Next Article in Journal
Multivariate Control Chart and Lee–Carter Models to Study Mortality Changes
Next Article in Special Issue
Life Insurance and Subsistence Consumption with an Exponential Utility
Previous Article in Journal
WINFRA: A Web-Based Platform for Semantic Data Retrieval and Data Analytics
Previous Article in Special Issue
DEA-BSC and Diamond Performance to Support Museum Management
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Valuation of Exchange Option with Credit Risk in a Hybrid Model

School of Liberal Arts, Seoul National University of Science and Technology, Seoul 01811, Korea
Mathematics 2020, 8(11), 2091; https://doi.org/10.3390/math8112091
Submission received: 6 November 2020 / Revised: 19 November 2020 / Accepted: 21 November 2020 / Published: 23 November 2020
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Financial Mathematics II)

Abstract

:
In this paper, the valuation of the exchange option with credit risk under a hybrid credit risk model is investigated. In order to build the hybrid model, we consider both the reduced-form model and the structural model. We adopt the probabilistic approach to derive the closed-form formula of an exchange option price with credit risk under the proposed model. Specifically, the change of measure technique is used repeatedly, and the pricing formula is provided as the standard normal cumulative distribution functions.

1. Introduction

Under the Black–Scholes model [1], Margrabe [2] first derived the closed-form pricing formula of the European exchange option which provides the option holder the right to exchange one risky asset for another. Since its introduction by Margrabe, the option has become one of the most popular exotic options in the over-the-counter (OTC) market. Thus, many researchers have studied the valuation of an exchange option with various extensions of the Black–Scholes model. Geman, Karoui, and Rochet [3] adopted the change of numeraire approach to derive the pricing formula of an exchange option. Antonelli, Ramponi, and Scarlatti [4] provided the price of the exchange option under the stochastic volatility model using a correlation expansion. Kim and Park [5] used a stochastic volatility model with fast mean reversion for a more precise price of the exchange option. In this paper, the exchange option pricing model is extended with the credit risk.
Options with credit risk have been called “vulnerable options’’ in general. For valuing the vulnerable options, most of the researchers have used one model between the reduced-form model and the structural model. The default of the firm in the reduced-form model is triggered by the counting process with some intensity. Recently, there have been various studies for vulnerable options in the reduced-form model such as the generalized jump model [6], catastrophe put option [7], and Generalized Autoregressive Conditionally Heteroscedastic (GARCH) model [8]. Because default is determined by the jump of the counting process, there is no relation between default and the firm value of the option issuer. In contrast to the reduced-form model, the structural model considers the dependence of them. Under the structural model, Johnson and Stulz [9] first provided the pricing formula of the vulnerable European option. Klein [10] extended the result of [9] by considering the correlation between the firm value process of the option issuer and the underlying asset process of the option. Based on the work of [10], there have been many extended results on vulnerable options with models such as the stochastic interest rate model [11], the early counterparty risk model [12,13], the stochastic volatility model [14,15,16,17], and the jump-diffusion model [18,19,20,21]. Furthermore, many researchers have studied vulnerable exotic options such as the American option [22], the Asian option [23], the exchange option [24], and the path-dependent option [25] under the structural model. Recently, several researchers proposed the hybrid credit risk models, incorporating the structural model and reduced-form model and provided the pricing formula of vulnerable European option [26,27]. In this paper, we deal with the option valuation based on a hybrid credit risk model. Specifically, we derive the closed-form solution for vulnerable exchange option pricing under a hybrid credit risk model.
In recent years, there have been studies on the pricing of exchange options with credit risk which is called the vulnerable exchange option. Kim and Koo [24] provided the pricing formula of an exchange option with credit risk based on the Mellin transform approach. Kim [28] used a probabilistic approach to obtain the closed-form solution of the vulnerable exchange option price under the structure model of Klein [10]. In addition, some researchers considered the generalization of the vulnerable exchange option as a power exchange option. They have developed the approaches to price the vulnerable power exchange options under the extensions of the Klein’s credit risk model, such as the jump risk [29,30], the possible default prior to the maturity [31], jumps under the double risk [32] and the intensity based approach [33]. In this sense, we also develop the pricing of exchange option with credit risk. Our main contribution is to propose a hybrid credit risk model and to provide the closed-form pricing formula of vulnerable exchange option under the proposed model based on the probabilistic approach.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, the hybrid credit model used in this paper and formulation for the exchange option with credit risk is is presented In Section 3, a closed-form formula for valuing of an exchange option with credit risk under the hybrid credit risk model is presented. In Section 4, concluding remarks are presented.

