Constitutional Values in the Gig-Economy? Why Labor Law Fails at Platform Work, and What Can We Do about It?
Abstract
:1. Introduction and Methodology of the Study
2. Features of Gig-Work
2.1. Gig-Work: Old-Fashioned Casual/Temporary Work?
“In fact the traditional labor market that most closely approximates the lean platform model is an old and low-tech one: the market of day laborers–agricultural workers, dock workers, or other low-wage workers–who would show up at a site in the morning in the hope of finding a job for the day. (…) The gig-economy simply moves these sites online and adds a layer of pervasive surveillance. A tool of survival is being marketed by Silicon Valley as a tool of liberation.”[9] (p. 78)
- The employer’s costs of real estate and equipment can be eliminated or reduced;
- Supervisory and management costs and efforts can be avoided;
- Outsourcing can forestall contact with other workers and the formation of sodalities by fragmenting the labor force and by increasing competition in the labor market.
- Where the demand for the work is discontinuous—where, for example, the sufficiency of the work needed varies due to “fluctuation in product demand”—outwork can be preferable because of the flexibility it affords.
2.2. Why Is This Different from Previous Similar Legal Relationships?
- Tripartite relationship: In the case of the gig-economy, the work is not simply outsourced by a large company, which is then provided with labor, but in most cases the legal relationship is tripartite and the “employees” are directly connected to consumers on the platform. They are vulnerable to both the demands of the platform and their daily changing customers.
- Code and data control: The organization of work is not done by individuals, but by an algorithm. This feature has two aspects or consequences: (a) although the platform seems to only mediate, in reality it collects an unprecedented amount of data from both sides, so it “knows” both the “employer” and the “employee” in some depth. (b) Thus, it is able to “emulate” the market by continuously fine-tuning its operation in real time (Cohen, 2019), and thereby continuously manipulating and distorting the conditions of both the employer and the employee side for its own benefit.
- Network effects: Platforms, as several studies have shown, are also effective because they reach a very large size very quickly for several reasons (this is the so-called network effect), mainly due to the associated economies of scale. Consequently, they very quickly drive all their competitors out of the market. The gig-economy thus typically involves monopolistic or oligopolistic markets.
2.2.1. Tripartite Structure
“Platform Operators are at the core of the structure because they operate the technological platform for transactions to occur by both aggregating information and, in many instances, supplying ancillary services, such as facilitating payments required to engage in the provision and consumption of goods and services. Platform Operators administer the technology which creates the environment in which the actors operate and upon which the whole model is founded”[5] (p. 1029)
”at all in the case of gig platforms? [13]. Weiss suggests that the whole structure should be considered a complex entity and it is thus necessary to determine where in the triangle the individual functions that the employer traditionally performed are to be found. Five types of functions can be distinguished on this basis: (a) the function of establishing and terminating a legal relationship; (b) the enjoyment of work and its fruits, (acceptance); (c) the issuance of work and pay; (d) the management of the company’s internal market; (e) the company’s external market management. By definition, it is the employer who plays a crucial role in performing any of these functions. While Prassl and Risak [14] suggest that multiple employers are conceivable for platform work, Weiss, by contrast, argues in this regard that “the traditional category of employer no longer serves the purpose of identifying among these actors among the digital work structures who are responsible for the obligations associated with employer status”[13] (p. 16)
2.2.2. Algorithmic and Data Driven Control
- Continuous surveillance. Like Bentham’s Panopticon, employees are constantly monitored from the moment they log in to the app. For example, a taxi application registers not only the current location of the car and the passenger, but also the destination, time, route, and all conceivable data. If the driver deviates from the instructions in the application, he may be penalized. Algorithmic management, controlled by platform-based rating and reputation systems, is a much more efficient form of control than has been available heretofore. Well-performing workers are assigned more jobs than poorly performing ones, therefore customer evaluation has a direct impact on the amount of work that employees receive and, of course, on their income (see also [17]).
- While the app knows almost everything about employees and transactions, employees know almost nothing about how the app works. The Hungarian experience also supports this. Both the evaluation system and the rationale behind the allocation of jobs are opaque (a recent empirical study confirms this [20]).
