Next Article in Journal
A Distributed Algorithm for the Assignment of the Laplacian Spectrum for Path Graphs
Next Article in Special Issue
Pricing and Carbon-Emission-Reduction Decisions under the BOPS Mode with Low-Carbon Preference from Customers
Previous Article in Journal
Data-Driven Optimized Artificial Neural Network Technique for Prediction of Flyrock Induced by Boulder Blasting
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Green Supply Chain Coordination Considering Carbon Emissions and Product Green Level Dependent Demand

Department of Decision Sciences, School of Business, Macau University of Science and Technology, Macau, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2023, 11(10), 2355; https://doi.org/10.3390/math11102355
Submission received: 27 April 2023 / Revised: 14 May 2023 / Accepted: 15 May 2023 / Published: 18 May 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Modeling, Simulation and Optimization of Supply Chains)

Abstract

:
As traditional supply chains face increasingly severe environmental issues, and as countries promote green development and sustainable development policy concepts, cultivating green supply chain operation models is gradually coming to be highly valued by governments and enterprises. Generally speaking, the production of green products incurs higher additional costs, and thus, their total production costs also increase. In this work, we studied the coordination mechanism, by considering carbon emissions and product green level dependent demand, in which the product green level is related to the random demand. Under the green supply chain buyback contract with the green product R & D cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer, both the product green level and the order quantity need to be decided, to maximize the channel profit. In order to coordinate the green supply chain, the manufacturer needs to share both the risk of good salvage and the green product R & D cost with the retailer. We found that both the wholesale price and the buyback price increase in the manufacturer’s proposition of the green product R & D cost, but decrease in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient or carbon trading price. In addition, the product green level, the optimal order quantity and the channel profit increase in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient, but decrease in the R & D cost coefficient of the product green level. Interestingly, we found that if the carbon trading price is low, the manufacturer will set a low product green level, and the product carbon emission trading is a cost for the supply chain. The increment of the carbon trading price leads to a higher cost, such that the channel profit is decreased. However, if the carbon trading price is high, the manufacturer will set a high product green level, and the product carbon emission trading is a revenue for the supply chain. The increment of the carbon trading price leads to a higher revenue, such that the channel profit is increased.

1. Introduction

The increase in the number of motor vehicles is an important manifestation of social and economic development and improvement in people’s living standards; however, the continuous increase in the number of motor vehicles has entailed pollution problems. The use maintenance and scrapping of motor vehicles entail environmental problems [1]. For example, exhaust gas problems caused by the use of motor vehicles (fuel vehicles) have increased demand for charging, leading to increased load on the power grid, and to pollution problems caused by increased demand for power generation at the source level (new energy vehicles or electric cars), tire wear particles (TWP) problems caused by low-tech tires, increased unit energy consumption and increased accident rates, due to tire wear air pollution, soil pollution and water pollution caused by dismantling, recycling and landfilling of scrapped cars, due to age or other reasons [2].
The harm caused by greenhouse gases is well-known, and the problem of exhaust emissions caused by the operation of internal combustion engines has become the focus of policy formulation by governments around the world. A series of policies have been successfully implemented, to reduce this aspect of traffic-related exhaust emissions. With the further promotion and use of new energy vehicles, PM (particulate matter) exhaust emissions will be further alleviated. However, the attention being paid to pollution caused by waste generated by friction between tires and the ground is still insufficient. For a long time, research on microplastics has focused only on thermoplastic materials such as polyethylene or polystyrene, without considering elastomeric materials, such as rubber. According to ISO’s definition, rubber is not included in the definition of plastic. By contrast, some academics have suggested a broader and more commonsense definition of microplastics that includes common macromolecular materials: hence, the inclusion of rubber [3].
The technical content of tires should receive attention, for its impact on the environment and driving safety. A tire is a round, black object that seems to have little technical content, but is not cheap. Consumers usually make tire purchase decisions based on price. In fact, in a typical radial passenger car tire, there are 20 or more components, and 15 or more rubber compounds. Tires are highly engineered structural composites, the performance design of which must meet the smoothness handling and traction standards of automobile manufacturers, as well as customer expectations of quality and performance. A medium-sized car’s tires rotate more than 1200 times per kilometer, and within 50,000 km each tire component undergoes more than 24 million loading and unloading cycles, requiring extremely high endurance [4]. The waste generated by the friction between a single tire and the ground seems insignificant, but on a global scale it is considerable, and it is predicted that, in the near future, pollution caused by this type of frictional wear will not decrease [2,5].
Microplastics are considered a global threat by many studies, due to their widespread presence in all regions inhabited by humans, as a result of the extensive use of automobiles. Microplastics permeate all ecosystems, and have the potential to impact the health of aquatic and terrestrial organisms, including humans, through various exposure pathways, such as food chains, drinking water and air [6,7,8,9]. According to academic and industry definitions, microplastics are polymer materials with a maximum diameter of no more than 5 mm, which are insoluble in water, and have an extremely low degradation rate [10]. Particles released from tire wear fit this description, and were recognized as a new type of potential pollutant by industry scholars as early as the 1970s [11]. Because of their insoluble and non-degradable nature, the distribution and residues of microplastics remain highly uncertain after decades of self-processing in nature [12]. The composition of tire wear varies, depending on the brand and intended use of the original tire. A typical passenger tire may contain 30 types of styrene–butadiene rubber, 8 types of natural rubber, 8 types of carbon black and over 40 different chemicals, as well as polyester and nylon fibers [13,14]. Different ingredient ratios result in a large number of tire formulations. The main components include 40–60% rubber content (including synthetic and natural rubber), 20–35% fillers (carbon black and silica) and 12–15% various oils [15]. The physical and chemical properties of tire wear particles (TWP) have not been sufficiently studied, as they can also absorb materials from the road and the surrounding environment [13]. The rate of tire wear particle (TWP) production due to road wear has been reported to vary between 10% to 50%, which may be related to road surface materials, including asphalt, road dust, gravel, oil, and plasticizers, all of which have an impact on the production of TWPs [9]. The amount and rate of tire wear particle production varies according to a number of factors, and, according to studies, increases due to vehicle loads, under- or over-inflation of tires, wheel alignment deviations, wheel position (front wheels wear first), transitional exposure to the elements, sudden braking, acceleration or sustained high speeds [10,16]. Kole et al. estimated data on TWPs from tire wear: based on the global population and the number of motor vehicles of all types, they estimated that emissions have reached nearly 6 million tons per year [16], equivalent to about 0.81 kg per capita per year. Some components of tires have been proven to be toxic; therefore, it is necessary to reduce the amount of these harmful substances released into the external environment [17,18,19].
As cars travel, the continuous wear of tires releases microplastic particles into the environment. Excessive tire wear can also affect driving safety. According to statistics from the World Health Organization, more than 1.3 million people die each year from road traffic accidents. Road traffic accident is one of the top ten causes of death for all age groups, and this trend is on the rise, especially for young people [20]. The health of a moving vehicle’s tires is only one of the causes of road traffic accidents, but road traffic accidents related to tire health problems can lead to more grievous injury to life and damage to property [21]. A study using seven years of Louisiana crash data showed that sudden tire failure and excessive tire wear significantly affect the severity of road crashes [22]. A substantial proportion of traffic accidents are caused by lack of vehicle maintenance, and by tire defects. For example, data from the United States show that in the National Motor Vehicle Crash Causation Survey (NMVCCS), conducted from 2005 to 2007, out of approximately 44,000 traffic accidents related to vehicle defects, more than 15,000 were related to tire defects, accounting for over 35%. According to a report from the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration (NHTSA), an average of nearly 11,000 tire-related motor vehicle accidents occur annually in the United States, resulting in approximately 200 fatalities. In 2017, a total of 738 people died in tire-related traffic accidents on American roads. These fatalities have drawn attention to the study of factors that cause tire failure, and to the analysis of the severity of injuries in tire-related accidents.
Therefore, it is necessary to develop green tires with better environmental performance (e.g., more wear-resistant, better air-tightness and better anti-burst performance), both for environmental protection and for the safety of people and property. Because of the increasingly serious environmental problems and the systematic promotion of the concept of green development, the cultivation of a green supply chain operation model is also gaining more and more attention from government, and from upstream and downstream enterprises in the supply chain.
The development and production of green tires can be traced back to 1992, when Michelin produced the first recognized green tire. This product strategy, which focuses on environmental protection, has brought Michelin both economic and social benefits [23]. In 2012, the European Union officially implemented a European tire labeling Regulation. This Regulation requires that car tires, light truck tires, truck tires and bus tires sold in the EU must have a label indicating the tire’s rolling resistance (fuel efficiency), rolling noise and wet grip performance levels. The introduction of this regulation is seen as a sign of the official promotion of high-quality green tires [24]. Subsequently, various countries have introduced labeling regulations related to tire rolling resistance. In 2016, China also issued a tire labelling law requiring that energy consumption, wet grip and noise be indicated on tires. Although green tires are relatively more expensive than ordinary tires, their superior performance, more user-friendly experience, lower fuel consumption and more environmentally friendly energy-saving features have made them increasingly popular among consumers.
Generally speaking, the development of green products requires relatively high research and development costs, and their selling prices are also higher. As China’s economy has entered a new stage in recent years, and its society has increasingly valued green environmental protection, consumers have also paid more attention to the low-carbon economy. Improving the greenness of products is one of the important ways to achieve this. Many studies have pointed out that today’s consumer concept makes buyers willing to choose products with carbon emission labels. Market demand changes with consumer willingness, prompting product manufacturers to innovate technology to produce low-carbon and environmentally friendly green products, to enhance their competitiveness in the market [25].
The green product market is still in its infancy. In order to further expand the market, and to gain a competitive advantage while also making long-term plans, it is necessary for companies to actively invest in the research and development of green products, and to produce green environmental protection products that meet government policy guidance, social development and consumer preferences. This article proposes that when green product manufacturers increase investment in research and development, and reduce carbon emissions, retailers can also effectively participate, which is conducive to promoting benign cooperation between manufacturers and retailers, increasing economic income and further enhancing the core competitiveness of enterprises. We conducted research on the current situation of green economy and carbon emissions development, and, based on systematic observations of green supply chain repurchase contracts, combined with supply chain theory, we conducted in-depth research on supply chain repurchase coordination and cost-sharing. We have striven to propose suggestions for effectively ensuring the coordination of the green supply chain system, and to provide research support for further enhancing the competitive advantage of the green supply chain in the rapid development process of the current market economy.
Based on the analysis above, there are three important questions: (1) When the random demand is related to the product green level, and considering carbon emissions trading, how to coordinate the green supply chain? (2) How does carbon emissions trading affect supply chain profit and coordination? (3) How to share the R & D cost between the parties in the green supply chain? The main purpose and significance of this study was to investigate these questions. The main contribution and results of this work are as follows:
  • Unlike the findings of the classic literature, random demand is related to the product green level. In addition, the R & D cost is shared between the manufacturer and the retailer. Under the green supply chain buyback contract, both the product green level and order quantity need to be decided. In order to coordinate the green supply chain, the manufacturer needs to share both the goods salvage risk and the R & D cost;
  • Under the green supply chain buyback contract, we found that both the wholesale price and buyback price increase in the manufacturer’s proposition of the R & D cost, but decrease in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient or carbon trading price.
  • Both the product green level and the optimal order quantity increase in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient, but decrease in the R & D cost coefficient of the product green level. The channel profit increases in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient, but decreases in the R & D cost coefficient of the product green level.
  • If the carbon trading price is low, the manufacturer will set a low product green level, and the product carbon emission trading is a cost for the supply chain. The increment of the carbon trading price leads to a higher cost, such that the channel profit is decreased. However, if the carbon trading price is high, the manufacturer will set a high product green level, and the product carbon emission trading is a revenue for the supply chain. The increment of the carbon trading price leads to a higher revenue, such that the channel profit is increased.
The structure of this work is organized as follows. The background, motivation and main contribution of this work are introduced in Section 1. We review the related literature in Section 2. In Section 3, we describe the model for the parties in the supply chain, and we show the centralized decisions and decentralized decisions: the product green level and the order quantity. In Section 4, we use a buyback contract, with R & D cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer, to coordinate the supply chain. In Section 5, we analyze the impact of the green emissions trading on the optimal channel profit. We conclude our work, and outline further research, in Section 6.

