time, and D ¯ l ( ω , ι ) = ( D ¯ l , 1 ( ω , ι ) , , D ¯ l , n ( ω , ι ) ) R n .
  • p l , i ( ω , ι ) : the supply PC related to SM S l , i at ι-time, and p l ( ω , ι ) = ( p l , 1 ( ω , ι ) , , p l , n ( ω , ι ) )   L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n ) .
  • q l , j ( ω , ι ) : the demand PC related to DM D l , j at ι-time, and q l ( ω , ι ) = ( q l , 1 ( ω , ι ) , , q l , n ( ω , ι ) )   L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n ) .
  • c i j l ( ω , ι ) = c i j l ( a i j l ( ω , ι ) ) : a unit transported cost from S l , i to D l , j at ι-time, and c l ( ω , ι ) = ( c i j l ( ω , ι ) ) R n × n .
  • L a d 2 = L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n ) × L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n ) × L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n × n ) and
    a , b L a d 2 = E 0 T a ( ω , ι ) , b ( ω , ι ) d ι , a , b L a d 2 .
  • u l ( ω , ι ) = ( S ¯ l ( ω , ι ) , D ¯ l ( ω , ι ) , a l ( ω , ι ) ) R n × R n × R n × n .
  • K l = { ( A l , B l , C l ) : A l = ( A l , 1 , A l , 2 , , A l , n ) R n , B l = ( B l , 1 , B l , 2 , , B l , n ) R n , C l = ( C i j l ) R n × n , C i j l 0 , A l , i = j = 1 n C i j l , B l , j = i = 1 n C i j l } .
  • U K l [ 0 , T ] = { u l L a d 2 : u l ( ω , ι ) K l , a . e . ι [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω } .
Thanks to the impact of jump and memory statuses on the APP, we presume always that for l = 1 , 2 , APPs p l ( ω , t ) , q l ( ω , t ) solve the FSDES possessing jumps:
d p l ( ι ) = b 1 l ( ι , p l ( ι ) , S ¯ l ( ι ) ) d ι + σ 1 l ( ι , p l ( ι ) , S ¯ l ( ι ) ) ( d ι ) α + f 1 l ( ι , p l ( ι ) , S ¯ l ( ι ) ) d B 1 l ( ι ) + x < c l G 1 l ( ι , p l ( ι ) , S ¯ l ( ι ) , x ) N ˜ 1 l ( d ι , d x ) , p l ( 0 ) = p l , 0 , d q l ( ι ) = b 2 l ( ι , q l ( ι ) , D ¯ l ( ι ) ) d ι + σ 2 l ( ι , q l ( ι ) , D ¯ l ( ι ) ) ( d ι ) α + f 2 l ( ι , q l ( ι ) , D ¯ l ( ι ) ) d B 2 l ( ι ) + x < c l G 2 l ( ι , q l ( ι ) , D ¯ l ( ι ) , x ) N ˜ 2 l ( d ι , d x ) , q l ( 0 ) = q l , 0 ,
where b i l , σ i l , f i l , G i l are of suitable measurability, σ 1 l ( ι , p l ( ω , ι ) , S ¯ l ( ω , ι ) ) and σ 2 l ( ι , q l ( ω , ι ) , D ¯ l ( ω , ι ) ) are of continuity w.r.t. ι, B 1 l ( ι ) and B 2 l ( ι ) are two F ι -adapted BMs, N 1 l , N 2 l are both F ι -adapted Poisson measure, and their martingale measures of associated compensation are formulated as N ˜ i l ( d ι , d x ) : = N i l ( d ι , d x ) ν i l ( d x ) d ι for i = 1 , 2 . Moreover, we assume that N 1 l , N 2 l , B 1 l , B 2 l are independent mutually.
Resembling the concept given in [23], we could put forward the following concept of spatial-price equilibria system point in a stochastic circumstance affected with Lévy jumps and memory.
Definition 2.
Given u * = ( u 1 * , u 2 * ) , where u l * ( ω , ι ) = ( S ¯ l * ( ω , ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ω , ι ) , a l * ( ω , ι ) ) , l = 1 , 2 , s.t. u l * U K l [ 0 , T ] . u * is termed as a SPE system point in SC iff there hold the relations below: for l , m = 1 , 2 and l m
p l , i * ( ω , ι ) + c i j m ( a i j m * ( ω , ι ) ) = q l , j * ( ω , ι ) if a i j m * 0 q l , j * ( ω , ι ) if a i j m * = 0 a . e . ι [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω ,
with p l * ( ω , ι ) and q l * ( ω , ι ) satisfying (31).
Lemma 9.
K l U K l [ 0 , T ] , and they are of both convexity and closedness for l = 1 , 2 .
Proof. 
First, it is easy to check that K l is nonempty convex closed and hence U K l [ 0 , T ] is nonempty.
Let us show that U K l [ 0 , T ] L a d 2 is convex. Indeed, for each u l , 1 , u l , 2 U K l [ 0 , T ] and each μ [ 0 , 1 ] , we know that u l , 1 , u l , 2 L a d 2 and u l , 1 , u l , 2 K l . Because K l , which is of both convexity and closedness, the following relation is valid:
μ u l , 1 ( ω , ι ) + ( 1 μ ) u l , 2 ( ω , ι ) K l , a . e . ι [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω ,
and hence U K l [ 0 , T ] is of convexity.
In what follows, it is enough to only show the closedness of U K l [ 0 , T ] in L a d 2 . Let the sequence { u l , n } lie in U K l [ 0 , T ] s.t. u l , n u l * L a d 2 0 . Whereby, we know that u l * L a d 2 and
0 T E u l , n ( ω , ι ) u l * ( ω , ι ) 2 d ι 0 ,
that hence yields
u l , n ( ω , ι ) u l * ( ω , ι ) 0 , a . e . ι [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω .
Because K l is of closedness, one gets u l * U K l [ 0 , T ] , that is, U K l [ 0 , T ] is of closedness. □
For achieving the major outcome in this section, we release the symbols below. Let l , m = 1 , 2 and l m . For each ( p l , q l ) L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n ) × L a d 2 ( Ω × [ 0 , T ] , R n ) and each u m = ( S ¯ m , D ¯ m , a m ) U K m [ 0 , T ] , let
F ˜ m ( p l , q l , u m ) ( ω , ι ) = F m ( ω , ι , p l ( ω , ι ) , q l ( ω , ι ) , u m ( ω , ι ) ) , ω Ω , ι [ 0 , T ]
and
F ˜ m ( p l , q l , u m ) , u m L a d 2 = E 0 T p l ( ω , ι ) , S ¯ m ( ω , ι ) q l ( ω , ι ) , D ¯ m ( ω , ι ) + c m ( a m ( ω , ι ) ) , a m ( ω , ι ) d ι .
Theorem 3.
Given u * = ( u 1 * , u 2 * ) , where for m = 1 , 2 , u m * ( ω , ι ) = ( S ¯ m * ( ω , ι ) , D ¯ m * ( ω , ι ) , a m * ( ω , ι ) ) such that u m * U K m [ 0 , T ] . Then the following relations are equivalent:
(i)
u * is a dynamic stochastic market equilibria system point;
(ii)
u * solves the SVIS: for l , m = 1 , 2 and l m ,
F ˜ m ( p l * , q l * , u m * ) , u m u m * L a d 2 = E 0 T { p l * ( ω , ι ) , S ¯ m ( ω , ι ) S ¯ m * ( ω , ι ) q l * ( ω , ι ) , D ¯ m ( ω , ι ) D ¯ m * ( ω , ι ) + c m ( a m * ( ω , ι ) ) , a m ( ω , ι ) a m * ( ω , ι ) } d ι 0 , u m U K m [ 0 , T ] .
Proof. 
Such demonstration is analogous to that of Theorem 4.1 of [23]. □
Given α ( 1 2 , 1 ) . From Theorem 3 and (31), it could be readily seen that the SPE system in SC is equivalent to the SS below: for l , m = 1 , 2 and l m ,
d p l * ( ι ) = b 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) ) d ι + σ 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) ) ( d ι ) α + f 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) ) d B 1 l ( ι ) + x < c l G 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) , x ) N ˜ 1 l ( d ι , d x ) , p l * ( 0 ) = p l , 0 * , d q l * ( ι ) = b 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) ) d ι + σ 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) ) ( d ι ) α + f 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) ) d B 2 l ( ι ) + x < c l G 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) , x ) N ˜ 2 l ( d ι , d x ) , q l * ( 0 ) = q l , 0 * , F ˜ m ( p l * , q l * , u m * ) , u m u m * L a d 2 0 , u m U K m [ 0 , T ] .
which could be rewritten as the SFDVIS possessing Lévy jumps (due to Lemma 4):
d y 1 ( ι ) = b 1 ( ι , y 1 ( ι ) , u 1 ( ι ) ) d ι + σ 1 ( ι , y 1 ( ι ) , u 1 ( ι ) ) ( d ι ) α + f 1 ( ι , y 1 ( ι ) , u 1 ( ι ) ) d B 1 ( ι ) + x < c 1 G 1 ( ι , y 1 ( ι ) , u 1 ( ι ) , x ) N ˜ 1 ( d ι , d x ) , d y 2 ( ι ) = b 2 ( ι , y 2 ( ι ) , u 2 ( ι ) ) d ι + σ 2 ( ι , y 2 ( ι ) , u 2 ( ι ) ) ( d ι ) α + f 2 ( ι , y 2 ( ι ) , u 2 ( ι ) ) d B 2 ( ι ) + x < c 2 G 2 ( ι , y 2 ( ι ) , u 2 ( ι ) , x ) N ˜ 2 ( d ι , d x ) , y 1 ( 0 ) = y 1 , 0 and y 2 ( 0 ) = y 2 , 0 ,
and
F ¯ 1 ( ω , ι , y 2 ( ω , ι ) , u 1 ( ω , ι ) ) , v 1 u 1 ( ω , ι ) 0 , v 1 K 1 , a . e . ι [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω , F ¯ 2 ( ω , ι , y 1 ( ω , ι ) , u 2 ( ω , ι ) ) , v 2 u 2 ( ω , ι ) 0 , v 2 K 2 , a . e . ι [ 0 , T ] , a . s . ω Ω ,
where for l = 1 , 2 ,
y l ( ι ) = ( p l * ( ι ) , q l * ( ι ) ) T , y l ( 0 ) = ( p l , 0 * , q l , 0 * ) T , u l ( ω , ι ) = u l * ( ω , ι ) , b l ( ι , y l ( ι ) , u l ( ι ) ) = ( b 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) ) , b 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) ) ) T , σ l ( ι , y l ( ι ) , u l ( ι ) ) = ( σ 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) ) , σ 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) ) ) T , f l ( ι , y l ( ι ) , u l ( ι ) ) = f 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) ) 0 0 f 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) ) , G l ( ι , y l ( ι ) , u l ( ι ) , x ) = G 1 l ( ι , p l * ( ι ) , S ¯ l * ( ι ) , x ) 0 0 G 2 l ( ι , q l * ( ι ) , D ¯ l * ( ι ) , x ) , B l ( ι ) = ( B 1 l ( ι ) , B 2 l ( ι ) ) T , N ˜ l ( ι , x ) = ( N ˜ 1 l ( ι , x ) , N ˜ 2 l ( ι , x ) ) T , F ¯ 1 ( ω , ι , y 2 ( ω , ι ) , u 1 ( ω , ι ) ) = F 1 ( ω , ι , p 2 * ( ω , ι ) , q 2 * ( ω , ι ) , u 1 ( ω , ι ) ) , F ¯ 2 ( ω , ι , y 1 ( ω , ι ) , u 2 ( ω , ι ) ) = F 2 ( ω , ι , p 1 * ( ω , ι ) , q 1 * ( ω , ι ) , u 2 ( ω , ι ) ) .
Therefore, under the assumptions of Theorem 1, we deduce that there is only a SPE system point in SC affected with Lévy jumps and memory, provided the APPs fulfill (31).