- Workers on almost all platforms complain about the alienating, dehumanizing nature of algorithmic control. It is possible to work for a long time in such a way that the employee has almost no contact with his co-workers or human boss or superior.
2.2.3. Network Effects
“The value of the services offered often does not only depend on the inherent service features provided to a user but is also and possibly primarily determined by whether and how intensively they are used by other users. When such a connection exists between individual benefits and others ’decisions, one speaks of external or network effects.”
3. The Responses of the Law
3.1. Interpreting Platform Work as an Employment Relationship
- the worker is free from control and direction in the performance of the hiring entity in connection with the performance of the work, both under contract for the performance of the work and in face;
- the worker is performing work outside the usual course of the business of the hiring company;
- the worker is customarily engaged in an independently established trade, occupation, or business of the same nature as the work performed.
- A first approach is to ‘simply’ apply existing regulations to online platform work;
- A second approach is to take specific action to narrow the group of persons that will be considered ‘self-employed’, through the addition of an intermediate ‘(independent) worker’ category or a rebuttable presumption of employment;
- A third approach is to decouple the application of existing regulations from the status of employment, thus potentially making employment (for instance concerning minimum wages and social security) and health and safety regulations applicable also to the self-employed;
- Finally, a fourth approach is to provide specific (health and safety and/or other employment) protection for online platform workers, regardless of their employment status. This has been the approach taken in France, with the Act of 8 August 2016 on work, modernisation of social dialogue, and securing of career paths.
3.2. The Limits of Applying Labor Law to Gig-Work
4. Discussion: Proposal for a More Complex Approach
4.1. Platforms and Constitutional Values
4.2. Why (Constitutional) Values Matter on Platforms?
4.3. What Parts of the Already Existing Rules Can Be Used
4.3.1. General Data Protection Regulation
4.3.2. Platform to Business Regulation (P2B Regulation)
“[t]he ranking of goods and services by the providers of online intermediation services has an important impact on consumer choice and, consequently, on the commercial success of the business users offering those goods and services to consumers. (…) Predictability entails that providers of online intermediation services determine ranking in a non-arbitrary manner. Providers should therefore outline the main parameters determining ranking beforehand, in order to improve predictability for business users, to allow them to better understand the functioning of the ranking mechanism and to enable them to compare the ranking practices of various providers.”
“internal complaint-handling system shall be easily accessible and free of charge for business users and shall ensure handling within a reasonable time frame. It shall be based on the principles of transparency and equal treatment applied to equivalent situations, and treating complaints in a manner which is proportionate to their importance and complexity.”
4.3.3. Digital Services Act (DSA) and Digital Markets Act (DMA) Proposals
“provide business users, or third parties authorised by a business user, free of charge, with effective, high-quality, continuous and real-time access and use of aggregated or non-aggregated data, that is provided for or generated in the context of the use of the relevant core platform services by those business users and the end users engaging with the products or services provided by those business users” (Article 6 (1) (i)),
4.3.4. Artificial Intelligence Act Proposal
5. Conclusions
5.1. Theoretical Conclusions
5.2. Practical Conclusions for the Legislation
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Questions and Answers. First Stage Social Partners Consultation on Improving the Working Conditions in Platform Work. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/commission/presscorner/detail/en/qanda_21_656 (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- De Stefano, V. Crowdsourcing, the gig-economy, and the law. Comp. Labor Law Policy J. 2016, 37, 461–470. [Google Scholar]
- Steinbaum, M. Antitrust, gig-economy and labor market power. Law Contemp. Probl. 2019, 85, 45–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lianos, I.; Countouris, N.; de Stefano, V. Re-thinking the competition law/labor law interaction: Promoting a fairer labor market. Eur. Labor Law J. 2019, 10, 291–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Diaz-Granados, J.J.; Sheehy, B. The sharing economy & the platform operator-user-provider “PUP model”: Analytical legal frameworks. Intellect. Prop. Media Entertain. Law J. 2021, 31, 997–1041. [Google Scholar]
- Finkin, M.W. Beclouded work, beclouded workers in historical perspective. Comp. Labor Law Policy J. 2016, 37, 603–618. [Google Scholar]
- Gyulavári, T. Hakingazdaság a láthatáron. Az internetes munka fogalma és sajátosságai. Gig-economy on the horizon. The concept and features of internet-work. Iustum Aequum Salut. 2019, 155, 25–51. [Google Scholar]
- Sundararajan, A. The Sharing Economy. The End of Employment and the Rise of Crowd-Based Capitalism; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Srniczek, N. Platform Capitalism; Polity Press: Cambridge, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Schneiderman, E.T. Attorney General of the State of New York: AirBnB in the City. October 2014. Available online: https://ag.ny.gov/pdfs/AIRBNB%20REPORT.pdf (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Das, S. The Sharing Economy Creates a Dickensian World for Workers—It Masks a Dark Problem in the Labor Market Independent, 12 February 2017. Available online: https://www.independent.co.uk/voices/sharing-economy-gig-economy-uber-airbnb-workers-rights-a7575856.html (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Rubery, J.; Wilkinson, F. Outwork and segmented labor markets. In The Dynamics of Labor Market Segmentation; Wilkinson, F., Ed.; Academic Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1981. [Google Scholar]
- Weiss, M. The platform economy; The main challenges to labor law. In Regulating the Platform Economy. International Perspectives on New Forms of Work; Mendez, L.M., Ed.; Routlege: London, UK; New York, NY, USA, 2020. [Google Scholar]
- Prassl, J.; Risak, M. Uber, Taskrabbit, and Co.: Platforms as employers—Rethinking the legal analysis of crowdwork. Comp. Labor Law Policy J. 2016, 37, 619–652. [Google Scholar]
- Lessig, L. Code, Version 2.0; Basic Books: New York, NY, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
- Bain, P.; Taylor, P. Entrapped by the ‘electronic panopticon’? Worker resistance in the call centre. New Technol. Work. Employ. 2000, 15, 2–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wood, A.J.; Graham, M.; Lehdonvirta, V.; Hjorth, I. Good gig, bad gig: Autonomy and algorithmic control in the global gig economy, work. Employ. Soc. 2019, 33, 56–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Fernie, S.; Metcalf, D. (Not) Hanging on the Telephone: Payment Systems in the New Sweatshops, CEP Discussion Papers dp0390, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE. 1998. Available online: https://ideas.repec.org/p/cep/cepdps/dp0390.html (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Möhlmann, M.; Henfridsson, O. What People Hate about Being Managed by Algorithms, According to a Study of Uber Drivers, Harvard Business Review. August 2019. Available online: https://hbr.org/2019/08/what-people-hate-about-being-managed-by-algorithms-according-to-a-study-of-uber-drivers (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Makó, C.; Illéssy, M.; Pap, J. Work Related Learning as a Core Lever Shaping Voice Options (Hungarian Platform Workers’ Views on Representation), Crowdwork21 Project 2nd National Report, Hungarian Fieldwork Experiences. Budapest: ELKH National Research Network—Centre for Social Sciences, June 2021, p. 131.
- Varian, H.; Shapiro, C. Information Rules. Strategic Guide to the Network Economy; Harvard Business School Press: Boston, MA, USA, 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Franck, J.; Peitz, M. Market Definition and Market Power in the Platform Economy; Centre on Regulation in Europe (CERRE): Brussels, Belgium, 2019; Available online: https://www.cerre.eu/sites/cerre/files/2019_cerre_market_definition_market_power_platform_economy.pdf (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- McGillis v. Dep’t of Economic Opportunity et al., No. 3D15-2758 (3d Dist. Ct. of App. Fla. Feb. 1, 2017).
- O’Connor v. Uber Techs 82 F. Supp. 3d 1133 (ND Cal. 2015).
- SG Borello & Sons, Inc. v. Dep’t of Indust. Relations, (48 Cal. 3d 341, 350 (1989).
- Dynamex Operations W. v. Superior Court of Los Angeles 4 Cal. 5th 903 (2018).
- Garben, S. Protecting Workers in the Online Platform Economy: An Overview of Regulatory and Policy Developments in the EU; European Agency for Safety and Health at Work: Luxembourg, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Ferencz, J. Az Atipikus Munkaviszonyok Komplex Megközelítése (The Complex Approach of Atypical Working Relations). Ph.D. Thesis, Széchenyi István University, Győr, Hungary, 2014. Available online: https://doktiskjog.sze.hu/images/doktori.hu-ra/Ferencz%20J%C3%A1cint/%C3%A9rt_Ferencz_v%C3%A9d%C3%A9sre.pdf (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Regulation (EU) 2019/1150 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 20 June 2019 on Promoting Fairness and Transparency for Business Users of Online Intermediation Services (P2B Regulation); Publications Office of the EU: Bruxelles, Belgium, 2019.