2. Literature Review

GSCM is defined as the “Integration of the company’s purchase plans with the environmental activities in SCM, to improve the environmental performance of suppliers and customers” [26]. Supply chain is essentially strategic alliances between companies with different core production businesses that have established long-term cooperation relationships [27]. Green supply chains (GSCs) have a strong orientation in the direction of change in the industrial environment. Since the introduction of the concept of green development, the focus of society has been on the study of green supply chains and the evolution of green coordination contracts in conjunction with various environmental factors. This study is closely related to three streams of the literature: buyback contracts; green supply chains; and carbon emissions.

2.1. Buyback Contract

Ref. [28] argues that traditional models, such as revenue sharing and buyback contracts, can have positive effects, and can help to coordinate the supply chain, by addressing discrepancies between the retailer’s order quantity and actual demand. However, when product demand is significantly influenced by other factors, ref. [29] argues that, although traditional contracts and buyback contracts are fundamentally different, they may become ineffective. Ref. [30] found that there is a positional relationship between retailers and market demand; however, reasonable predictions can be made, based on past sales experience. Assuming that the prediction error is negligible, the retailer can make corresponding promotional efforts, and can design a coordination mechanism that combines profit contribution with cost sharing. Ref. [31] argues that in buybacks, the wholesale price and buyback price are determined by the supplier, while the order quantity and retail price are determined by the retailer. When the buyback price is much lower than the wholesale price, more than one condition must be met, for supply chain coordination to be successful. Ref. [32] developed a dual-channel supply chain model, composed of a retailer with capital constraints and a supplier with sufficient funds, in which the retailer can apply the trade credit financing (TCF) from the supplier; to reduce the conflict between the two channels, they proposed a supplier revenue-sharing contract, to coordinate the supply chain.

2.2. Carbon Emissions

In the relevant literature on emission estimation, it is clearly evident that the content of the greenhouse inventory has a great impact on early national policies related to carbon emissions. By analyzing the emission inventories of different emission sources, ref. [33] further pointed out that fossil fuel combustion is currently the largest influencing factor in climate change, and is also the focus of current human social and economic improvement. This study further estimated greenhouse gas emissions from dozens of international metropolises, using carbon emission coefficients and defined measurement factors. Ref. [34] estimated the energy consumption and carbon emissions of 20 mega-cities in China, and found that carbon emissions per capita are increasing rapidly by more than 20%; therefore, it is imperative to further control carbon emissions in large cities, with the help of high technology. Ref. [35] used the life cycle method to carry out relevant calculations on direct carbon emissions from energy combustion in China: the results showed that, in 2017, China’s direct carbon emissions from energy consumption increased by more than 300% compared to 1979. Ref. [36] used the LMDI decomposition method to conduct an empirical analysis of China’s data from 1995 to 2017. They believed that carbon emission factors have the following four components: energy structure; energy efficiency; energy intensity; and economic development. The results were summarized in categories, including total energy consumption, technical factors, energy consumption structure and industrial structure. The carbon emission quota trading mechanism is a highly effective emission reduction measure at present: it may encourage more enterprises to follow the market development trend, and to promote the stable and long-term development of enterprises. Experts and scholars use simulation methods to study how carbon quotas and carbon emission rights can place a reasonable constraint on enterprises, thereby effectively reducing carbon emissions [37].
Most related research provides references for production choices during enterprise production. Ref. [38] believes that, against a background where a government has agreed on carbon emission quotas, and has established a carbon emission trading market, when retailers possess and have fair preferences, the type of contract will have a differential impact on coordinating the supply chain. Ref. [39] explored how enterprises can carry out technical emission reduction when facing constraints, and how to make decisions on production, manufacturing, inventory and other issues. The focus was on analyzing the weight of carbon emission trading and the proportion of enterprise production operations. The type of product has a great impact on carbon emissions. Limited by current green emission reduction technology, some green products may actually cause higher carbon emissions. There is a need for further research on the issue of enterprise green product development under multi-cycle conditions.
After analyzing the literature on carbon emissions research, it can be seen that using different models, to clarify the impact of carbon emission trading on the entire supply chain, further provides scientific and effective guidance for enterprise production. The existing literature on carbon emissions included an in-depth analysis of the effects and significance of considering carbon emissions, which provided a solid theoretical reference for this study.

2.3. Green Supply Chains

The concept of the green supply chain has been defined through numerous papers, in view of its practical application to the development of modern enterprises, and to further enhance the value of its application. Ref. [33] argues that green supply chain management (GSCM) was initially studied as a secondary aspect of the logistics management research process, and that changes in supply chain management have occurred as a result of environmental factors.
Ref. [40] notes that the Manufacturing Research Association of Michigan State University launched an ‘Environmentally Responsible Manufacturing’ survey, with the support of a Foundation, and first proposed the concept of a green supply chain in 1996. Therefore, based on the relevant research on green supply chain management by representative foreign scholars, it can be seen that the definition of green supply chain management is ‘environmentally conscious supply chain management’. Measures must be taken to address environmental issues at every stage of the daily supply chain. By studying the impact of numerous factors on the environment and the overall economy, effective protection can be achieved, while balancing both economic and environmental considerations.
Green supply chain management is now being practiced in all of China’s hotspot industries, and the concept of green supply chains will be gradually introduced in more and more areas, as global research on green supply chains intensifies. In the manufacturing industry, ref. [41] wanted to seek synergies between green management and performance development in enterprises at this stage, and further derived contract negotiation coordination mechanisms, such as negotiation coordination and decentralized balanced decision making based on green management coordination. In the rubber industry, ref. [42] analyzed the impact of green supply chain practices on organizational performance. In the field of construction, ref. [43] described how, under the guidance of government policies, an experimental simulation was conducted, to analyze the impact of government policies on the green supply chain at this stage, based on the game behaviors of various participants, and then a model was constructed to protect the construction industry, resulting in a green supply chain implementation tool that can effectively satisfy the economic interests of different parties. In the financial field, ref. [44] believes that green supply chain finance continues to promote the upgrading and transformation of the financial industry. Research shows that, at this stage, electronic order financing models and B2B e-commerce credit scoring can promote long-term cooperation between upstream and downstream enterprises in green supply chains, and can build trust between them. In the field of logistics, with the increasing demand for fruits and vegetables, ref. [45] described the current development status of fruit and vegetable cold chain logistics. With the actual operating efficiency of cold chain logistics in China, and the suggestions and countermeasures proposed under the green supply chain, the application of green supply chains is currently expanding horizontally at all levels, but the specific research is uneven and not in-depth, making it difficult to implement the application of green supply chain management practices.
The practical implementation of green supply chains faces a variety of issues, such as the inability to conduct objective performance evaluations. Effective performance evaluations can provide support for the development of more systematic management policies. Fuzzy evaluation and the analytic hierarchy process are qualitative methods among effective performance evaluation methods, and are widely used. Ref. [46] believes that multi-objective decision making exists in the process of green supply chain evaluation, and that it should be conducted from multiple links, and use the network analytic hierarchy process to start from the four basic links of the supply chain. Ref. [47] used the queue model to study inventory policy with two classes of customers in a supply chain. Ref. [48] showed how, based on the DEMTEL method, green supply chain performance evaluation indicators are classified and identified on the basis of comprehensive management of processes, information and services. Key evaluation indicators are obtained, and their secondary evaluation indicator system is evaluated comprehensively from four standards: environmental reputation; environmental impact; resource re-usability; and energy consumption using the analytic hierarchy process. Ref. [49] identified the dimensions of the green supply chain, and their impact on manufacturing practices, and developed a green supply chain management model, using interpretive structural modeling. Ref. [50] innovatively developed a three-level indicator system based on the gray correlation analysis method, on the basis of the connotation and characteristics of green supply chains. Ref. [51] evaluated the impact of clean technology adoption and environmental taxes on the TA supply chains. They found that if the buyer’s market share is sufficiently large (small), the optimal greenness level for this buyer’s product increases (decreases) in the environmental tax rate; whereas if the two product market shares are relatively equal, the optimal greenness levels for both products buyers increase in the environmental tax rate. The existence of the spillover effect reduces the cost, and improves the product’s greenness. Recently, by examining the moderating and mediating effects of strategic procurement 4.0 performance, ref. [52] explored the role of procurement 4.0 in the circular economy, and its impact on organizational competitiveness, and made a significant contribution to the emerging research in this field.
In conclusion, there are three points that summarize the theory and practice of green supply chain management. Firstly, there are some deficiencies in both the content and definition of green supply chain research in China. Secondly, it is not difficult to see from the relevant research literature that in the manufacturing industry, significant progress has been made in green supply chain management, in terms of processes, operational indicators and related policy research; moreover, it has been widely practiced in the management application of actual enterprises; however, the development of industries, such as finance, agriculture and logistics, is still relatively immature. Finally, in terms of performance evaluation research, scholars have further developed their research, based on various perspectives, to effectively enrich performance-evaluation-related indicators, and to obtain a more accurate evaluation indicator system.

3. Basic Model for Green Supply Chains Considering Carbon Emissions

As economic development enters a new stage, and people’s mindsets change, people are paying more attention to low-carbon economy, because of economic development and the importance of green environmental protection in recent years. Local governments have explicitly proposed actively promoting low-carbon green development, accelerating the construction of innovative incentives for practice, and strengthening green and environmental industries. Traditional fuel vehicles emit a large amount of carbon dioxide, and new energy vehicles can solve this problem. Recently, many logistics companies, such as sf-express, have been using new energy vehicles to transport their goods, to reduce carbon emissions. A series of policies have been successfully implemented, to reduce this part of traffic-related exhaust emissions [3].
Consumers are paying more attention to carbon emissions and energy efficiency labels when shopping, and this is driving manufacturers to innovate and upgrade their industries. Manufacturers are increasing the market demand for their products, by increasing the greenness of their products, while adding additional research and development costs that are only borne by the manufacturers, leaving them to make decisions between the cost of research and development and increasing market demand. At the same time, retailers are ordering to meet market demand, but are concerned about the possibility of a backlog of stock. A contract is therefore needed to reconcile the decision to order with the decision to green the product, to eliminate this conflict arising from the double marginal effect of the green supply chain. This chapter will discuss the optimal decision of green manufacturers and retailers in the case of random demand and deciding the greenness of products based on the consideration of tradable carbon emissions.

3.1. Description of the Problem and Main Parameters

We considered a buyback contract between a single green product manufacturer and a single retailer. The manufacturer decides the green level of the product (denoted as k), and the retailer decides how much to order (denoted as q). Both the manufacturer and the retailer are risk-neutral.
The retail price is denoted as p. The manufacturer’s production cost per unit is denoted as c s and the retailer’s sales cost per unit is c r ; c m + c r < p . The retailer’s marginal cost is incurred upon procuring a unit (rather than upon selling a unit). For notational convenience, we let c = c m + c r . The retailer earns v < c per unit unsold at the end of the sales period, where v is the salvage value of the unit. We considered a buyback contract between the manufacturer and the retailer. With a buyback contract, the manufacturer charges the retailer w per unit purchased, but pays the retailer b per unit remaining at the end of the season.
We assumed that the normal product demand y is random. We let F be the distribution function of demand, and f its density function: F is strictly increasing and differentiable, where F ( 0 ) = 0 , F ( y ) > 0 , f ( y ) > 0 , F ¯ ( y ) = 1 F ( y ) .
Due to the popularization of environmental education in recent years, people increasingly like green products. The product’s green level k can be measured by carbon emission, and normalized to 1 in the case of normal products that do not adopt any emission reduction measure during production and transportation. Then, any emission reduction measure will advance the product’s green level, i.e., k 1 , so as to increase product demand; therefore, we assumed that the demand for the green product (denoted as y ) increases at the green level of the product (denoted as k), i.e., y = k y , where k 1 , and that, when k = 1 , the product is the normal product, and its demand is y.
The R & D cost of the green product manufacturer is convex increasing in product green level k, i.e., m ( k ) = 1 2 h ( k 1 ) 2 , where h is the R&D cost coefficient. The manufacturer has a free carbon credit, denoted as E. The actual carbon emission decrease is the product green level, i.e., e ( k 1 ) a , where e is the normal product carbon emissions ( k = 1 ) and a is denoted as the emission reduction efficiency coefficient. Then, E [ e ( k 1 ) a ] is the trading carbon emission of the manufacturer, and the unit trading price is denoted as p t .
All of the parameters can be found in Table 1.
We assumed p > w + c r , to ensure profitability for the retailer, and w > c m , to ensure profitability for the manufacturer.
In the green supply chain system, manufacturers of green products are subject to government-regulated carbon emission quotas. Initially, companies are allocated a certain amount of carbon emissions for free by the government. Any excess can be purchased on the market. If a company reduces its carbon emissions by improving its production technology, and saves its carbon quota, it can sell the surplus quota on the carbon trading market, and earn revenue.

3.2. Centralized Decision Model

Considering the situation of carbon emissions and carbon trading quotas, the overall supply chain profit can be represented as π c ( q , k ) ; then,
π c = p S ( q , k ) + v I ( q , k ) ( c r + c m ) q 1 2 h ( k 1 ) 2 + p t [ E ( e ( k 1 ) a ) ] .
where S ( q , k ) represents the expected sales volume. Referring to [29], coupled with the green level of the product k, we obtain S ( q , k ) = m i n ( q , y ) = m i n ( q , k y ) = q k 0 q k F ( y ) d y . The expected inventory volume is represented by I ( q , k ) : that is, where I ( q , k ) = m a x ( q k y , 0 ) , it can be derived that I ( q , k ) = q S ( q , k ) .
The R&D cost of green product manufacturers is represented by 1 2 h ( k 1 ) 2 , and p t [ E ( e ( k 1 ) a ) ] represents the income or expenditure of carbon trading. We denoted A = E e as the normal product carbon emission trading. As the free carbon credit E is set for the carbon emission reduction, and the carbon emission of the normal product e should be less than E, so we assumed that A < 0 . Therefore, Equation (1) can be simplified as
π c = ( p v ) S ( q , k ) ( c v ) q 1 2 h ( k 1 ) 2 + p t [ A + ( k 1 ) a ] .
Considering the situation of carbon emissions and carbon trading quotas, the order quantity q and the product green level k were determined to maximize the supply chain profit. We obtained the following proposition (The proof is in the Appendix A).
Proposition 1.
Under the centralized decision scenario, the optimal product green level is
k 0 = ( p v ) h 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y + p t a h + 1 ,
and the optimal order quantity is
q 0 = F 1 p c p v ( p v ) h 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y + p t a h + 1 .
Under government-regulated carbon quotas, and with increasing consumer awareness of environmental protection, companies can improve the overall profitability of their supply chain, by making centralized decisions, to enhance the eco-friendliness of their products. The product green level and the order quantity are jointly concave. We found that the optimal product green level and the optimal order quantity are affected by the other parameters, such as retail price, salvage value, R&D cost coefficient, etc. Then, we conducted a sensitivity analysis, and obtained the following proposition.
Proposition 2.
Both k 0 and q 0 increase in p t , a, v and p, but decrease in h and c.
As retail price p or salvage value v increases, the goods are more profitable from sales, or lose less from salvage, so both the optimal product green level and the optimal order quantity should be increased, to advance the probability of goods sales (see Figure 1c,d); however, as the total unit cost c decreases, the profitability of goods is decreased, such that both the optimal product green level and the optimal order quantity should be decreased, to avoid the loss from salvage (see Figure 1f). As emission reduction efficiency coefficient a or carbon trading price p t increases, the product green level can be increased, to improve the supply chain’s revenue; however, as the R&D cost coefficient of product green level h increases, the product green level should be decreased, to reduce the supply chain’s cost. As the optimal order quantity increases in the optimal product green level, then the optimal order quantity increases in emission reduction efficiency coefficient a or carbon trading price p t (see Figure 1a,b), but decreases in the R&D cost coefficient of the product green level (see Figure 1e).

3.3. Decentralized Decision Model under the Buyback Contract

Under a buyback contract with the green product R & D cost-sharing, the retailer helps the green product manufacturer bear part of the research and development costs at a ratio of 1 θ , while the green product manufacturer bears a proportion of θ . The manufacturer and retailer reach an agreement in advance that the retailer can obtain products from the manufacturer at a wholesale price w. At the end of the sales period, the manufacturer will compensate for unsold products at a repurchase price b. However, as transportation of remaining products also incurs costs, these products will not be shipped back to the manufacturer, and their residual value still belongs to the retailer. In the green supply chain buyback model, the expected profit functions for retailers and green product manufacturers are π r and π m , respectively:
π r = ( p v b ) S ( q , k ) + ( v c r w + b ) q 1 2 h ( 1 θ ) ( k 1 ) 2 ;
π m = b S ( q , k ) + ( w c m b ) q 1 2 h θ ( k 1 ) 2 + p t [ A + ( k 1 ) a ] .
Proposition 3.
Under the decentralized decision scenario, there is an equilibrium between the manufacturer and the retailer; the equilibrium green level of products is
k = b θ h 0 F 1 p c r w p v b p c r w p v b F ( y ) d y + p t a θ h + 1 ,
and the equilibrium order quantity is
q = F 1 p c r w p v b k .
Under the decentralized decision scenario, the manufacturer and the retailer make their own decisions in relation to the green level of products and product order quantity. We obtain a unique equilibrium, in which both the green level of products and the order quantity are affected by other parameters, such as retail price, salvage value, R & D cost coefficient, etc. Then, we conduct a sensitivity analysis under the decentralized decision scenario, and obtain the following proposition.
Proposition 4.
Both k and q increase in p t , a, v, b and p, but decrease in h, θ and c r .
Under the decentralized decision scenario, in equilibrium, as retail price p or salvage value v increases, the goods are more profitable from sales, or lose less from salvage, so both the equilibrium product green level and the equilibrium order quantity should be increased, to advance the probability of goods sales. However, as the unit marginal cost c r increases, the profitability of goods is decreased, such that both the equilibrium product green level and the equilibrium order quantity should be decreased, to avoid the loss from salvage. As emission reduction efficiency coefficient a or carbon trading price p t increases, the product green level can be increased, to improve the product’s revenue, so as to increase the product’s profit. However, as the R & D cost coefficient of product green level h increases, the product green level should be decreased to reduce the supply chain’s cost. As the product’s proportion of the R & D cost increases, a lower equilibrium product green level should be set, to retain its profit. As the equilibrium order quantity increases in the equilibrium product green level, then the equilibrium order quantity increases in emission reduction efficiency coefficient a or carbon trading price p t , but decreases in the R & D cost coefficient of product green level and the product’s proportion of the R & D cost.

4. Coordination under the Buyback Contract

In the centralized system, the supplier and the retailer are considered as a whole part, and maximize the channel profit by deciding q and k, which are the global optimal decisions for the supply chain. However, in the decentralized system, the supplier and the retailer maximize their own profit such that the optimal decision q and k are local optimal, not global optimal. Consequently, the local optimal profit is lower than or equal to the global optimal profit. With the coordination mechanism in this part, the local optimal profit equals the global optimal profit.
In research on coordinating supply chain systems through the buyback contract, many studies have found that in the real world, the buyback contract can indeed help participants at all levels of the supply chain to effectively enhance their optimal interests. The buyback contract has gradually become one of the measures by which suppliers and retailers can expand sales volume: on the one hand, it promotes further cooperation between the manufacturer and the retailer, and encourages both parties to make decisions from the perspective of maximizing the benefits of the supply chain system; on the other hand, it is conducive to increasing the benefits of the green product retailer and manufacturer, and to improving system performance [31].
When the retailer’s order quantity decision is the same as the previous centralized decision, and the manufacturer’s product eco-friendliness is the same as the centralized decision, the green supply chain reaches coordination, and should satisfy the conditions: q = q 0 , k = k 0 .
Proposition 5.
For a contract combining buybacks and research and development cost-sharing to achieve perfect coordination of the system, the following parameters must meet the conditions:
w = ( p c ) θ + ( c v ) ( p c ) p t a ( 1 θ ) ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y ;
b = θ ( p v ) ( 1 θ ) p t a 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y .
Under the contract, the manufacturer and the retailer share the risk of demand uncertainty by the cost share of the R & D and buyback behavior from the manufacturer to the retailer. Specifically, the retailer bears 1 θ of the manufacturer’s research and development costs, the manufacturer compensates the retailer for unsold products at a repurchase price b at the end of the sales period, and the supply chain is coordinated. The wholesale price and buyback price are both affected by other parameters, such as retail price, salvage value, etc. Next, we conducted a sensitivity analysis, and obtained the following proposition.
Proposition 6.
When the supply chain is coordinated, w increases in θ, but decreases in p t and a; b increases in θ, but decreases in p t and a.
As emission reduction efficiency coefficient a or carbon trading price p t increases, the product green level can be increased to improve the product’s revenue, so as to increase the product’s profit. As the equilibrium order quantity increases in the equilibrium product green level, then the equilibrium order quantity and channel optimal order quantity increases in emission reduction efficiency coefficient a or carbon trading price p t . However, due to the R & D cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer, the equilibrium order quantity increases more, such that the buyback price needs to be reduced, to slow the equilibrium order quantity increment range, so as to remain consistent with the optimal order quantity. As the manufacturer’s proposition of the R & D cost θ increases, the equilibrium order quantity’s increment is close to the channel optimal order quantity’s increment, such that the motivation of the buyback price decrement is diminished. As the wholesale price increases in the buyback price, then the wholesale price increases in the manufacturer’s proposition of the R & D cost (see Figure 2c), but decreases in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient or carbon trading price (see Figure 2a,b).
With the wholesale price and buyback price, the supply chain can be coordinated, and the supply chain profit can be maximized. Due to the R & D cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer, θ can be used to distribute the total optimal supply chain to the manufacturer and the retailer.
In decentralized decision-making, the green product manufacturer decides the optimal product green level k, and the retailer decides the optimal order quantity q on this basis. When the supply chain is coordinated, due to the R & D cost sharing between the manufacturer and the retailer, θ can be used to distribute the total optimal supply chain between the manufacturer and the retailer. As θ increases, the changes in profits of all parties are shown in Figure 3. Under the buyback and R & D cost-sharing contract, when θ = 25 % , the retailer’s profit is 50,150; the green manufacturer’s profit is 16,697 when the supply chain is coordinated, and the channel profit is 66,848. As θ increases, the retailer profit decreases but the manufacturer increases, and the channel profit is unchanged. Therefore, the R & D cost sharing, θ , can be used to distribute the optimal channel supply chain between the manufacturer and the retailer.

5. Sensitivity Analysis on the Optimal Channel Profit

With the channel optimal product green level and the channel optimal order quantity, the optimal channel profit is
π c = ( p v ) S ( q 0 , k ) ( c v ) q 0 1 2 h ( k 0 1 ) 2 + p t [ A + ( k 0 1 ) a ] = ( M + p t a ) 2 2 h + ( M + p t A ) ,
where M = ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y .
Next, we analyzed the impacts of parameters on the optimal channel profit, and obtained the following proposition.
Proposition 7.
The channel profit π c increases in a, p, v and A, but decreases in c and h.
As retail price p or salvage value v increases, the goods are more profitable from sales, or lose less from salvage, so the channel profit is increased (see Figure 4c,d). However, as the total unit cost c or R & D cost coefficient h decreases, the profitability of goods is decreased, such that the channel profit is decreased (see Figure 4e,f). As the normal product carbon emission trading A or emission reduction efficiency coefficient a increases, the manufacturer can obtain more profit from the product carbon emission trading, such that the channel profit is increased (see Figure 4a,b).
The increment of p t always leads to the increment of the optimal product green level k 0 and the optimal order quantity q 0 . If the carbon trading price p t is low ( p t < p ¯ t ), the manufacturer will set a low product green level, and the product carbon emission trading is a cost for the supply chain ( p t [ A + ( k 0 1 ) a ] < 0 ). The increment of p t leads to a higher cost, such that the channel profit π c is decreased; however, if the carbon trading price p t is high ( p t > p ¯ t ), the manufacturer will set a high product green level, and the product carbon emission trading is a revenue for the supply chain ( p t [ A + ( k 0 1 ) a ] > 0 ). The increment of p t leads to a higher revenue, such that the channel profit π c is increased (see Figure 5).
Proposition 8.
The channel profit π c decreases in p t when p t < p ¯ t , but increases in p t when p t > p ¯ t , where p ¯ t = ( h A + M a ) / a 2 .
Whether the product carbon emission trading is a revenue or a cost for the green supply chain depends on the threshold of the carbon trading price p ¯ t . We then analyzed the impact of the parameters on the threshold of the carbon trading price p ¯ t , and obtained the following proposition.
Proposition 9.
The threshold p ¯ t decreases in A, p and v, but increases in c and h. when a < h A / M , the threshold p ¯ t decreases in a; when a > h A / M , p ¯ t is negative, and p t > p ¯ t always holds.
Whether the product carbon emission trading is a revenue or a cost for the green supply chain depends on the threshold of the carbon trading price p ¯ t . Consequently, when p ¯ t increases, it is more probable that p t < p ¯ t , and the product carbon emission trading will be a cost for the supply chain; when p ¯ t decreases, it is more probable that p t > p ¯ t , and the product carbon emission trading will be a revenue for the supply chain.
The increment of the retail price p or salvage value v leads to a higher product green level k 0 , so it is more probable that carbon emission trading will be a revenue; however, the increment of the total unit cost c leads to a lower product green level k 0 , so it is more probable that carbon emission trading will be a cost.
The increment of the R & D cost h always leads to a higher product green level k 0 , so it is more probable that carbon emission trading will be a revenue. As the normal product carbon emission trading A increases, the product green level remains unchanged, but it is more probable that the product carbon emission trading will be a revenue ( p t [ A + ( k 0 1 ) a ] > 0 ) for the supply chain, such that p ¯ t decreases.
When the emission reduction efficiency coefficient a is low ( a < h A / M ), k 0 is low, such that the product carbon emission trading is a cost for the supply chain; therefore, the increment of a leads to the increment of k 0 , such that the product carbon emission trading becomes the revenue for the supply chain, and it is more possible that p t > p ¯ t . When the emission reduction efficiency coefficient a is high enough ( a > h A / M ), k 0 is high, such that the product carbon emission trading is a revenue for the supply chain, and p t > p ¯ t always holds.

6. Conclusions and Further Research

6.1. Conclusions

Unlike the traditional buyback contract, under the green supply chain buyback contract, both the product green level and order quantity need to be decided, and the product green level is related to the random demand. In addition, the R & D cost is shared between the manufacturer and the retailer. In order to coordinate the green supply chain, the manufacturer needs to share both the risk of goods salvage and the R & D cost.
Under the green supply chain buyback contract, we find that both the wholesale price and buyback price increase in the manufacturer’s proposition of the R & D cost, but decrease in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient or carbon trading price.
As retail price increases or as salvage value increases, the goods are more profitable from sales, or lose less from salvage, so both the optimal product green level and the optimal order quantity should be increased, to advance the probability of goods sales, such that the channel profit is increased. However, as the total unit cost increases, the profitability of goods is decreased, such that both the optimal product green level and the optimal order quantity should be decreased, to avoid loss from salvage, such that the channel profit is decreased.
As the emission reduction efficiency coefficient increases, the product green level can be increased, to improve the supply chain’s revenue, so as to increase the supply chain profit; however, as the R & D cost coefficient of the product green level increases, the product green level should be decreased, to reduce the supply chain’s cost. As the optimal order quantity increases in the optimal product green level, then the optimal order quantity increases in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient, but decreases in the R & D cost coefficient of the product green level. The channel profit increases in the emission reduction efficiency coefficient, but decreases in the R & D cost coefficient of the product green level.
As the carbon trading price increases, the product green level can be increased, to improve the supply chain’s revenue, so as to increase the supply chain profit. As the optimal order quantity increases in the optimal product green level, then the optimal order quantity increases in the carbon trading price. If the carbon trading price is low, the manufacturer will set a low product green level, and the product carbon emission trading will be a cost for the supply chain. The increment of the carbon trading price leads to a higher cost, such that the channel profit is decreased; however, if the carbon trading price is high, the manufacturer will set a high product green level, and the product carbon emission trading will be a revenue for the supply chain. The increment of the carbon trading price leads to a higher revenue, such that the channel profit is increased.

6.2. Further Research

For the convenience of research and modeling, this paper simplified the actual situation of the supply chain. This has resulted in a certain degree of deviation between the research results and the actual situation. The main shortcomings are as follows. The relationship between members of the supply chain is complex and changeable, so it is not appropriate to discuss them together: on the one hand, there is not much attention paid to the quantitative relationship between buyers and suppliers; on the other hand, whether there is competition or cooperation between suppliers has not been considered. In reality, game behavior often occurs under conditions where information among members of the supply chain is not equal, and decision-making is not completely rational. This study assumes that product greenness and consumer purchase preferences are not completely positively correlated: that is, consumers do not completely pursue green consumption.
Under the current premise of carbon emissions, the exploration of green supply chain repurchase contracts can be extended to the following areas.
Firstly, green supply chain coordination can also be studied in multiple suppliers and multiple stages of products. At present, most repurchase contract explorations are basically focused on the coordination between a single cycle, a single product and a single retailer. However, in practice, the structure of the supply chain involved in practical life is much more complicated than in theory; therefore, it would be possible to consider further expanding the exploration of repurchase contracts involved in green supply chains to one-to-many or many-to-one modes between supply chains and retailers. The exploration could even be further expanded to multi-cycle, multi-level and multi-product type supply chain network structures.
Secondly, during the period when productivity constraints arise in green supply chains. At present, the exploration of green supply chain repurchase contracts is based on the assumption that the production and supply capacity of manufacturers or suppliers is infinite. There is scant related literature that considers situations where the production capacity of manufacturers is limited; however, in practice, most enterprises have significant constraints on their production capacity; therefore, in actual operation, how to reasonably arrange the production capacity of suppliers or manufacturers, so as to effectively improve their own resource utilization rate, has become a major concern for most enterprises.
The issue of information asymmetry in green supply chains is also a difficult problem that we need to carefully consider. In cooperation, due to asymmetric information, coordination mechanisms may not be able to enable both supply and demand sides to make global optimal decisions, resulting in the reduction of supply chain profit; therefore, in future, some treaties and parameters could be set to associate with some effective information. Of course, the ultimate goal is to make the upstream and downstream information of the green supply chain fully flow, and to further improve the overall collaborative efficiency.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, X.L. and G.Z.; methodology, X.L.; software, G.Z.; validation, X.L. and G.Z.; formal analysis, X.L. and G.Z.; investigation, X.L. and G.Z.; resources, X.L.; data curation, G.Z.; writing—original draft preparation, X.L. and G.Z.; writing—review and editing, X.L. and G.Z.; visualization, G.Z.; supervision, X.L.; project administration, X.L. and G.Z.; funding acquisition, X.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by Macau University of Science and Technology Faculty Research Grants through FRG-22-057-MSB.

Data Availability Statement

The data used to support the findings of this study are included within the article.

Acknowledgments

This research was funded by Macau University of Science and Technology Faculty Research Grants through FRG-22-057-MSB.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Proof of Proposition 1.
According to Equation (2), for the overall supply chain profit function π c , find the first and second derivatives of order quantities q and greenness k:
π c q = ( p v ) S ( q , k ) q ( c v ) ;
π c k = ( p v ) S ( q , k ) k h ( k 1 ) + p t a ;
2 π c q 2 = ( p v ) 2 S ( q , k ) q 2 ;
2 π c k 2 = ( p v ) 2 S ( q , k ) k 2 h ;
2 π c q q = ( p v ) 2 S ( q , k ) q k ;
of which,
S ( q , k ) q = 1 F ( q k ) ;
S ( q , k ) k = q k F ( q k ) 0 q k F ( y ) d y ;
f ( q q ) = 2 S ( q , k ) q 2 = 1 k f ( q k ) < 0 ;
f ( k k ) = 2 S ( q , k ) k 2 = q 2 k 3 f ( q k ) < 0 ;
f ( q k ) = f ( k q ) = 2 π c q k = q k 2 f ( q k ) > 0 ;
f ( k q ) = 2 π c q k = q k 2 f ( q k ) > 0 .
According to the above, the determinant of the Hessian matrix, with respect to q and k, can be obtained:
| H ( π c ) | = det f ( q q ) f ( q k ) f ( k q ) f ( k k ) = h k ( p v ) f ( q k ) > 0 .
Given | H ( π c ) | > 0 and 2 S ( q , k ) q 2 < 0 , then | H ( π c ) | is strictly negative definite; therefore, it can be judged that π c is a joint concave function, with respect to q and k. Q 0 represents the optimal order quantity of the supply chain system, and k 0 represents the optimal greenness of the supply chain system. Hence, there exists ( q 0 , k 0 ) , such that the overall supply chain profit is maximized.
Let Equation (5) equal to 0, and q 0 satisfies the formula:
S ( q , k ) q = 1 F ( q k ) = c v p v .
Let Equation (6) equal 0, and k 0 satisfies the formula:
0 q 0 k F q 0 k F ( y ) d y = 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y = h ( k 1 ) + P t a p v = 0 .
Proof of Proposition 2.
Taking the first-order derivatives of k 0 , with respect to p, c, v, h, a and p t , we obtain
k 0 p = 0 F 1 p c p v 1 F ( y ) d y h > 0 , k 0 c = F 1 p c p v h < 0 , k 0 v = 0 F 1 p c p v F ( y ) d y h > 0 , k 0 h = ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y + p t a h 2 < 0 , k 0 a = p t h > 0 , k 0 p t = a h > 0 .
Proof of Proposition 3.
The first and second derivatives of Equation (5), with respect to q, are
π r q = ( p v b ) S ( q , k ) q c r + v w + b ,
2 π r q 2 = ( p v b ) 2 S ( q , k ) q 2 ,
where § ( q , k ) q = 1 f ( q k ) , and 2 π r q 2 = 1 k f ( q k ) . It can be derived that 2 π r q 2 < 0 ; therefore, there exists a unique optimal solution q within the range of q ( 0 , ) that maximizes π r .
By setting Equation (A14) equal to 0, it can be determined that under the conditions of a cost-sharing contract for buybacks and research and development, the retailer’s optimal order quantity q satisfies
S ( q , k ) q = c r + w b v p v b .
The first and second derivatives of Equation (6), with respect to k, are
π m k = b S ( q , k ) k θ h ( k 1 ) + p t a ,
2 π m k 2 = b 2 S ( q , k ) k 2 θ h .
where S ( q , k ) k = q k F ( q k ) 0 q k F ( y ) d y , and 2 π r k 2 = q 2 k 3 f ( q k ) . It can be derived that 2 π m k 2 < 0 ; therefore, there exists a unique optimal solution q within the range of q ( 0 , ) that maximizes π m .
By setting Equation (A17) equal to 0, it can be determined that under the conditions of a cost-sharing contract for buybacks and research and development, the manufacturer’s optimal product eco-friendliness k satisfies the formula
S ( q , k ) k = θ h ( k 1 ) p t a b .
Thus, we obtain the result. □
Proof of Proposition 4.
The proof of Proposition 4 is similar to the proof of Proposition 2. □
Proof of Proposition 5.
When the retailer’s order quantity decision is the same as the previous centralized decision, and when the manufacturer’s product eco-friendliness is the same as the centralized decision, the green supply chain reaches coordination, and should satisfy the conditions q = q 0 , k = k 0 . Coupled with Equation (3), we obtain
b = θ h ( k 0 1 ) p t a h ( k 0 1 ) p t a ( p v ) = θ ( p v ) ( 1 θ ) p t a 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y ,
w = ( c v ) ( p v b ) ( p v ) + v + b c r = ( p c ) θ + ( c v ) ( p c ) p t a ( 1 θ ) ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y .
Proof of Proposition 6.
Based on Proposition 5, taking the first-order derivatives of w and b, with respect to p t , a and θ , we obtain
w p t = ( p c ) a ( 1 θ ) ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y < 0 , w a = ( p c ) p t ( 1 θ ) ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y < 0 , w θ = ( p c ) + ( p c ) p t a ( p v ) 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y > 0 , b p t = ( 1 θ ) a 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y < 0 , b a = ( 1 θ ) p t 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y < 0 , b θ = ( p v ) + p t a 0 F 1 p c p v p c p v F ( y ) d y > 0 .
Proof of Proposition 7.
Taking the first-order derivatives of π c , with respect to a, h, A, M, we obtain
π c a = ( M + p t a ) p t h > 0 , π c h = p t > 0 , π c A = ( M + p t a ) 2 h 2 < 0 , π c M = ( M + p t a ) h + 1 > 0 .
Taking the first-order derivative of M, with respect to p, c and v, we obtain
M p = 0 F 1 p c p v 1 F ( y ) d y > 0 , M c = F 1 p c p v < 0 , M v = 0 F 1 p c p v F ( y ) d y > 0 .
Thus, we obtain the results. □
Proof of Proposition 8.
Taking the first-order and second-order derivatives of π c , with respect to p t , we obtain
π c p t = ( M + p t a ) a + h A h , 2 π c ( p t ) 2 = a 2 h > 0 .
Then, the channel profit π c decreases in p t when p t < ( h A + M a ) / a 2 , but increases in p t when p t > ( h A + M a ) / a 2 . Let p ¯ t = ( h A + M a ) / a 2 . □
Proof of Proposition 9.
Taking the first-order derivatives of p ¯ t , with respect to h, A, M, we obtain
p ¯ t h = A / a 2 > 0 , p ¯ t A = h / a 2 < 0 , p ¯ t M = 1 / a < 0 .
Taking the first-order derivative of M, with respect to p, c and v, we obtain
M p = 0 F 1 p c p v 1 F ( y ) d y > 0 , M c = F 1 p c p v < 0 , M v = 0 F 1 p c p v F ( y ) d y > 0 .
Thus, we obtain the results.
Taking the first-order derivative of p ¯ t , with respect to a, we obtain
p ¯ t a = 2 h A + M a a 3 .
If 2 h A + M a > 0 , p ¯ t a > 0 , while if 2 h A + M a < 0 , p ¯ t a < 0 .
When a > h A / M , p ¯ t is negative, such that p t > p ¯ t always holds. When a h A / M , 2 h A + M a < 0 always holds, such that p ¯ t a < 0 . Thus, we obtain the results. □

References

  1. Fu, L.; Hao, J.; He, D.; He, K.; Li, P. Assessment of vehicular pollution in China. J. Air Waste Manag. Assoc. 2001, 51, 658–668. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  2. Amato, F.; Karanasiou, A.; Moreno, T.; Alastuey, A.; Orza, J.; Lumbreras, J.; Borge, R.; Boldo, E.; Linares, C.; Querol, X. Emission factors from road dust resuspension in a Mediterranean freeway. Atmos. Environ. 2012, 61, 580–587. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Verschoor, A. Towards a Definition of Microplastics Considerations for the Specification of Physico-Chemical Properties (No. 2015-116); RIVM Letter Report; RIVM: Bilthoven, The Netherlands, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  4. Gent, A.N.; Walter, J.D. Pneumatic Tire; The University Of Akron: Akron, OH, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  5. Grigoratos, T.; Martini, G. Brake wear particle emissions: A review. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2015, 22, 2491–2504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Luo, Z.; Zhou, X.; Su, Y.; Wang, H.; Yu, R.; Zhou, S.; Xu, E.G.; Xing, B. Environmental occurrence, fate, impact, and potential solution of tire microplastics: Similarities and differences with tire wear particles. Sci. Total Environ. 2021, 795, 148902. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  7. Ma, H.; Pu, S.; Liu, S.; Bai, Y.; Mandal, S.; Xing, B. Microplastics in aquatic environments: Toxicity to trigger ecological consequences. Environ. Pollut. 2020, 261, 114089. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ng, E.; Lwanga, E.H.; Eldridge, S.M.; Johnston, P.; Hu, H.; Geissen, V.; Chen, D. An overview of microplastic and nanoplastic pollution in agroecosystems. Sci. Total Environ. 2018, 627, 1377–1388. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Sommer, F.; Dietze, V.; Baum, A.; Sauer, J.; Gilge, S.; Maschowski, C.; Gieré, R. Tire abrasion as a major source of microplastics in the environment. Aerosol Air Qual. Res. 2018, 18, 2014–2028. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Verschoor, A.; De Poorter, L.; Dröge, R.; Kuenen, J.; de Valk, E. Emission of Microplastics and Potential Mitigation Measures: Abrasive Cleaning Agents, Paints and Tyre Wear; National Institute for Public Health and the Environment: Catharijnesingel, The Netherlands, 2016.
  11. Cadle, S.; Williams, R. Gas and particle emissions from automobile tires in laboratory and field studies. Rubber Chem. Technol. 1979, 52, 146–158. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Magnusson, K.; Eliaeson, K.; Fråne, A.; Haikonen, K.; Olshammar, M.; Stadmark, J.; Hultén, J. Swedish Sources and Pathways for Microplastics to the Marine Environment; IVL Svenska Miljöinstitutet: Stockholm, Sweden, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  13. Kreider, M.L.; Panko, J.M.; McAtee, B.L.; Sweet, L.I.; Finley, B.L. Physical and chemical characterization of tire-related particles: Comparison of particles generated using different methodologies. Sci. Total Environ. 2010, 408, 652–659. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Lassen, C.; Hansen, S.F.; Magnusson, K.; Norén, F.; Hartmann, N.I.B.; Jensen, P.R.; Nielsen, T.G.; Brinch, A. Occurrence, Effects and Sources of Releases to the Environment in Denmark; The Danish Environmental Protection Agency: Copenhagen, Denmark, 2012.
  15. Wagner, S.; Hüffer, T.; Klöckner, P.; Wehrhahn, M.; Hofmann, T.; Reemtsma, T. Tire wear particles in the aquatic environment—A review on generation, analysis, occurrence, fate and effects. Water Res. 2018, 139, 83–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Kole, P.J.; Löhr, A.J.; Van Belleghem, F.G.; Ragas, A.M. Wear and tear of tyres: A stealthy source of microplastics in the environment. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2017, 14, 1265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  17. Marwood, C.; McAtee, B.; Kreider, M.; Ogle, R.S.; Finley, B.; Sweet, L.; Panko, J. Acute aquatic toxicity of tire and road wear particles to alga, daphnid, and fish. Ecotoxicology 2011, 20, 2079. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  18. Bejgarn, S.; MacLeod, M.; Bogdal, C.; Breitholtz, M. Toxicity of leachate from weathering plastics: An exploratory screening study with Nitocra spinipes. Chemosphere 2015, 132, 114–119. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  19. Wik, A.; Dave, G. Acute toxicity of leachates of tire wear material to Daphnia magna—Variability and toxic components. Chemosphere 2006, 64, 1777–1784. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  20. WHO. Global Status Report on Road Safety 2015; World Health Organization: Geneva, Switzerland, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  21. Haq, M.T.; Zlatkovic, M.; Ksaibati, K. Assessment of tire failure related crashes and injury severity on a mountainous freeway: Bayesian binary logit approach. Accid. Anal. Prev. 2020, 145, 105693. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  22. Das, S.; Dutta, A.; Geedipally, S.R. Applying Bayesian data mining to measure the effect of vehicular defects on crash severity. J. Transp. Saf. Secur. 2021, 13, 605–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Hanoteau, J. Competitiveness through political environmental strategies: The case of Michelin’s green tires. Glob. Bus. Organ. Excell. 2009, 29, 32–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Berge, T.; Sandberg, U. Five years of EU tyre labelling-Success or failure? In INTER-NOISE and NOISE-CON Congress and Conference Proceedings; Institute of Noise Control Engineering: Reston, VA, USA, 2017; Volume 255, pp. 876–887. [Google Scholar]
  25. Vanclay, J.K.; Shortiss, J.; Aulsebrook, S.; Gillespie, A.M.; Howell, B.C.; Johanni, R.; Maher, M.J.; Mitchell, K.M.; Stewart, M.D.; Yates, J. Customer response to carbon labelling of groceries. J. Consum. Policy 2011, 34, 153–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Bowen, F.E.; Cousins, P.D.; Lamming, R.C.; Farukt, A.C. The role of supply management capabilities in green supply. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2001, 10, 174–189. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Mentzer, J.T.; DeWitt, W.; Keebler, J.S.; Min, S.; Nix, N.W.; Smith, C.D.; Zacharia, Z.G. Defining supply chain management. J. Bus. Logist. 2001, 22, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Emmons, H.; Gilbert, S.M. The role of returns policies in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods. JOT-J. Oberflachentech. 1997, 37, 276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Cachon, G.P. Supply chain coordination with contracts. Handb. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2003, 11, 227–339. [Google Scholar]
  30. Sun, X.Y.; Qi, J. Study on the Coordination of Supply Chain with Supplier’s Sales Effort. Sci. Technol. Manag. Res. 2012, 32, 231–236. [Google Scholar]
  31. Taylor, T.A. Supply chain coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effects. Manag. Sci. 2002, 48, 992–1007. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Xu, S.; Tang, H.; Lin, Z.; Lu, J. Pricing and sales-effort analysis of dual-channel supply chain with channel preference, cross-channel return and free riding behavior based on revenue-sharing contract. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2022, 249, 108506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Giri, B.; Roy, B. Dual-channel competition: The impact of pricing strategies, sales effort and market share. Int. J. Manag. Sci. Eng. Manag. 2016, 11, 203–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Wang, D.P.; Li, X.Y.; Zhang, B.Q. Study on the Coordination of Supply Chain Based on Carbon Emissions Trading Considering the Manufacturers’ Competition. Oper. Res. Manag. Sci. 2018, 27, 1007–3221. [Google Scholar]
  35. Liu, M.W.; Wu, K.L.; Fu, H.; Xu, M.W. Cooperation on Carbon Emission Reduction in a Retailer-led Supply Chain with Consumer’s Low-carbon Performance. Syst. Eng.–Theory Pract. 2017, 31, 3109–3117. [Google Scholar]
  36. Yang, A.F.; Wang, J.Q.; Hu, X.J. Study on the Third-party Remanufacturing Problem under Carbon Tax Mechanism. Ruan Ke Xue 2017, 31, 13–139. [Google Scholar]
  37. Chen, X.; Benjaafar, S.; Elomri, A. The carbon-constrained EOQ. Oper. Res. Lett. 2013, 41, 172–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Li, Y.; Zhao, D.Z. Low-Carbonization Supply Chain Coordination with Contracts Considering Fairness Preference. J. Ind. Eng. Eng. Manag. 2015, 29, 156–161. [Google Scholar]
  39. Fan, T.J.; Yang, J.; Luo, R.L. Production and Inventory Based on Carbon Emission Trading Mechanism and Investment of Emission Reducing Technology. J. Beijing Inst. Technol. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2012, 14, 14–21. [Google Scholar]
  40. Kouvelis, P.; Zhao, W. The newsvendor problem and price-only contract when bankruptcy costs exist. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2011, 20, 921–936. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Cao, Y.; Liu, Z.H. A feasibility analysis for practicing green supply chain management without government policy incentives. J. Ind. Eng. Eng. Manag. 2017, 31, 119–127. [Google Scholar]
  42. Dubey, R.; Bag, S.; Ali, S.S. Green supply chain practices and its impact on organisational performance: An insight from Indian rubber industry. Int. J. Logist. Syst. Manag. 2014, 19, 20–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Zhang, L.H.; Song, X.B.; Zhang, G.W.; Lin, G.L. Adoption and coordination of carbon reduction technology in supply chain based on carbon tax. Comput. Integr. Manuf. Syst. 2017, 23, 883–891. [Google Scholar]
  44. Zhou, Y.J.; Bao, M.J.; Chen, X.H.; Xu, X.H. Co-op Advertising and Emission Reduction Cost Sharing Contract and Coordination in Low-carbon Supply Chain Based on Fairness Concerns. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2017, 25, 121–129. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. He, L.H.; Liao, Q.; Liu, M.M.; Yuan, C. A Game Analysis of Optimal Advertising Efforts and Direct Price Discount Strategy for the Two-level Supply Chain. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2017, 25, 130–138. [Google Scholar]
  46. Wang, D.P.; Li, X.Y.; Zhao, L. Study on the Decision of Supply Chain Based on Information Asymmetry Considering the Retailers’ Competition on Promotion Effort. Ind. Eng. Manag. 2017, 22, 27–35. [Google Scholar]
  47. Zhao, N.; Lian, Z. A queueing-inventory system with two classes of customers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2011, 129, 225–231. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Shi, P.; Yan, B.; Shi, S. Pricing and Product Green Degree Decisions in Green Supply Chain with Fairness Concerns. Syst. Eng.–Theory Pract. 2016, 36, 1937–1950. [Google Scholar]
  49. Bag, S.; Anand, N.; Pandey, K.K. Green supply chain management model for sustainable manufacturing practices. In Green Supply Chain Management for Sustainable Business Practice; IGI Global: Hershey, PA, USA, 2017; pp. 153–189. [Google Scholar]
  50. Qu, Y.; Guan, Z.M.; Ye, T.; Tao, J. Supply Chain Coordination for Green Innovation-advertisement Decisions Based on Mixture CVaR Criterion. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2018, 36, 89–101. [Google Scholar]
  51. Shen, B.; Zhu, C.; Li, Q.; Wang, X. Green technology adoption in textiles and apparel supply chains with environmental taxes. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2021, 59, 4157–4174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Corboș, R.A.; Bunea, O.I.; Jiroveanu, D.C. The Effects of Strategic Procurement 4.0 Performance on Organizational Competitiveness in the Circular Economy. Logistics 2023, 7, 13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. The impacts of p t , a, v, p, h and c on k 0 and q 0 : (a) the impact of p t ( p = 100 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (b) the impact of a ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , h = 100 ); (c) the impact of v ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (d) the impact of p ( p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (e) the impact of h ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 ); (f) the impact of c ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Figure 1. The impacts of p t , a, v, p, h and c on k 0 and q 0 : (a) the impact of p t ( p = 100 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (b) the impact of a ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , h = 100 ); (c) the impact of v ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (d) the impact of p ( p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (e) the impact of h ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 ); (f) the impact of c ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Mathematics 11 02355 g001
Figure 2. The impacts of θ , p t and a on w and b: (a) the impact of p t ( p = 100 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 , θ = 0.5 ); (b) the impact of a ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , h = 100 , θ = 0.5 ); (c) the impact of θ ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Figure 2. The impacts of θ , p t and a on w and b: (a) the impact of p t ( p = 100 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 , θ = 0.5 ); (b) the impact of a ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , h = 100 , θ = 0.5 ); (c) the impact of θ ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Mathematics 11 02355 g002
Figure 3. Distributing the channel profit by θ ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c r = 10 , c m = 10 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Figure 3. Distributing the channel profit by θ ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c r = 10 , c m = 10 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Mathematics 11 02355 g003
Figure 4. The impacts of A, a, v, p, h and c on π c : (a) the impact of A ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (b) the impact of a ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , h = 100 ); (c) the impact of v ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (d) the impact of p ( p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (e) the impact of h ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 ); (f) the impact of c ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Figure 4. The impacts of A, a, v, p, h and c on π c : (a) the impact of A ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (b) the impact of a ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , h = 100 ); (c) the impact of v ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (d) the impact of p ( p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ); (e) the impact of h ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , c = 50 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 ); (f) the impact of c ( p = 100 , p t = 20 , v = 10 , e = 6 , E = 3 , a = 0.2 , h = 100 ).
Mathematics 11 02355 g004
Figure 5. The impact of p t on π c .
Figure 5. The impact of p t on π c .
Mathematics 11 02355 g005
Table 1. The basic parameters and their descriptions.
Table 1. The basic parameters and their descriptions.
ParametersDescriptions
pRetail price.
vSalvage value at the end of the sales period.
wWholesale price of unit product.
cTotal unit cost, where c = c r + c m .
c r Unit marginal cost.
c m Unit production costs of green products.
bUnit buyback price offered by the manufacturer.
yThe random demand of normal product (k = 1) with mean u.
f(y)Probability density function of y.
F(y)Cumulative distribution function of y, which is strictly increasing and differentiable, where F(0) = 0, F(y) > 0, f ( y ) > 0 , F ¯ ( y ) = 1 F ( y ) .
kProduct green level.
hR&D cost coefficient.
m ( k ) The R&D cost of the green product manufacturer, and m ( k ) = h ( k 1 ) 2 / 2 .
y The market demand of the green product ( k > 1 ), and y = k y .
EFree carbon credits allocated to the manufacturer.
eThe manufacturer’s carbon emissions at k = 1 .
aEmission reduction efficiency coefficient.
p t Carbon trading price.
qRetailers’ order quantities.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Li, X.; Zhu, G. Green Supply Chain Coordination Considering Carbon Emissions and Product Green Level Dependent Demand. Mathematics 2023, 11, 2355. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11102355

AMA Style

Li X, Zhu G. Green Supply Chain Coordination Considering Carbon Emissions and Product Green Level Dependent Demand. Mathematics. 2023; 11(10):2355. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11102355

Chicago/Turabian Style

Li, Xin, and Guanlai Zhu. 2023. "Green Supply Chain Coordination Considering Carbon Emissions and Product Green Level Dependent Demand" Mathematics 11, no. 10: 2355. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11102355

APA Style

Li, X., & Zhu, G. (2023). Green Supply Chain Coordination Considering Carbon Emissions and Product Green Level Dependent Demand. Mathematics, 11(10), 2355. https://doi.org/10.3390/math11102355

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop