Game-Theoretic Analysis to Examine How Government Subsidy Policies Affect a Closed-Loop Supply Chain Decision
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- How does the government social welfare optimization goal affect the optimal decision of a CLSC members?
- Do power structures and product type affect the used product collection, pricing, and investment decision of the product?
- Which policy stimulates the manufacturer to escalate investment in R&D and product collection activity?
- What are the main barriers associated with each subsidy policy that overturn the government, as well as CLSC members’ sustainability target?
Literature Review
2. Prerequisites and Assumptions
- Similar to Nielsen et al. [60]; Dey et al. [14]; Dey and Saha [61], the market demand is linearly dependent on the retail price and GL, and its functional form is , where a represents potential intrinsic demand, and represents GL sensitivity. Therefore, higher value for a means the consumer has the better perception about the product. For analytical simplicity, the coefficient of price sensitivity is normalized with the unit [15].
- It is assumed that re-manufacturing cost is less compared to manufacturing cost, i.e., [6,57]. The manufacturer invests to collect used products, where represents the scaling parameter, and represents the monetary benefit’s for the consumers for returning used products. If , this assumption is similar to Ma et al. [28], Xiao et al. [53], and Wan and Hong [57]. represents the collection rate . While optimizing objective functions, all members have access to the same information [51,59]. A portion () of the collected used products converts into new one [57].
- The manufacturer bears extra cost for green technology innovation. In a recent study by Zhang et al. [62], it was found that technological innovation have significant effects on regional industrial eco-efficiency. In this study, we assume that the manufacturer produces MDIGPs, and corresponding per unit and total R&D investment costs are considered as and , respectively. Therefore, and represents the efficiency of the manufacturer on per unit investment and investment in R&D, respectively. If , then the manufacturer invests in producing DIGPs [18,19]. If , then the product converts to MIGPs [63]. The fixed cost for the retailer and manufacturer are normalized to zero [14,15]. The government organizations provide a R&D subsidy on the total investment. As noted by Dey et al. [14], for MIGPs, the variable cost is directly proportional with the product quality, and it might not possible to recover the cost for the manufacturers. For example, installing emission reduction devices or packaging material are directly proportional to the unit product, but it is difficult for the manufacturer to recover the cost of those in the re-manufacturing process.
- The influence of three subsidy policies was analyzed. In Policy C, the government provides a subsidy on per unit product directly to consumers. Therefore, the consumers need to pay [12,64] for per unit purchase. In Policy RE, the manufacturer receives a subsidy , () on the investment effort on used product collection. In Policy T, the manufacturer receives a subsidy , () on the R&D investment [13,65] to improve GL.
- We find optimal decisions in a three-stage game to study the influence of government decision. Under the MS and RS games, the decision sequence is defined as follows:
- Step 1: The government decides the subsidy rate ( or or ) by maximizing social welfare;
- Step 2: In the MS game, the manufacturer decides , , and . In the RS game, the retailer decides the profit margin ;
- Step 3: In the MS game, the retailer decides the retail price . In the RS game, the manufacturer decides , , and .
3. The Models
3.1. Optimal Decisions in Policy C
- The greening levels, collection rates, and social welfare are identical under both games; and the amount of the subsidy on per unit product is higher under the MS game.
- The greening levels, collection rates, subsidy rates, and social welfare decrease with respect toand.
3.2. Optimal Decisions in Policy RE
- The greening levels, collection rate, and social welfare are always higher under the RS game: however, the subsidy rate is higher under the MS game
- The greening levels, collection rates, subsidy rates, and social welfare decrease with respect toand.
3.3. Optimal Decisions in Policy T
- The greening level, collection rate, and social welfare are always higher under the RS game; however, the subsidy rate is higher under the MS game.
- The greening levels, collection rates, subsidy rates, and social welfare decreases with respect toand.
3.4. Optimal Decisions in Absence of Subsidy
4. Analysis and Discussions
4.1. Consumer’s Perspective
4.2. Retailer and Manufacturer Perspectives
4.3. Government Perspective
4.4. When Manufacturer Produces Only DIGPs
4.5. Overall Implications
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Optimal Decision in Scenario MC
Appendix B. Optimal Decision in Scenario RC
Appendix C. Proof of Theorem 1
Appendix D. Proof of Theorem 2
Appendix E. Proof of Theorem 3
Appendix F. Proof of Theorem 4
Appendix G. Proof of Theorem 5
Appendix H. Proof of Theorem 6
References
- Abdallah, T.; Diabat, A.; Simchi-Levi, D. Sustainable supply chain design: A closed-loop formulation and sensitivity analysis. Prod. Plan. Control 2011, 23, 120–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Govindan, K.; Soleimani, H.; Kannan, D. Reverse logistics and closed-loop supply chain: A comprehensive review to explore the future. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 240, 603–626. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Guo, J.; He, L.; Gen, M. Optimal strategies for the closed-loop supply chain with the consideration of supply disruption and subsidy policy. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2019, 128, 886–893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Iris, Ç.; Lam, J.S.L. A review of energy efficiency in ports: Operational strategies, technologies and energy management systems. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2019, 112, 170–182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mishra, J.L.; Hopkinson, P.G.; Tidridge, G. Value creation from circular economy-led closed loop supply chains: A case study of fast-moving consumer goods. Prod. Plan. Control 2018, 29, 509–521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Savaskan, R.C.; Bhattacharya, S.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Closed-loop supply chain models with product Re-manufacturing. Manag. Sci. 2004, 50, 239–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Shaharudin, M.R.; Tan, K.C.; Kannan, V.; Zailani, S. The mediating effects of product returns on the relationship between green capabilities and closed-loop supply chain adoption. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 211, 233–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wang, Y.; Chang, X.; Chen, Z.; Zhong, Y.; Fan, T. Impact of subsidy policies on recycling and Re-manufacturing using system dynamics methodology: A case of auto parts in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 74, 161–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Helveston, J.P.; Liu, Y.; Feit, E.M.; Fuchsa, E.; Klampfl, E.; Michalekad, J.J. Will subsidies drive electric vehicle adoption? Measuring consumer preferences in the U.S. and China. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2015, 73, 96–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Han, X.; Feng, B.; Pu, X. Modelling decision behaviours in pricing game of closed-loop supply chains. J. Oper. Soc. 2015, 66, 1052–1060. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Iris, Ç; Asan, S.S. A review of genetic algorithm applications in supply chain network design. In Computational Intelligence Systems in Industrial Engineering; Atlantis Press: Paris, France, 2012; pp. 203–230. [Google Scholar]
- Sinayi, M.; Rasti-Barzoki, M. A game theoretic approach for pricing, greening, and social welfare policies in a supply chain with government intervention. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 196, 1443–1458. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, C.; Xia, G. Research on the dynamic interrelationship among R&D investment, technological innovation and economic growth in China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 4260. [Google Scholar]
- Dey, K.; Roy, S.; Saha, S. The impact of strategic inventory and procurement strategies on green product design in a two-period supply chain. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2019, 57, 1915–1948. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, W.; He, Y. Green pro duct design in supply chains under competition. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 258, 165–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ottman, J.A. Green Marketing: Challenges & Opportunities for the New Marketing Age; NTC Publishing Group: Lincolnwood, IL, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
- Basiri, Z.; Heydari, J. A mathematical model for green supply chain coordination with substitutable products. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 145, 232–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ghosh, D.; Shah, J. Supply chain analysis under green sensitive consumer demand and cost sharing contract. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 164, 319–329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Song, H.; Gao, X. Green supply chain game model and analysis under revenue-sharing contract. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 170, 183–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ghosh, D.; Shah, J. A comparative analysis of greening policies across supply chain structures. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2012, 135, 568–583. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, P.; Yi, S.P. Pricing policies of green supply chain considering targeted advertising and product green degree in the Big Data environment. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 164, 1614–1622. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, D.; Xiao, T. Pricing and green level decisions of a green supply chain with governmental interventions under fuzzy uncertainties. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 149, 1174–1187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Saha, S. Exploring the intervention of intermediary in a green supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 233, 1525–1544. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, X.; Wang, X.; Zhou, M. Firms’ green R&D cooperation behavior in a supply chain: Technological spillover, power and coordination. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 218, 118–134. [Google Scholar]
- Huang, Y.; Wang, K.; Zhang, T.; Pang, C. Green supply chain coordination with greenhouse gases emissions management: A game-theoretic approach. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 112, 2004–2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ranjan, A.; Jha, J.K. Pricing and coordination strategies of a dual-channel supply chain considering green quality and sales effort. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 218, 409–424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, I.; Yeh, J.S. Modeling closed-loop supply chains in the electronics industry: A retailer collection application. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2012, 48, 817–829. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, Z.J.; Zhang, N.; Dai, Y.; Hu, S. Managing channel profits of different cooperative models in closed-loop supply chains. Omega 2016, 59, 251–262. [Google Scholar]
- Saha, S.; Sarmah, S.P.; Moon, I. Dual channel closed-loop supply chain coordination with a reward-driven Re-manufacturing policy. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2016, 54, 1503–1517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, C.T.; Ren, M.L. Closed-loop supply chain coordination strategy for the remanufacture of patented products under competitive demand. Appl. Math. 2016, 40, 6243–6255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- He, Q.; Wang, N.; Yang, Z.; He, Z.; Jiang, B. Competitive collection under channel inconvenience in closed-loop supply chain. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 155, 155–166. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, X.; Xu, L.; Du, P.; Wang, W. Joint advertising, pricing and collection decisions in a closed-loop supply chain. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 167, 12–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Johari, M.; Motlagh, S.H. Coordination of social welfare, collecting, recycling and pricing decisions in a competitive sustainable closed-loop supply chain: A case for lead-acid battery. Ann. Oper. Res. 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, J.; Wei, J.; Sun, X. Coordination of fuzzy closed-loop supply chain with price dependent demand under symmetric and asymmetric information conditions. Ann. Oper. Res. 2017, 257, 469–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xie, J.P.; Liang, L.; Liu, L.; Ieromonachou, P. Coordination contracts of dual-channel with cooperation advertising in closed-loop supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 183, 528–538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Choi, T.M.; Li, Y.; Xu, L. Channel leadership, performance and coordination in closed loop supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2013, 146, 371–380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, W.; Zhang, Y.; Zhang, K.; Bai, T.; Shang, J. Reward-penalty mechanism for closed-loop supply chains under responsibility-sharing and different power structures. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 170, 178–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gao, J.; Han, H.; Hou, L.; Wang, H. Pricing and effort decisions in a closed-loop supply chain under different channel power structures. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 112, 2043–2057. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zheng, B.; Yang, C.; Yang, J.; Zhang, M. Dual channel closed loop supply chains: Forward channel competition, power structures and coordination. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2017, 55, 3510–3527. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bressanelli, G.; Perona, M.; Saccani, N. Challenges in supply chain redesign for the circular economy: A literature review and a multiple case study. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Coenen, J.; Van der Heijden, R.E.; Van Riel, A.C. Understanding approaches to complexity and uncertainty in closed-loop supply chain management: Past findings and future directions. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 201, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Diallo, C.; Venkatadri, U.; Khatab, A.; Bhakthavatchalam, S. State of the art review of quality, reliability and maintenance issues in closed-loop supply chains with Re-manufacturing. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2017, 55, 1277–1296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bottani, E.; Casella, G. Minimization of the environmental emissions of closed-loop supply chains: A case study of returnable transport assets management. Sustainability 2018, 10, 329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Garg, K.; Kannan, D.; Diabat, A.; Jha, P.C. A multi-criteria optimization approach to manage environmental issues in closed loop supply chain network design. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 100, 297–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Govindan, K.; Darbari, J.D.; Agarwal, V.; Jha, P.C. Fuzzy multi-objective approach for optimal selection of suppliers and transportation decisions in an eco-efficient closed loop supply chain network. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 165, 1598–1619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, J.; Chang, Y.; Wang, C.; Zhang, L. The green efficiency of industrial sectors in China: A comparative analysis based on sectoral and supply-chain quantifications. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2018, 132, 269–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hafezalkotob, A. Modeling intervention policies of government in price-energy saving competition of green supply chains. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2018, 119, 247–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, J.Y.; Dimitrov, S.; Pun, H. The impact of government subsidy on supply chains’ sustainability innovation. Omega 2019, 86, 42–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Safarzadeh, S.; Rasti-Barzoki, M. A game theoretic approach for pricing policies in a duopolistic supply chain considering energy productivity, industrial rebound effect, and government policies. Energy 2019, 167, 92–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mitra, S.; Webster, S. Competition in Re-manufacturing and the effects of government subsidies. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2008, 111, 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, W.; Zhao, Z.; Ke, H. Dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government consumption-subsidy. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2013, 226, 221–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shu, T.; Peng, Z.; Chen, S.; Wang, S.; Lai, K.K.; Yang, H. Government subsidy for Re-manufacturing or carbon tax rebate: Which is better for firms and a low-carbon economy. Sustainability 2017, 9, 156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Xiao, L.; Wang, X.; Chin, K.S.; Qin, Y. Competitive strategy in Re-manufacturing and the effects of government subsidy. J. Syst. Sci. Syst. Eng. 2017, 26, 417–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heydari, J.; Govindan, K.; Jafari, A. Reverse and closed loop supply chain coordination by considering government role. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2017, 52, 379–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jena, S.K.; Ghadge, A.; Sarmah, S.P. Managing channel profit and total surplus in a closed-loop supply chain network. J. Oper. Soc. 2018, 69, 1345–1356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jena, S.K.; Sarmah, S.P.; Padhi, S.S. Impact of government incentive on price competition of closed-loop supply chain systems. INFOR Inf. Syst. Oper. Res. 2018, 56, 192–224. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wan, N.; Hong, D. The impacts of subsidy policies and transfer pricing policies on the closed-loop supply chain with dual collection channels. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 224, 881–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Saha, S.; Majumder, S.; Nielsen, I.E. Dilemma in two game structures for a closed-loop supply chain under the influence of government incentives. J. Ind. Eng. Int. 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- He, P.; He, Y.; Xu, H. Channel structure and pricing in a dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government subsidy. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 213, 108–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Sana, S.; Saha, S. Comparative analysis of government incentives and game structures on single and two-period green supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 235, 1371–1398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dey, K.; Saha, S. Influence of procurement decisions in two-period green supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 190, 388–402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, J.; Liu, Y.; Chang, Y.; Zhang, L. Industrial eco-efficiency in China: A provincial quantification using three-stage data envelopment analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 143, 238–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mussa, M.; Rosen, S. Monopoly and product quality. J. Econ. Theory 1978, 18, 301–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shu, T.; Huang, C.; Chen, S.; Wang, S.; Lai, K.K. Trade-Old-for-Remanufactured Closed-Loop Supply Chains with Carbon Tax and Government Subsidies. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3935. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Saha, S.; Majumder, S.; Nielsen, I.E. Is it a strategic move to subsidized consumers instead of the manufacturer? IEEE Access 2019. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huang, J.; Leng, M.; Liang, L.; Liu, J. Promoting electric automobiles: Supply chain analysis under a government’s subsidy incentive scheme. IIE Trans. 2013, 45, 826–844. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fu, J.; Chen, X.; Hu, Q. Subsidizing strategies in a sustainable supply chain. J. Oper. Soc. 2017, 69, 283–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Y.; Quan, B.; Xu, Q.; Forrest, J.Y. Corporate social responsibility and decision analysis in a supply chain through government subsidy. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 2098, 436–447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ferrer, G.; Swaminathan, J.M. Managing new and differentiated remanufactured products. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 203, 370–379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Saha, S. Supply chain coordination through rebate induced contracts. Transp. Res. E Logist Transp. Rev. 2013, 50, 120–137. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Saha, S.; Goyal, S.K. Supply chain coordination contracts with inventory level and retail price dependent demand. Int. J. Prod Econ. 2015, 161, 140–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Study | Games | Effect | Nature of Subsidy | SW |
---|---|---|---|---|
of GL | Maximization | |||
Mitra and Webster [50] | MS | No | To the manufacturer to increase re-manufacturing activity | No |
Ma et al. [51] | MS | No | To consumers to procure new products | No |
Shu et al. [52] | MS | No | To the manufacturer for re-manufacturing | No |
Xiao et al. [53] | MS | No | To the manufacturer and consumer jointly | Yes |
Heydari et al. [54] | MS | No | To the manufacturer and retailer for re-manufacturing | No |
Jena et al. [55] | MS | No | Replacement subsidy to the customer and manufacturer | Yes |
Jena et al. [56] | MS | No | To the manufacturer for re-manufacturing | No |
Guo et al. [3] | MS | No | To the manufacturer for re-manufacturing | No |
Wan and Hong [57] | MS | No | To the manufacturer for re-manufacturing and retailer for recycling | No |
Saha et al. [58] | MS | No | To the manufacturer and to consumer based on the greening level | No |
He et al. [59] | MS | No | Directly to consumers | Yes |
Present study | MS and RS | Yes | Directly to consumers, to the manufacturer for improving quality and to the manufacturer for re-manufacturing | Yes |
wholesale price of the new/re-manufacturing product | |
market price | |
collection rate of used products | |
greening level | |
per unit subsidy received by the consumer from the government, () | |
subsidy received by the manufacturer on investment to improve recycling, () | |
fraction of subsidy received by the manufacturer on investment to improve GL, () | |
member k’s profit, | |
SW of government | |
sales volume |
© 2019 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Saha, S. Game-Theoretic Analysis to Examine How Government Subsidy Policies Affect a Closed-Loop Supply Chain Decision. Appl. Sci. 2020, 10, 145. https://doi.org/10.3390/app10010145
Nielsen IE, Majumder S, Saha S. Game-Theoretic Analysis to Examine How Government Subsidy Policies Affect a Closed-Loop Supply Chain Decision. Applied Sciences. 2020; 10(1):145. https://doi.org/10.3390/app10010145
Chicago/Turabian StyleNielsen, Izabela Ewa, Sani Majumder, and Subrata Saha. 2020. "Game-Theoretic Analysis to Examine How Government Subsidy Policies Affect a Closed-Loop Supply Chain Decision" Applied Sciences 10, no. 1: 145. https://doi.org/10.3390/app10010145
APA StyleNielsen, I. E., Majumder, S., & Saha, S. (2020). Game-Theoretic Analysis to Examine How Government Subsidy Policies Affect a Closed-Loop Supply Chain Decision. Applied Sciences, 10(1), 145. https://doi.org/10.3390/app10010145