- Regulation (EU) 2016/679 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 27 April 2016 on the Protection of Natural Persons with Regard to the Processing of Personal Data and on the Free Movement of Such Data, and Repealing Directive 95/46/EC (General Data Protection Regulation—GDPR); European Comission: Brussels, Belgium.
- European Comission. Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on a Single Market For Digital Services (Digital Services Act) and Amending Directive 2000/31/EC. COM/2020/825 Final (DSA Proposal); European Comission: Brussels, Belgium.
- European Comission. Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on Contestable and Fair Markets in the Digital Sector (Digital Markets Act) COM/2020/842 Final (DMA Proposal); European Comission: Brussels, Belgium.
- European Comission. Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council Laying Down Harmonised Rules on Artificial Intelligence (Artificial Intelligence Act) and Amending Certain Union Legislative Acts {SEC(2021) 167 Final}—{SWD(2021) 84 Final}—{SWD(2021) 85 final} (AIA Proposal); European Comission: Brussels, Belgium.
- Kennedy, R. Algorithms and the rule of law. Leg. Inf. Manag. 2017, 17, 170–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Devins, C.; Felin, T.; Kauffman, S.; Koppl, R. The law and big data. Cornell J. Law Public Policy 2018, 27, 357. Available online: https://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/cjlpp/vol27/iss2/3 (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Coglianese, C.; Lehr, D. Regulating by robot: Administrative decision making in the machine-learning era. Georget. Law J. 2017, 105, 1147. [Google Scholar]
- Moses, L.B.; Chan, J. Using big data for legal and law enforcement decisions: Testing the new tools. Univ. N. S. W. Law J. 2014, 37, 643. [Google Scholar]
- Crawford, K.; Schultz, J. Big data and due process: Toward a framework to redress predictive privacy harms. Boston Coll. Law Rev. 2014, 55, 93. [Google Scholar]
- Simon, M.; Lindsay, A.F.; Sosa, L.; Comparato, P. Lola v skadden and the automation of the legal profession. Yale J. Law Technol. 2018, 20, 234. [Google Scholar]
- Pasquale, F. Restoring transparency to automated authority. J. Telecommun. High Technol. Law 2011, 9, 235. [Google Scholar]
- Pasquale, F. Black-Box Society. The Secret Algorithms That Control Money and Information; Harvard University Press: Cambridge, MA, USA; London, UK, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Temme, M. Algorithms and transparency in view of the new general data protection regulation. Eur. Data Prot. Law Rev. 2017, 3, 473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Karageorgou, V. Transparency Principle as an Evolving Principle of EU Law: Regulative Contours and Implications. 2012. Available online: https://www.right2info.org/resources/publications/eu-karageorgou-vasiliki-transparency-principle-as-an-evolving-principle-of-eu-law (accessed on 12 July 2021).
- Frantziou, E. The horizontal effect of the charter of fundamental rights of the EU: Rediscovering of reasons for horizontality. Eur. Law J. 2015, 21, 657–679. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Ződi, Z.; Török, B. Constitutional Values in the Gig-Economy? Why Labor Law Fails at Platform Work, and What Can We Do about It? Societies 2021, 11, 86. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc11030086
Ződi Z, Török B. Constitutional Values in the Gig-Economy? Why Labor Law Fails at Platform Work, and What Can We Do about It? Societies. 2021; 11(3):86. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc11030086
Chicago/Turabian StyleZődi, Zsolt, and Bernát Török. 2021. "Constitutional Values in the Gig-Economy? Why Labor Law Fails at Platform Work, and What Can We Do about It?" Societies 11, no. 3: 86. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc11030086
APA StyleZődi, Z., & Török, B. (2021). Constitutional Values in the Gig-Economy? Why Labor Law Fails at Platform Work, and What Can We Do about It? Societies, 11(3), 86. https://doi.org/10.3390/soc11030086