5. Conclusions

This paper have introduced and analyzed a new symmetrical SFSDVI with Lévy jumps (3) and (4) which can be applied for acquiring the systems’ instability and memorability. By aid of Picard’s successive iteration method and the equivalent relationship of solutions to (3) and (4), along with Hölder-type inequality, Itô-type isometry and Doob-type inequality, we have shown that there holds the unique existence of solutions to issue (3) and (4) via a few mild assumptions. In addition, we have presented an illustrative instance of our theoretical outcomes to the SPE system in the SCs affected with Lévy jumps and memory. It is noteworthy that the fractional Brownian Motion (FBM) has captured extensive attention in SSs [27,33,34]. As well as we know, there has been no research work for one to explore the symmetrical SFSDVI driven by FBM. Whereby, it is naturally interesting and meaningful to delve into the symmetrical SFSDVI driven by FBM. So, there is no doubt for us to aim at studying such matters in the future.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang), L.-C.C., J.-C.Y. and Y.Z. (Yue Zeng); methodology, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang), L.-C.C., J.-C.Y. and Y.Z. (Yue Zeng); software, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang); validation, Y.-Y.H. and S.-Y.L.; formal analysis, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang), L.-C.C., J.-C.Y. and Y.Z. (Yue Zeng); investigation, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang), L.-C.C., J.-C.Y., Y.Z. (Yue Zeng), Y.-Y.H. and S.-Y.L.; resources, L.-C.C.; data curation, Y.Z. (Yue Zeng)., Y.-Y.H. and S.-Y.L.; writing-original draft preparation, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang), L.-C.C., J.-C.Y., Y.Z. (Yue Zeng), Y.-Y.H. and S.-Y.L.; writing-review and editing, Y.Z. (Yue Zhang), L.-C.C. and J.-C.Y.; visualization, Y.Z. (Yue Zeng), Y.-Y.H. and S.-Y.L.; supervision, L.-C.C.; project administration, L.-C.C.; funding acquisition, L.-C.C. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by the 2020 Shanghai Leading Talents Program of the Shanghai Municipal Human Resources and Social Security Bureau (20LJ2006100), the Innovation Program of Shanghai Municipal Education Commission (15ZZ068) and the Program for Outstanding Academic Leaders in Shanghai City (15XD1503100).

Data Availability Statement

Data are contained within the article.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Zhang, Y.J.; Gou, Z.; Huang, N.J.; Li, X.S. A class of stochastic differential variational inequalities with some applications. J. Nonlinear Convex. Anal. 2023, 24, 75–100. [Google Scholar]
  2. Zhang, Y.J.; Chen, T.; Huang, N.J.; Li, X.S. Euler scheme for solving a class of stochastic differential variational inequalities with some applications. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul. 2023, 127, 107577. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Pang, J.S.; Stewart, D.E. Differential variational inequalities. Math. Program. 2008, 113, 345–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Chen, X.J.; Chao, Z.; Fukushima, M. Robust solution of monotone stochastic linear complementarity problems. Math. Program. 2009, 117, 51–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Daniele, P. Time-dependent spatial price equilibrium problem: Existence and stability results for the quantity formulation model. J. Global. Optim. 2004, 28, 283–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Ceng, L.C.; Huang, N.J.; Wen, C.F. On generalized global fractional-order composite dynamical systems with set-valued perturbations. J. Nonlinear Var. Anal. 2022, 6, 149–163. [Google Scholar]
  7. Ceng, L.C.; Chen, B.L.; Liao, S.L.; Nguyen, V.T.; Yao, J.C. Solvability and optimal control of a system of semilinear nonlocal fractional evolution inclusions with partial Clarke subdifferential. Fractals 2024, 32, 2440009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Migórski, S.; Zeng, S.D. Mixed variational inequalities driven by fractional evolutionary equations. Acta Math. Sci. 2019, 39, 461–468. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Weng, Y.H.; Chen, T.; Li, X.S.; Huang, N.J. Rothe method and numerical analysis for a new class of fractional differential hemivariational inequality with an application. Comput. Math. Appl. 2021, 98, 118–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Zeng, S.D.; Liu, Z.H.; Migórski, S. A class of fractional differential hemivariational inequalities with application to contact problem. Z. Angew. Math. Phys. 2018, 69, 36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Liang, Y.S.; Ceng, L.C.; Yao, J.C.; Wu, W. On fuzzy fractional differential inclusion driven by variational-hemivariational inequality in Banach spaces. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul. 2024, 138, 108180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Liang, Y.S.; Ceng, L.C.; Yao, J.C.; Zeng, S.D. On second order differential inclusion driven by quasi-variational-hemivariational inequalities. Nonlinear Anal. Real World Appl. 2024, 77, 104060. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Ceng, L.C.; Huan, X.Z.; Liang, Y.; Yao, J.C. On stochastic fractional differential variational inequalities general system with Lévy jumps. Commun. Nonlinear Sci. Numer. Simul. 2025, 140, 108373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Ceng, L.C.; Cho, S.Y. On approximate controllability for systems of fractional evolution hemivariational inequalities with Riemann-Liouville fractional derivatives. J. Nonlinear Var. Anal. 2022, 6, 421–438. [Google Scholar]
  15. Ceng, L.-C.; Fu, Y.-X.; Yin, J.; He, L.; He, L.; Hu, H.-Y. The solvability of generalized systems of time-dependent hemivariational inequalities enjoying symmetric structure in reflexive Banach spaces. Symmetry 2021, 13, 1801. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Ceng, L.C.; Liu, Z.H.; Yao, J.C.; Yao, Y. Optimal control of feedback control systems governed by systems of evolution hemivariational inequalities. Filomat 2018, 32, 5205–5220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Ceng, L.C.; Wen, C.F.; Liou, Y.C.; Yao, J.C. A general class of differential hemivariational inequalities systems in reflexive Banach spaces. Mathematics 2021, 9, 3173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Abouagwa, M.; Li, J. Stochastic fractional differential equations driven by Lévy noise under Carathéodory conditions. J. Math. Phys. 2019, 60, 022701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ke, T.D.; Loi, N.V.; Obukhovskii, V. Decay solutions for a class of fractional differential variational inequalities. Fract. Calc. Appl. Anal. 2015, 18, 531–553. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Pedjeu, J.C.; Laddle, G.S. Stochastic fractional differential equations: Modeling, method and analysis. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2012, 45, 279–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Palanisamy, M.; Chinnathambi, R. Approximate controllability of second-order neutral stochastic differential equations with infinite delay and Poisson jumps. J. Syst. Sci. Complex. 2015, 28, 1033–1048. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Yang, Z.W.; Zang, X.C.; Zhang, Z.Q.; Wang, H. Strong convergence of euler-maruyama scheme to a variable-order fractional stochastic differential equation driven by a multiplicative white noise. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2021, 142, 110392. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Zeng, Y.; Zhang, Y.J.; Huang, N.J. A stochastic fractional differential variational inequality with Lévy jump and its application. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2024, 178, 114372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Weng, Y.H.; Chen, T.; Huang, N.J. A new fractional nonlinear system driven by a quasi-hemivariational inequality with an application. J. Nonlinear Convex. Anal. 2021, 22, 559–586. [Google Scholar]
  25. Xia, Y.S.; Wang, J. A general projection neural network for solving monotone variational inequalities and related optimization problems. IEEE Trans. Neural Netw. 2004, 15, 318–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Weng, Y.H.; Chen, T.; Huang, N.J.; O’Regan, D. A new class of fractional impulsive differential hemivariational inequalities with an application. Nonlinear Anal. Model. Control. 2022, 27, 199–220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Biagini, F.; Hu, Y.Z.; Øksendal, B.; Zhang, T.S. Stochastic Calculus for Fractional Brownian Motion and Applications; Springer: London, UK, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  28. Jumarie, G. Fractional Brownian motions via random walk in the complex plane and via fractional derivative, comparison and further results on their Fokker-Planck equations. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2004, 22, 907–925. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Yong, J.M.; Zhou, X.Y. Hamiltonian systems and HJB equations. In Stochastic Controls; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
  30. Øksendal, B. An introduction with applications. In Stochastic Differential Equations; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  31. Li, W.; Wang, X.; Huang, N.J. Differential inverse variational inequalities in finite dimensional spaces. Acta Math. Sci. 2015, 35, 407–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Farhadi, A.; Salehi, M.; Erjaee, G.H. A new version of Black–Scholes equation presented by time-fractional derivative. Iran. J. Sci. Technol. Trans. A Sci. 2018, 42, 2159–2166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Ahmadian, D.; Ballestra, L.V.; Shokrollahi, F. A Monte-Carlo approach for pricing arithmetic Asian rainbow options under the mixed fractional Brownian motion. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2022, 158, 112023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ballestra, L.V.; Pacelli, G.; Radi, D. A very efficient approach for pricing barrier options on an underlying described by the mixed fractional Brownian motion. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2016, 87, 240–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Zhang, Y.; Ceng, L.-C.; Yao, J.-C.; Zeng, Y.; Huang, Y.-Y.; Li, S.-Y. On Symmetrically Stochastic System of Fractional Differential Equations and Variational Inequalities. Symmetry 2025, 17, 138. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym17010138

AMA Style

Zhang Y, Ceng L-C, Yao J-C, Zeng Y, Huang Y-Y, Li S-Y. On Symmetrically Stochastic System of Fractional Differential Equations and Variational Inequalities. Symmetry. 2025; 17(1):138. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym17010138

Chicago/Turabian Style

Zhang, Yue, Lu-Chuan Ceng, Jen-Chih Yao, Yue Zeng, Yun-Yi Huang, and Si-Ying Li. 2025. "On Symmetrically Stochastic System of Fractional Differential Equations and Variational Inequalities" Symmetry 17, no. 1: 138. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym17010138

APA Style

Zhang, Y., Ceng, L.-C., Yao, J.-C., Zeng, Y., Huang, Y.-Y., & Li, S.-Y. (2025). On Symmetrically Stochastic System of Fractional Differential Equations and Variational Inequalities. Symmetry, 17(1), 138. https://doi.org/10.3390/sym17010138

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop