4.1. Nonparametric Method of Demand Analysis
The approach to evaluation of demand and price indices, which takes into account the change of consumer preferences, is based on Pareto’s theory of demand [
44]. According to this theory, a representative economic agent chooses a consumption basket by maximizing the utility function with budget constraint. If we know the demand function, then the problem of recovering the corresponding utility function is related to the integrability problem of demand functions. This question is studied by revealed preference theory [
45]. The results of revealed preference theory allow us to test whether given trade statistics (i.e., observations of prices and consumption for a group of goods in a finite time period) is consistent with Pareto demand theory. Let us denote by
the class of non-negative on
, positive on
, continuous, concave, and positively homogeneous of degree one utility functions. Then, the criterion for trade statistics to be consistent with Pareto theory with an utility function
, which is a homothetic axiom of revealed preference [
13,
46].
We say that the trade statistics is rationalizable by a utility function
if the trade statistics is consistent with Pareto demand theory. In this case, we can construct so-called Konyus–Divisia consumption and price indexes [
2], which take into account the change of consumer’s basket structure and give generalization to well-known Laspeyres and Paasche indices with a fixed structure of the basket. Moreover, Konyus–Divisia consumption and price indices are related through Young transform [
2].
Let be an inverse demand function which describes behavior of the consumer’s group. The function reflects the relationship between consumption of products and corresponding prices. We suggest that functions are continuous on . The initial data for Konyus–Divisia indices evaluation are trade statistics which give the values of inverse demand function in a finite number of points for a considered group of products. Testing the hypothesis of rationalizability of trade statistics and the algorithm for calculating Konyus–Divizia indices are based on the following theorem.
Theorem 2 ([
13,
46])
. Given trade statistics the following statements are equivalent:- 1.
Trade statistics is rationalizable in class , i.e., there exists the utility function with property - 2.
Trade statistics satisfies Homothetic Axiom of Revealed Preference (HARP), which means that for all ordered time sub-series , the following inequality holds - 3.
The system of linear inequalitieshas a positive solution ; - 4.
The functionwhere ,
satisfy (18) rationalizes the trade statistics.
Positive solution of the system (
18) could be evaluated by Floyd–Warshall algorithm [
2,
15,
16].
Then, time series of Konyus–Divisia consumption indices are evaluated as [
2]
and time series of Konyus–Divisia price indices are evaluated as [
2]
This approach to the evaluation of consumption and price indices is called the nonparametric approach (see [
2,
47]).
In general, the conditions of rationalizability of trade statistics may be violated. The reason for this may be, for example, errors that arise by the formation of statistics time series. The issue of an indicator that measures the degree of rationalization of trade statistics was considered in [
2,
12,
47].
As a result, the generalized nonparametric method was developed [
2], which is based on the inclusion of an additional parameter
in the system (
18), which measures the level of rationalization of trade statistics. In this case, the system (
18) takes the form
The minimal value of
, which implies the consistency of the system of inequalities (
22), is called irrationality index. Positive solution of the system (
22) implies the time series of generalized Konyus–Divisia demand index (
20) and generalized Konyus–Divisia price index (
21).
4.2. Framework Concept for Analysis of Interests of Final Consumers in Network Economy
National account systems share the following main groups as part of final consumption (see quadrant II in the
Table 1): households, government, export, and gross capital formation. Note that IO statistics include the full quadrant II, i.e., it contains consumption vectors in current prices of each final consumer.
Given the initial national IO statistics for a range of years, the synthesis of the IO model with CES technologies and the generalized nonparametric approach allows us to suggest a framework for scenario analysis of the interests of groups of final consumers.
For projection of consumption vectors of different final consumers with the framework, we need to set the scenario conditions, which include the following projection data:
Price indices of primary inputs: currency exchange rate for imported intermediates and consumer price index (CPI) for gross value added;
Total final consumption values for each final consumer , where denotes the total final demand on imported products of agent .
We denote this set of scenario conditions for a projected period by .
As a result of the framework scenario evaluation, we calculate equilibrium prices of products and IO Table Z for a projected year with detailed quadrant II and additional row of final consumption of imported products, i.e., we evaluate vectors and for each final consumer . Then, the vector of total domestic final consumption for a projected year is the sum of vectors by .
In applications, we aggregate the initial IO structure to several large production complexes (up to 10). The aggregation principles are based on the analysis of economy features and depend on the objectives of the study. High-level aggregation guarantees more stable model calibration results in case of statistics errors and is useful for many tasks of macroeconomic analysis. However, the methodology can be generalized to the case of a detailed input–output balance.
The framework algorithm includes two stages.
Stage I. Identification.
Step 1. Based on studying the structure of the national production network, aggregate the initial statistics IO Tables for a given range of years to m large industrial complexes.
Step 2. Form the initial data base for model identification: aggregated annual IO Tables , , average annual price indices of primary inputs: currency exchange rate for imported products and consumer price index (CPI) for gross value added, .
Step 3. Given
fix the base year
with a given IO Table
and identify the IO balance model with CES technologies (
7) (see
Section 3.2), i.e.,
Calculate matrices
by (
11) with IO Table
,
Calibrate the model by evaluating
,
(
7) with
.
As a result, the IO model with CES technologies is ready for scenario IO Table projection given primary price indices and a vector of total final consumption for a projected year (Proposition 6).
Step 4. Given statistics of price indices of primaries
for the period
(
) we evaluate equilibrium price indices
,
for domestic products
of the network by the solution of (
14).
Step 5. For each final consumer
from the quadrant II of IO Table
(households, government, etc.), we form the annual final consumption vector
as data
.
Step 6. Denote . Given trade statistics for each final consumer , we apply the generalized non parametric method, i.e., we evaluate
- (1)
Irrationality index
and
by solving the system (
22),
- (2)
Demand function
by (
19),
- (3)
Konyus–Divisia consumption and price indices time series by (
20) and (
21) correspondingly.
Stage II. Scenario evaluation
Step 1. Set scenario conditions for a projected year.
Step 2. Evaluate equilibrium price indices for projected year
of products
by solution of (
14)).
Step 3. Given equilibrium price indices
and demand function
evaluate demand vector
of each final consumer
for the projected year by solution of the problem (
17) with budget constraint
:
If
is a solution of the problem (
23) then
We calculate the scenario projection of Konyus–Divisia consumption index as . We calculate the scenario projection of Konyus–Divisia price index as .
Step 4. Given total final consumption of each domestic product
,
(i.e., quadrant II of IO Table
Z), we evaluate the quadrants I, III of IO Table
Z for projected year by (
15).