A Business Model Framework to Characterize Digital Multisided Platforms
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Background
2.1. Perspectives on the Platform Concept
2.2. Digital Multisided Platforms
2.3. Characterizing a Digital Multisided Platform
3. Research Objectives and Method
3.1. Initial Framework Development
3.2. Exploratory Case Study and Framework Refinement
4. A Framework for Characterizing Multisided Platforms
4.1. Structure and Methodological Approach
- Level 1—Dimensions (D): The first level of the framework consists of six dimensions covering the main features of MSPs. The dimensions have been defined based on the findings of the literature analysis, that have been matched with the BM constituents [39] relevant for MSPs
- Level 2—Variables (V): A set of variables has been identified in order to characterize each dimension of the first level of the framework. The variables derive from the literature analysis with some refinement from the exploratory study;
- Level 3—Items (I): the third level of the framework encompasses a set of items that operationalize the variables of the second level. They have been defined based on the exploratory study of the 26 MSPs listed in Table 3.
- Binary items—They measure the presence of a specific platform feature, in the platform under investigation, and take the value “yes” or “no”;
- Configuration items—they can take a value among a set of predefined ones, which represent the possible configuration options;
- Open items—they are qualitative items for which it has not been possible to identify pre-defined set of configuration options, so an open description is allowed.
4.2. Platform Value Proposition
- Value proposition. The value proposition strongly depends on both the industry in which the platform operates and the services offered [71]. Indeed, an unclear definition of the value proposition may cause the failure of a business since it represents the main pillar of a BM.
- Function. DMSPs are diffused in several business sectors and may perform one or more of three different functions, namely: matchmaking, transaction and maker [53,72]. The matchmaking regards the capability to match the demand and offer among the sides. The transaction function refers to the possibility to make a transaction, between demand and offer, with the corresponding payment process through the platform. Finally, the maker function denotes the provision of specific tools or instruments that can be used by the users of a side to create, within the platform, a content to be transacted.
4.3. Platform Sides
- Segmentation. The platform may create a segmentation of different types of users within each side (e.g., premium users with additional functions or facilitations) [43];
- Engagement incentives. This variable investigates the presence of mechanisms that incentivize users in the platform to invite others to join [44];
- Direct externalities. This variable analyses the presence of mechanisms that make more valuable the joining of a potential user in one side based on the number of users already present in the same side [21].
4.4. Platform Revenue Model
- Financial flows between sides. A financial flow between sides may be present between users of two different sides and it is generally related to a transaction payment for the exchange of a product or a service [74];
- Referral fees. Referral fees represent economic flows that are given to a specific user of a side as a reward for its specific actions [75].
4.5. Platform Control
- Control mechanisms. The mechanisms arranged by the platform aim at controlling the behavior and the activities of the users as well as the contents provided through the platform [35].
- Rating and review system. The presence of a rating and review system helps both users in choosing the best match for their need and the platform manager in verifying potential incorrect behaviors [76].
- Exclusive agreements and contents. The presence of exclusive agreements between the platform manager and users allows the former to provide exclusive services or products so users are forced to join that platform [77].
4.6. Platform Competition
- Inside competition. Inside competition is the competition within one side. This generally might occur among the users of the supply side [47];
- Outside competition. Outside competition refers to the competitors of the DMSP under study. Competitors could be either MSPs or traditional businesses providing a similar value proposition [77];
4.7. Platform Architecture
- Versioning and update. This variable aims at understanding in which way the platform updates are arranged by the platform manager and how the versioning is organized [83];
- Platform access. This variable aims at investigating which are the “access ways” that the users can adopt in order to interact with other users [84];
5. Main Study: Description of Companies
5.1. Alpha
5.2. Beta
5.3. Sigma
6. Findings and Discussion
6.1. Value Proposition
6.2. Platform Sides
6.3. Platform Revenue Model
6.4. Platform Control
6.5. Platform Competition
6.6. Platform Architecture
7. Conclusions and Limitations
7.1. Scientific Contributions
7.2. Managerial Implications
7.3. Future Research Trends and Limitations
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Schallmo, D.; Williams, C.A.; Boardman, L. Digital transformation of business models—Best practice, enablers, and roadmap. Int. J. Innov. Manag. 2017, 21, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Evans, D.; Schmalensee, R. Matchmakers: The New Economics of Multisided Platforms; Harvard Business Review Press: Brighton, MA, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Rochet, J.C; Tirole, J. Platform competition in two-sided markets. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2003, 1, 990–1029. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Armstrong, M. Competition in two-sided markets. RAND J. Econ. 2006, 37, 668–691. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Eisenmann, T.; Parker, G.; Van Alstyne, M. Strategies for two-sided markets. Harv. Bus. Rev. 2006, 84, 92–101. [Google Scholar]
- Evans, D.; Schmalensee, R. The Antitrust Analysis of Multi-sided Platform Businesses. In Oxford Handbook on International Antitrust Economics; Blair, R., Sokol, D., Eds.; Oxford University: New York, NY, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Choudary, S.P. Platform Scale: How An Emerging Business Model Helps Startups Build Large Empires with Minimum Investment; Platform thinking Labs: Boston, MA, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Hagiu, A.; Wright, J. Multi-sided platforms. Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2014, 43, 162–174. [Google Scholar]
- Campbell-Kelly, M.; Garcia-Swartz, D.; Lam, R.; Yang, Y. Economic and business perspectives on smartphones as multi-sided platforms. Telecommun. Policy 2015, 39, 717–734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Tang, J.; Jin, Q.; Ma, J. On studying business models in mobile social networks based on two-sided market (TSM). J. Supercomput. 2014, 70, 1297–1317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kang, M.; Gao, Y.; Wang, T.; Zheng, H. Understanding the determinants of funders’ investment intentions on crowdfunding platforms: A trust-based perspective. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2016, 116, 1800–1819. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bryant, K.; Sheldon, P. Cyber Dating in the Age of Mobile Apps: Understanding Motives, Attitudes, and Characteristics of Users. Am. Commun. J. 2017, 19, 1–15. [Google Scholar]
- Rajeswari, M. A study on effectiveness of social media in recruitment process. Int. J. Econ. Res. 2017, 14, 367–373. [Google Scholar]
- Hagiu, A.; Wright, J. Marketplace or reseller? Manag. Sci. 2015, 61, 184–203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chesbrough, H.; Vanhaverbeke, W.; West, J. Open Innovation: Researching A New Paradigm; Oxford University Press on Demand: Oxford, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- De Oliveira, D.T.; Cortimiglia, M.N. Value co-creation in web-based multisided platforms: A conceptual framework and implications for business model design. Bus. Horiz. 2017, 60, 747–758. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Abhari, K.; Davidson, E.J.; Xiao, B. Co-innovation platform affordances: Developing a conceptual model and measurement instrument. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2017, 117, 873–895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ardolino, M.; Rapaccini, M.; Saccani, N.; Gaiardelli, P.; Crespi, G.; Ruggeri, C. The role of digital technologies for the service transformation of industrial companies. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2018, 56, 2116–2132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fu, W.; Wang, Q.; Zhao, X. Platform-based service innovation and system design: A literature review. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2018, 118, 946–974. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Piezunka, H. Technological platforms: An assessment of the primary types of technological platforms, their strategic issues and their linkages to organizational theory. J. Betr. 2011, 61, 179–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sriram, S.; Puneet, M.; Bravo, M.E.; Chu, J.; Ma, L.; Song, M.; Shriver, S.; Subramanian, U. Platforms: A multiplicity of research opportunities. Mark. Lett. 2015, 26, 141–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Belleflamme, P.; Peitz, M. Platform competition and seller investment incentives. Eur. Econ. Rev. 2010, 54, 1059–1076. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Matta, R.; Lowe, T.J.; Zhang, D. Competition in the multi-sided platform market channel. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 189, 40–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ondrus, J.; Gannamaneni, A.; Lyytinen, K. The impact of openness on the market potential of multi-sided platforms: A case study of mobile payment platforms. J. Inf. Technol. 2015, 30, 260–275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, H.H.; Chen, J.H. 11 Multisided platforms strategy in social entrepreneurship. In Social Entrepreneurship in the Greater China Region: Policy and Cases; Routledge: London, UK, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Täuscher, K.; Laudien, S.M. Understanding platform business models: A mixed methods study of marketplaces. Eur. Manag. J. 2018, 36, 319–329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jiao, J.; Simpson, T.; Siddique, Z. Product family design and platform-based product development: A state-of-the-art review. J. Intell. Manuf. 2007, 18, 5–29. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sanderson, S.; Uzumeri, M. Managing product families: The case of the Sony Walkman. Res. Policy 1995, 24, 761–782. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gawer, A.; Cusumano, M. Industry platforms and ecosystem innovation. J. Prod. Innov. Manag. 2014, 31, 417–433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gawer, A.; Henderson, R. Platform owner entry and innovation in complementary markets: Evidence from Intel. J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 2007, 16, 1–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yun, J.J.; Won, D.; Park, K.; Yang, J.; Zhao, X. Growth of a platform business model as an entrepreneurial ecosystem and its effects on regional development. Eur. Plan. Stud. 2017, 25, 805–826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Staykova, K.S; Damsgaard, J. Adoption of Mobile Payment Platforms: Managing Reach and Range. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2016, 11, 65–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rysman, M. The economics of two-sided markets. J. Econ. Perspect. 2009, 23, 125–143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhu, F.; Iansiti, M. Entry into platform-based markets. Strateg. Manag. J. 2012, 33, 88–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scholten, S.; Scholten, U. Platform-based innovation management: Directing external innovational efforts in platform ecosystems. J. Knowl. Econ. 2012, 3, 164–184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Coyle, D. Precarious and Productive Work in the Digital Economy. Natl. Inst. Econ. Rev. 2017, 240, 5–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Frishammar, J.; Cenamor, J.; Cavalli-Björkman, H.; Hernell, E.; Carlsson, J. Digital strategies for two-sided markets: A case study of shopping malls. Decis. Support Syst. 2018, 108, 34–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kim, J. Platform adoption factors in the internet industry. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3185. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Osterwalder, A.; Pigneur, Y. Business Model Generation: A Handbook for Visionaries, Game Changers, and Challengers; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Evans, D. Some Empirical Aspects of Multisided Platform Industries. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2003, 2, 191–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, J. Is online media a two-sided market? Comput. Law Secur. Rev. 2015, 31, 99–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Choudary, S.P.; Van Alstyne, M.; Parker, G. Platform Revolution: How Networked Markets Are Transforming the Economy—And How to Make Them Work for You; W. W. Norton & Company: New York, NY, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Gazé, P.; Vaubourg, A.G. Electronic platforms and two-sided markets: A side-switching analysis. J. High Technol. Manag. Res. 2011, 22, 158–165. [Google Scholar]
- Bhargava, H.K. Platform technologies and network goods: Insights on product launch and management. Inf. Technol. Manag. 2014, 15, 199–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van Alstyne, M.W.; Parker, G.G.; Choudary, S.P. Pipelines, platforms, and the new rules of strategy. Harv. Bus. Rev. 2016, 94, 54–62. [Google Scholar]
- Eisenmann, T. Managing Proprietary and Shared platforms. Calif. Manag. Rev. 2008, 50, 31–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thomes, T.P. In-house publishing and competition in the video game industry. Inf. Econ. Policy 2015, 32, 46–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jullien, B. Two-sided markets and electronic intermediaries. CESifo Econ. Stud. 2005, 51, 233–260. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Albuquerque, P.; Pavlidis, P.; Chatow, U.; Chen, K.Y; Jamal, Z. Evaluating promotional activities in an online two sided market of user-generated content. Mark. Sci. 2012, 31, 406–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Caillaud, B.; Jullien, B. Chicken and egg: Competition among intermediation service providers. RAND J. Econ. 2013, 34, 309–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goos, M.; Van Cayseele, P.; Willekens, B. Platform pricing in matching markets. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2013, 12, 437–457. [Google Scholar]
- Muzellec, L.; Ronteau, S.; Lambkin, M. Two-sided Internet platforms: A business model lifecycle perspective. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2015, 45, 139–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Evans, D.; Schmalensee, R. Markets with two-sided platforms. Compet. Law Policy 2008. Available online: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/255997636_Markets_with_Two-Sided_Platforms (accessed on 1 February 2020).
- Gawer, A. Platforms, Markets and Innovation; Edward Elgar Publishing: Cheltenham, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Huotari, P.; Kati, J.; Kortelainen, S.; Huhtamäki, J. Winner does not take all: Selective attention and local bias in platform-based markets. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2017, 114, 313–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Luchetta, G. Is the google platform a two-sided market? J. Compet. Law Econ. 2013, 10, 185–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Henten, A.H; Windekilde, I.M. Transaction costs and the sharing economy. Digit. Policy Regul. Gov. 2016, 18, 1–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schmalensee, R.; Evans, D. Industrial Organization of Markets with Two-Sided Platforms. Compet. Policy Int. 2007, 3, 150–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chen, Y.; Xie, J. Cross-market network effect with asymmetric customer loyalty: Implications for competitive advantage. Mark. Sci. 2007, 26, 52–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vasconcelos, H. Is exclusionary pricing anticompetitive in two-sided markets? Int. J. Ind. Organ. 2015, 40, 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Raivio, Y.; Luukkainen, S. Mobile networks as a two-sided platform-case open telco. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2011, 6, 77–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Miles, M.B.; Huberman, A.M. Qualitative Data Analysis: A Sourcebook; Sage Publications: Beverly Hills, CA, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
- Orton, J.D. From inductive to iterative grounded theory: Zipping the gap between process theory and process data. Scand. J. Manag. 1997, 13, 419–438. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pousttchi, K.; Schiessler, M.; Wiedemann, D.G. Proposing a comprehensive framework for analysis and engineering of mobile payment business models. Inf. Syst. E Bus. Manag. 2009, 7, 363–393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Im, K.; Cho, H. A systematic approach for developing a new business model using morphological analysis and integrated fuzzy approach. Expert Syst. Appl. 2013, 40, 4463–4477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Witt, T.; Stahlecker, K.; Geldermann, J. Morphological analysis of energy scenarios. Int. J. Energy Sect. Manag. 2018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zwicky, F. Compact galaxies and compact parts of galaxies. II. Astrophys. J. 1966, 143, 192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tholke, J.M.; Hultink, E.J.; Robben, H.S. Learning new product features: A multiple case examination. J. Prod. Innov. Manag. 2001, 18, 3–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yin, R.K. Case Study Research: Design and Methods. (Applied Social Research Methods, Volume 5) 005, 3rd ed.; Sage Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Zott, C.; Amit, R.; Massa, L. The business model: Recent developments and future research. J. Manag. 2011, 37, 1019–1042. [Google Scholar]
- Eloranta, V.; Turunen, T. Platforms in service-driven manufacturing: Leveraging complexity by connecting, sharing, and integrating. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2016, 55, 178–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ballon, P.; Van Heesvelde, E. ICT platforms and regulatory concerns in Europe. Telecommun. Policy 2011, 35, 702–714. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zingal, F.; Becker, F. Drivers of optimal prices in two-sided markets: The state of the art. J. Betr. 2013, 63, 87–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Akbar, Y.H.; Tracogna, A. The sharing economy and the future of the hotel industry: Transaction cost theory and platform economics. Int. J. Hosp. Manag. 2018, 71, 91–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Libai, B.; Biyalogorsky, E.; Gerstner, E. Setting referral fees in affiliate marketing. J. Serv. Res. 2003, 5, 303–315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hagiu, A.; Wright, J. Do You Really Want to Be an eBay? Harv. Bus. Rev. 2013, 91, 102–108. [Google Scholar]
- Cennamo, C.; Santalo, J. Platform competition: Strategic trade-offs in platform markets. Strateg. Manag. J. 2013, 34, 1331–1350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Landsman, V.; Stremersch, S. Multihoming in two-sided markets: An empirical inquiry in the video game console industry. J. Mark. 2011, 75, 39–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jiang, Y.; Shang, J.; Liu, Y.; May, J. Redesigning promotion strategy for e-commerce competitiveness through pricing and recommendation. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 167, 257–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mitra, A.; Ghosh, S.; Basuchowdhuri, P.; Shekhawat, M.K; Saha, S.K. Recommendation system based on product purchase analysis. Innov. Syst. Softw. Eng. 2016, 12, 177–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Häubl, G.; Murray, K.B. Preference construction and persistence in digital marketplaces: The role of electronic recommendation agents. J. Consum. Psychol. 2003, 13, 75–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Parguel, B.; Lunardo, R.; Benoit-Moreau, F. Sustainability of the sharing economy in question: When second-hand peer-to-peer platforms stimulate indulgent consumption. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Anderson, E.G.; Parker, G.G.; Tan, B. Platform performance investment in the presence of network externalities. Inf. Syst. Res. 2014, 25, 152–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Finley, B.; Soikkeli, T. Multidevice mobile sessions: A first look. Pervasive Mob. Comput. 2017, 39, 267–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kim, J.; Yoo, J. Platform Growth Model: The Four Stages of Growth Model. Sustainability 2019, 11, 5562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Research Domain | Concept | Perspective | Example | References |
---|---|---|---|---|
New product development | Product platform | The platform is a product that meets the needs of a core group of customers but is designed for easy modification into derivatives through the addition, substitution or removal of features. The platform allows to save costs and increase efficiency in product development through the reuse of common parts and ease in the manufacturing of a large number of derivative products. | Sony Walkman | [20,27,28] |
Technology management | Industry platform | The platform is a product, service or technology that is developed by one or several firms and that serve as the foundation upon which other firms can build complementary products, services or technologies. | Intel microprocessor | [5,29,30] |
Industrial organization | Multisided platform | The platform intermediates between two or more distinct groups of users enabling interactions among them. Therefore, a multisided platform consists of a shared facility in which the interactions take place among the users. | E-bay | [3,4,20,32,33] |
Area | Description | Reference |
---|---|---|
Network effects/Network externalities | Network effects (or network externalities) are a distinctive feature of a multisided platform, arising when the growth in usage by one side increases the value for the other side. Such interdependencies often lead to a feedback loop in which the number of participants on both sides affect each other recursively. | [3,4,40,50,51] |
Pricing | The pricing structure in a MSP generally makes the revenue model very complex. For instance, the price for one side can be zero and the profit by the platform manager is made only on the other side(s). Moreover, platform managers can choose among different kinds of fees to be applied. | [3,10,44,51] |
Integration and control | Platforms involve several users on each side. It is important to control the behavior of the users participating in the platform and contents provided. | [14,22,33,35] |
Engagement | Due to the presence of network effects (externalities), attracting users presents peculiar challenges, differently from traditional businesses, such as the so-called chicken and egg dilemma. Users on side “A” would not participate without users on side “B” and vice-versa. It is important to implement appropriate strategies to incentivize participation to all the sides of the platform. | [48,50,52] |
Competition | Platforms are subject to two main forms of competition: (1) outside competition—competition of the platform business with other similar businesses; (2) inside competition—competition among the users participating in the same side. | [53,54,55] |
Advertisement | Advertisement is an element often present in platform-based businesses. On the one hand, it is an important source of revenue for many businesses. On the other hand, it could be counterproductive because it causes frictions in interactions among the sides. | [48,49,56] |
Regulation and antitrust | Multisided platforms can provide new alternatives to conventional BMs and that tests the limits of existing regulatory policies. Traditional businesses and policy makers generally wonder and debate if MSPs conform to regulations and antitrust laws. | [56,57,58] |
Case | Description | Role of Person Interviewed |
---|---|---|
Case 1 | Crowdsourcing graphic design company | Vice President Engineering |
Case 2 | Online marketplace for renting vacation homes | Host Operations Lead |
Case 3 | Classifieds operating in second-hand cars and vehicles industry | Founder |
Case 4 | Booking platform for hotels and other kinds of accommodations | Regional Director |
Case 5 | Food delivery platform | Analytics Manager |
Case 6 | Crowdfunding platform | Founder |
Case 7 | E-commerce product marketplace | Head of Marketplace |
Case 8 | Crowdfunding platform | Founder |
Case 9 | Self-service ticketing platform | Business Development Manager (UK) |
Case 10 | Peer to peer car sharing platform | Vice President |
Case 11 | Social eating platform | Founder and CEO |
Case 12 | Couponing platform operating in products, beauty and travels | Country Communications Manager |
Case 13 | Marketplace for smartphone reparation services | Country Manager |
Case 14 | Classifieds operating in second-hand machinery industry | Cofounder |
Case 15 | Job seeking platform | Marketing Manager |
Case 16 | Platform enabling purpose-built industrial IoT applications to ensure connectivity to devices, applications, and data sources across industrial organizations. | Country manager |
Case 17 | Dating platform | Country Manager |
Case 18 | Lead generator platform for service centers | Founder and CEO |
Case 19 | Caregiving services marketplace | Analytics Manager |
Case 20 | Meta search engine in travel industry | Senior Growth Strategist |
Case 21 | Classifieds platform for products | Product director |
Case 22 | Household services marketplace | Chief architect and Technical Cofounder |
Case 23 | Metasearch engine for holiday accommodations | Country manager Italy and Portugal |
Case 24 | Peer to peer car sharing platform | Director of International Expansion |
Case 25 | People transportation services marketplace | Marketing Manager |
Case 26 | Cloud-based, open IoT operating platform for plants, systems and machines. | Country Business Developer |
Company | Description | Geographic Coverage | Platform Sides | Role of Respondent |
---|---|---|---|---|
Alpha | Italian company providing a solution to help customers and taskers to meet, interact and close good deals. Customers request for price quotation filling out a specific form on the platform with all the detailed information of the service needed. Taskers are able to see this request and, if interested, they pay a fee to obtain the contact information of the customer in order to provide a price quotation. The customer can receive up to 5 price quotations. | Italy | Customers Taskers | 1 interview Role: Company CEO and founder |
Beta | Multinational French company operating in long-distance ridesharing. Through a large community of users, Beta enables interactions between drivers and passengers willing to go to the same destination and share the cost of the journey. | Europe, Brasil, India, Mexico | Drivers Passengers | 2 interviews Roles: (1) Marketing manager (2) Public relations manager |
Sigma | Multinational American cloud computing company that provides business software solutions on a subscription basis. The company is well known for its on-demand customer relationship management (CRM) solution offering users with a customer community, developer community and an app exchange marketplace. | Global | Customers App developers | 1 interview Role: Exclusive Sigma app developer |
Variables | Items | Item Type | Options |
---|---|---|---|
Value proposition | Value proposition | Open | |
Function | Function | Configuration | Matchmaking; Transaction; maker |
Variables | Items | Item Type | Options |
---|---|---|---|
Sides | Number of sides | Configuration | From 2 to N sides |
Sides type | Configuration | Supply; Demand; Peer; Maker; Advertisement | |
Segmentation | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Segment participation criteria | Configuration | Payment of a fixed fee; Payment of an interaction extra-fee; Achievement of a specific objective; Platform registration | |
Benefits | Configuration | Enhanced services and/or functions; Enhanced visibility | |
Benefit standardization | Configuration | Standard; Customized | |
Engagement incentives | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Reward | Binary | Yes; No | |
Reward type | Configuration | Amount of money to be spent in the platform (for both users); Amount of money to be spent in the platform (only for the user already present to the platform); Amount of money to be spent in the platform (only for the user invited to join the platform); Reward different from an amount of money to be spent in the platform | |
Reward setting | Open | ||
Direct externalities | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Direct externalities characteristics | Open | - |
Variables | Items | Item Type | Options |
---|---|---|---|
Affiliation fees | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Payer | Configuration | [All the sides involved in the platform] | |
Standardization | Configuration | Standard; Customized | |
Frequency | Configuration | Una tantum; Regular frequency [specify] | |
Amount | Open | ||
Interaction fees | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Payer | Configuration | [All the sides involved in the platform] | |
Standardization | Configuration | Standard; Customized | |
Interaction charged | Open | ||
Calculation | Configuration | Fixed fee per each interaction; Percentage of an economic flow related to the interaction | |
Amount | Open | ||
Financial flows between sides | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Transaction object | Open | ||
Referral fees | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Recipients | Configuration | Sides involved in the platform | |
Amount | Open |
Variables | Items | Item Type | Options |
---|---|---|---|
Control mechanisms | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Type | Configuration | Identity check; User requirements; Contents (products/services) quality; Respect of the rules of the platform | |
Timing | Configuration | Ex-ante; ex-post | |
Rating and review system (R&R) | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Sides involved | Configuration | [All the sides involved in the platform] | |
R&R direction | Configuration | Unilateral; Bilateral | |
R&R privacy | Configuration | Public; Partially public; Private | |
Exclusive agreements and contents | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Side(s) involved | Configuration | [All the sides involved in the platform] | |
Benefits characteristics | Open |
Variables | Items | Item Type | Options |
---|---|---|---|
Inside competition | Presence | Binary | Yes; No |
Sides involved | Configuration | [All the sides involved in the platform] | |
Platform manager influence presence | Binary | Yes; No | |
Platform manager influence type | Configuration | Enhanced visibility respect others users; Showing ratings results; Specific recognitions by the platform manager | |
Outside competition | Main competitors organization model | Configuration | Platform business; Traditional business |
Main competitors value proposition | Configuration | Similar value proposition; Partial overlapping value proposition | |
Main competitors geographical market | Configuration | Same geographical market; Different geographical market | |
Multihoming | Multihoming | Configuration | Allowed; Partially allowed; Forbidden |
Variables | Items | Item Type | Options |
---|---|---|---|
User registration | User registration | Configuration | Registration necessary to access; Registration necessary to interact; No registration needed but it allows to benefit from customized services; No registration envisaged in the platform |
Boundaries between sides | Boundaries between sides | Configuration | Clear distinction between sides; No distinction between sides |
Versioning and update | Versioning and update | Configuration | Platform versions automatically updated with no charge; Platform versions automatically updated with charge; Platform versions "updatable" with charge; Platform versions "updatable" with no charge |
Platform access | Web portal implementation | Binary | Yes; No |
Dedicated application implementation | Binary | Yes; No | |
Operating system (app) | Configuration | iOS; Android | |
Openness | Platform openness | Configuration | Closed; Open |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Ardolino, M.; Saccani, N.; Adrodegari, F.; Perona, M. A Business Model Framework to Characterize Digital Multisided Platforms. J. Open Innov. Technol. Mark. Complex. 2020, 6, 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6010010
Ardolino M, Saccani N, Adrodegari F, Perona M. A Business Model Framework to Characterize Digital Multisided Platforms. Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity. 2020; 6(1):10. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6010010
Chicago/Turabian StyleArdolino, Marco, Nicola Saccani, Federico Adrodegari, and Marco Perona. 2020. "A Business Model Framework to Characterize Digital Multisided Platforms" Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity 6, no. 1: 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6010010
APA StyleArdolino, M., Saccani, N., Adrodegari, F., & Perona, M. (2020). A Business Model Framework to Characterize Digital Multisided Platforms. Journal of Open Innovation: Technology, Market, and Complexity, 6(1), 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6010010