2. The Model

We assume that there is a filtered complete probability space ( Ω , F , { F t } , P ) with a filtration { F t } satisfying the usual conditions, where P is a risk-neutral probability measure. Then, under the measure P, the dynamics of two risky underlying assets S 1 ( t ) and S 2 ( t ) are given by
d S 1 ( t ) = r S 1 ( t ) d t + σ 1 S 1 ( t ) d W 1 ( t ) ,
d S 2 ( t ) = r S 2 ( t ) d t + σ 2 S 2 ( t ) d W 2 ( t ) ,
where σ i , i = 1 , 2 are the volatilities of asset i, r is a constant interest rate, W 1 ( t ) and W 2 ( t ) are the standard Brownian motions under the measure P and ρ 12 is a correlation between asset S 1 ( t ) and asset S 2 ( t ) satisfying d W 1 ( t ) d W 2 ( t ) = ρ 12 d t . We adopt the model of Klein to describe the credit risk under the structure model. Then, the asset value process V ( t ) of option issuer is governed by the geometric Brownian motions (GBM) as
d V ( t ) = r V ( t ) d t + σ 3 V ( t ) d W 3 ( t ) ,
where σ 3 is the volatility of asset V ( t ) , W 3 ( t ) is a standard Brownian motion satisfying d W 1 ( t ) d W 3 ( t ) = ρ 13 d t and d W 2 ( t ) d W 3 ( t ) = ρ 23 d t . As mentioned in [10], we assume that if a default of the option issuer happens, the option issuer’s asset is liquidated and provides only the scrap value at the maturity T. The scrap value is defined by
( 1 α ) V ( T ) D ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + ,
where α is a deadweight cost related with the default, T is a time to maturity and D is a critical value (or a value of the option issuer’s liability) that a default occurs if the value of the option issuer asset is lower than D.
We now define the default intensity process for the reduced-form model. As in Fard [6], under the risk-neutral measure P, we assume that the default intensity process is given by
d λ ( t ) = a ( b λ ( t ) ) d t + σ 4 d W 4 ( t ) ,
where σ 4 is a positive constant and W 4 ( t ) is a standard Brownian motion satisfying d W 1 ( t ) d W 4 ( t ) = ρ 14 d t , d W 2 ( t ) d W 4 ( t ) = ρ 24 d t and d W 3 ( t ) d W 4 ( t ) = ρ 34 d t . We also define the filtration F t generated by F t = F t S 1 F t S 2 F t λ H t , where F t S 1 = σ ( S 1 ( t ) , s t ) , F t S 2 = σ ( S 2 ( t ) , s t ) , F t λ = σ ( λ ( t ) , s t ) and H t = σ ( 1 { τ t } , s t ) , where τ is the default time defined by P ( τ > t ) = E e 0 t λ ( s ) d s . Then, with the underlying assets S 1 ( t ) , S 2 ( t ) and V ( t ) , the price of the exchange option C with credit risk at time 0 under the measure P is given by
C = e r T E P ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { τ > T , V ( T ) > D } + ( 1 α ) V ( T ) D ( 1 1 { τ > T , V ( T ) > D } ) | F 0 = e r T E P ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { τ > T , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 + ( 1 α ) D e r T E P V ( T ) ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + | F 0 ( 1 α ) D e r T E P V ( T ) ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { τ > T , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 .

3. Valuation of the Exchange Option with Credit Risk under the Hybrid Model

We propose a valuation of exchange option with credit risk exchange option with credit risk under the hybrid model in this section. By the law of iterated conditional expectations, the price C in the Equation (4) is given by
C = ( 1 α ) D e r T E P V ( T ) ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + | F 0 + e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { V ( T ) > D } | F 0 ( 1 α ) D e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s V ( T ) ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { V ( T ) > D } | F 0 .
In order to simplify the notations, we denote that
J 1 = ( 1 α ) D e r T E P V ( T ) ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + | F 0 , J 2 = e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { V ( T ) > D } | F 0 , J 3 = ( 1 α ) D e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s V ( T ) ( S 1 ( T ) S 2 ( T ) ) + 1 { V ( T ) > D } | F 0 .
Then, the price C can be written as
C = J 1 + J 2 J 3 .
We calculate J 1 , J 2 and J 3 in the following Lemmas, respectively.
Lemma 1.
Let us consider J 1 in the Equation (6), then J 1 is given by
J 1 = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T N ( a 1 ) ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T N ( a 2 ) ,
where
a 1 = 1 σ T ln S 1 ( 0 ) S 2 ( 0 ) + ρ 13 σ 1 σ 3 ρ 23 σ 2 σ 3 σ + σ 2 T , a 2 = 1 σ T ln S 1 ( 0 ) S 2 ( 0 ) + ρ 13 σ 1 σ 3 ρ 23 σ 2 σ 3 σ σ 2 T ,
with σ 2 = σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 2 σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 and N ( a ) = 1 2 π a e 1 2 x 2 d x .
Proof. 
We can write J 1 as
J 1 = ( 1 α ) D e r T E P V ( T ) S 1 ( T ) 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 ( 1 α ) D e r T E P V ( T ) S 2 ( T ) 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 : = I 1 I 2 .
To calculate I 1 , we define a new measure Q 1 as
d Q 1 d P = exp σ 1 W 1 ( T ) + σ 3 W 3 ( T ) 1 2 ( σ 1 2 + σ 3 2 + 2 ρ 13 σ 1 σ 3 ) T .
By Girsanov’s thoerem,
W 1 Q 1 = W 1 ( T ) σ 1 T σ 3 ρ 13 T , W 2 Q 1 = W 2 ( T ) σ 1 ρ 12 T σ 3 ρ 23 T , W 3 Q 1 = W 3 ( T ) σ 3 T σ 1 ρ 13 T
are the standard Brownian motions under the measure Q 1 . Then we have
I 1 = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T E Q 1 d P d Q 1 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T P Q 1 S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T × P Q 1 σ 2 W 2 Q 1 ( T ) σ 1 W 1 Q 1 ( T ) < ln S 1 ( 0 ) S 2 ( 0 ) + 1 2 σ 2 T + σ 1 2 T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T N ( a 1 ) .
To calculate I 2 , we define a new measure Q 2 as
d Q 2 d P = exp σ 2 W 1 ( T ) + σ 3 W 3 ( T ) 1 2 ( σ 2 2 + σ 3 2 + 2 ρ 23 σ 2 σ 3 ) T .
Since
W 1 Q 2 = W 1 ( T ) σ 2 ρ 12 T σ 3 ρ 13 T , W 2 Q 2 = W 2 ( T ) σ 2 T σ 3 ρ 23 T , W 3 Q 2 = W 3 ( T ) σ 3 T σ 2 ρ 23 T
are the standard Brownian motions under the measure Q 2 , I 2 can be calculated as
I 2 = ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T E Q 2 d P d Q 2 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 = ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T P Q 2 S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) = ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T × P Q 2 σ 2 W 2 Q 2 ( T ) σ 1 W 1 Q 2 ( T ) < ln S 1 ( 0 ) S 2 ( 0 ) 1 2 σ 2 T + σ 1 2 T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T = ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T N ( a 2 ) .
By the Equations (9) and (10), the proof of Lemma is completed.  □
Lemma 2.
Let us consider J 2 in the Equation (6), then J 2 is given by
J 2 = S 1 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( b 1 , b 2 , θ 1 ) S 2 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( b 3 , b 4 , θ 1 ) ,
where
θ 1 = ( σ 1 ρ 13 σ 2 ρ 23 ) / σ , σ 2 = σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 2 σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 , f ( s , t , u ) = 1 e u ( t s ) , M 1 ( T ) = exp b T λ ( 0 ) b a f ( 0 , T , a ) + σ 4 2 a 2 0 T f 2 ( s , T , a ) d s , b 1 = ln ( V ( 0 ) / D ) σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + r 1 2 σ 3 2 + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 3 T , b 2 = ln ( S 1 ( 0 ) / S 2 ( 0 ) ) σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + 1 2 ( σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 ) σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 T σ T , b 3 = ln ( V ( 0 ) / D ) σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + r 1 2 σ 3 2 + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T σ 3 T , b 4 = ln ( S 1 ( 0 ) / S 2 ( 0 ) ) σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + 1 2 ( σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 ) + σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 T σ T ,
and
N 2 ( n 1 , n 2 , ρ ) = 1 2 π 1 ρ 2 n 1 n 2 e 1 2 ( 1 ρ 2 ) ( x 2 2 x y ρ + y 2 ) d y d x .
Proof. 
We can write J 2 as
J 2 = e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s S 1 ( T ) 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s S 2 ( T ) 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 : = I 3 I 4 .
To calculate I 4 , we define a new measure Q 3 such that
d Q 3 d P = e 0 T λ ( s ) d s E [ e 0 T λ ( s ) d s | F 0 ] .
Then,
I 3 = e r T M 1 ( T ) E Q 3 S 1 ( t ) 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 .
Under the measure Q 3 ,
W 1 Q 3 ( T ) = W 1 ( T ) + σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s , W 2 Q 3 ( T ) = W 2 ( T ) + σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s , W 3 Q 3 ( T ) = W 3 ( T ) + σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s , W 4 Q 3 ( T ) = W 4 ( T ) + σ 4 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s
are the standard Brownian motions.
To calculate the Equation (13), we define a new measure Q ˜ 3 such that
d Q ˜ 3 d P = exp σ 1 W 1 Q 3 1 2 σ 1 2 .
Then,
I 3 = S 1 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s E Q ˜ 3 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 ,
where M 1 ( T ) = E [ e 0 T λ ( s ) d s | F 0 ] .
Since
E Q ˜ 3 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } = P Q ˜ 3 S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D = P Q ˜ 3 z 1 < b 1 , z 2 < b 2
and z 1 and z 2 are the standard normal variables, we have
I 3 = S 1 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( b 1 , b 2 , θ 1 ) ,
where θ 1 is the correlation between z 1 and z 2 .
Under the measure Q 3 , I 4 is represented by
I 4 = e r T M 1 ( T ) E Q 3 S 2 ( t ) 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 .
We define a new measure Q ^ 3 such that
d Q ^ 3 d P = exp σ 2 W 2 Q 3 1 2 σ 2 2 .
Then, by using the standard Brownian motions under the measure Q ^ 3 , we have
I 4 = S 2 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s E Q ^ 3 1 { S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D } | F 0 = S 2 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s P Q ^ 3 S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) , V ( T ) > D = S 2 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( b 3 , b 4 , θ 1 ) .
 □
Lemma 3.
Let us consider J 3 in the Equation (6), then J 3 is given by
J 3 = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e ( r + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 ) T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) N 2 ( c 1 , c 2 , θ 1 ) ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e ( r + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 ) T σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s × M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( c 3 , c 4 , θ 1 ) ,
where
θ 1 = ( σ 1 ρ 13 σ 2 ρ 23 ) / σ , σ 2 = σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 2 σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 , f ( s , t , u ) = 1 e u ( t s ) , M 1 ( T ) = exp b T λ ( 0 ) b a f ( 0 , T , a ) + σ 4 2 a 2 0 T f 2 ( s , T , a ) d s , c 1 = ln ( V ( 0 ) / D ) σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + r + 1 2 σ 3 2 + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 3 T , c 2 = ln ( S 1 ( 0 ) / S 2 ( 0 ) ) σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 + 1 2 ( σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 ) T σ T , c 3 = ln ( V ( 0 ) / D ) σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + r + 1 2 σ 3 2 + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 T σ 3 T , c 4 = ln ( S 1 ( 0 ) / S 2 ( 0 ) ) σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 + σ 1 σ 2 ρ 12 σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 1 2 ( σ 1 2 + σ 2 2 ) T σ T ,
and θ 1 , σ, f, M 1 ( T ) and N 2 are defined in Lemma 2.
Proof. 
We rewrite J 3 as
J 3 = ( 1 α ) D e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s V ( T ) S 1 ( T ) 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 ( 1 α ) D e r T E P e 0 T λ ( s ) d s V ( T ) S 2 ( T ) 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 : = ( 1 α ) D I 5 ( 1 α ) D I 6 .
To calculate I 5 , we use the measure Q 3 defined in Lemma 2. Under the measure Q 3 , we have
I 5 = e r T M 1 ( T ) E Q 3 V ( T ) S 1 ( T ) 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 ,
where M 1 ( T ) is defined in Lemma 2. With the standard Brownian motions under the measure Q 3 in (14), we define a new measure Q 4 such that
d Q 4 d Q 3 = exp σ 1 W 1 Q 3 ( T ) + σ 3 W 3 Q 3 ( T ) 1 2 ( σ 1 2 + σ 3 2 + 2 ρ 13 σ 1 σ 3 ) T .
By Girsanov’s thoerem,
W 1 Q 4 = W 1 Q 3 ( T ) σ 1 T σ 3 ρ 13 T , W 2 Q 4 = W 2 Q 3 ( T ) σ 1 ρ 12 T σ 3 ρ 23 T , W 3 Q 4 = W 3 Q 3 ( T ) σ 3 T σ 1 ρ 13 T
are the standard Brownian motions under the measure Q 4 . Then, we obtain
I 5 = S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) E Q 4 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 = S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) P Q 4 V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) = S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) N 2 ( c 1 , c 2 , θ 1 ) .
In a similar way, we can write I 6 under the measure Q 3 as
I 6 = e r T M 1 ( T ) E Q 3 V ( T ) S 2 ( T ) 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 .
To calculate I 6 , we define a new measure Q 5 equivalent to Q 3 by
d Q 5 d Q 3 = exp σ 2 W 2 Q 3 ( T ) + σ 3 W 3 Q 3 ( T ) 1 2 ( σ 2 2 + σ 3 2 + 2 ρ 23 σ 2 σ 3 ) T .
By Girsanov’s thoerem,
W 1 Q 5 = W 1 Q 3 ( T ) σ 1 ρ 12 T σ 3 ρ 13 T , W 2 Q 5 = W 2 Q 3 ( T ) σ 2 T σ 3 ρ 23 T , W 3 Q 5 = W 3 Q 3 ( T ) σ 3 T σ 2 ρ 23 T
are the standard Brownian motions under the measure Q 5 . Then, we obtain
I 6 = S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) E Q 4 1 { V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) } | F 0 = S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) P Q 4 V ( T ) > D , S 1 ( T ) > S 2 ( T ) = S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) N 2 ( c 1 , c 2 , θ 1 ) .
This completes the proof. □
From above Lemmas, we can obtain the following theorem.
Theorem 1.
The value of exchange option with credit risk at time 0 under the hybrid credit risk model is given by
C = ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T N ( a 1 ) ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e r T + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 T N ( a 2 ) + S 1 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( b 1 , b 2 , θ 1 ) S 2 ( 0 ) M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( b 3 , b 4 , θ 1 ) ( 1 α ) D S 1 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e ( r + σ 1 σ 3 ρ 13 ) T σ 1 σ 4 ρ 14 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s M 1 ( T ) N 2 ( c 1 , c 2 , θ 1 ) + ( 1 α ) D S 2 ( 0 ) V ( 0 ) e ( r + σ 2 σ 3 ρ 23 ) T σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s σ 3 σ 4 ρ 34 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s × M 1 ( T ) e σ 2 σ 4 ρ 24 a 0 T f ( s , T , a ) d s N 2 ( c 3 , c 4 , θ 1 ) ,
where all parameters and notations are defined in Lemmas 1–3.

4. Concluding Remarks

Exchange option is one of the popular exotic options with two underlying assets in the OTC markets, and credit risk is undoubtedly very important issue in the OTC market. In fact, there have been numerous studies on the valuation of exchange option with credit risk. However, to the best of my knowledge, all results adopted only one of the two models (the reduced-form model and the structural model) for modeling credit risk. In this paper, we first deal with the valuation of exchange option under the hybrid credit risk model combining the reduced-form model and the structural model. Specifically, we use the reduced-form model of Fard [6] and the structural model of Klein [10] to build the hybrid credit risk model. To derive the pricing formula, we adopt the probabilistic approach and use the change of measure technique as the important tool. Finally, we provide the closed-form pricing formula of vulnerable exchange option with the standard normal cumulative distribution functions. Even though our approach has the limitation that the underlying assets for exchange option follow Geometric Brownian Motion (GBM) process, our approach will enable the valuation of other type of multi-asset options under the hybrid credit risk model.

Funding

The author was supported by a National Research Foundation of Korea grant funded by the South Korean government (Grant No. NRF-2017R1E1A1A03070886).

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Black, F.; Scholes, M. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J. Polit. Econ. 1973, 81, 637–654. [Google Scholar]
  2. Margrabe, W. The value of an option to exchange one asset for another. J. Financ. 1978, 33, 177–186. [Google Scholar]
  3. Geman, H.; El Karoui, N.; Rochet, J.C. Changes of numeraire, changes of probability measure and option pricing. J. Appl. Probab. 1995, 32, 443–458. [Google Scholar]
  4. Antonelli, F.; Ramponi, A.; Scarlatti, S. Exchange option pricing under stochastic volatility: A correlation expansion. Rev. Deriv. Res. 2010, 13, 45–73. [Google Scholar]
  5. Kim, J.H.; Park, C.R. A multiscale extension of the Margrabe formula under stochastic volatility. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2017, 97, 59–65. [Google Scholar]
  6. Fard, F.A. Analytical pricing of vulnerable options under a generalized jump–diffusion model. Insur. Math. Econ. 2015, 60, 19–28. [Google Scholar]
  7. Koo, E.; Kim, G. Explicit formula for the valuation of catastrophe put option with exponential jump and default risk. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2017, 101, 1–7. [Google Scholar]
  8. Wang, X. Analytical valuation of vulnerable options in a discrete-time framework. Probab. Eng. Informational Sci. 2017, 31, 100–120. [Google Scholar]
  9. Johnson, H.; Stulz, R. The pricing of options with default risk. J. Financ. 1987, 42, 267–280. [Google Scholar]
  10. Klein, P. Pricing Black-Scholes options with correlated credit risk. J. Bank. Financ. 1996, 20, 1211–1229. [Google Scholar]
  11. Klein, P.; Inglis, M. Valuation of European options subject to financial distress and interest rate risk. J. Deriv. 1999, 6, 44–56. [Google Scholar]
  12. Liao, S.L.; Huang, H.H. Pricing Black–Scholes options with correlated interest rate risk and credit risk: An extension. Quant. Financ. 2005, 5, 443–457. [Google Scholar]
  13. Jeon, J.; Kim, G. Pricing of vulnerable options with early counterparty credit risk. North Am. J. Econ. Financ. 2019, 47, 645–656. [Google Scholar]
  14. Yang, S.J.; Lee, M.K.; Kim, J.H. Pricing vulnerable options under a stochastic volatility model. Appl. Math. Lett. 2014, 34, 7–12. [Google Scholar]
  15. Lee, M.K.; Yang, S.J.; Kim, J.H. A closed form solution for vulnerable options with Heston’s stochastic volatility. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2016, 86, 23–27. [Google Scholar]
  16. Wang, G.; Wang, X.; Zhou, K. Pricing vulnerable options with stochastic volatility. Phys. Stat. Mech. Its Appl. 2017, 485, 91–103. [Google Scholar]
  17. Ma, C.; Yue, S.; Wu, H.; Ma, Y. Pricing Vulnerable Options with Stochastic Volatility and Stochastic Interest Rate. Comput. Econ. 2020, 56, 391–429. [Google Scholar]
  18. Xu, W.; Xu, W.; Li, H.; Xiao, W. A jump-diffusion approach to modelling vulnerable option pricing. Financ. Res. Lett. 2012, 9, 48–56. [Google Scholar]
  19. Tian, L.; Wang, G.; Wang, X.; Wang, Y. Pricing vulnerable options with correlated credit risk under jump-diffusion processes. J. Futur. Mark. 2014, 34, 957–979. [Google Scholar]
  20. Zhou, Q.; Wang, Q.; Wu, W. Pricing vulnerable options with variable default boundary under jump-diffusion processes. Adv. Differ. Equ. 2018, 2018, 465. [Google Scholar]
  21. Han, X. Valuation of vulnerable options under the double exponential jump model with stochastic volatility. Probab. Eng. Informational Sci. 2019, 33, 81–104. [Google Scholar]
  22. Chang, L.F.; Hung, M.W. Valuation of vulnerable American options with correlated credit risk. Rev. Deriv. Res. 2006, 9, 137–165. [Google Scholar]
  23. Jeon, J.; Yoon, J.H.; Kang, M. Valuing vulnerable geometric Asian options. Comput. Math. Appl. 2016, 71, 676–691. [Google Scholar]
  24. Kim, G.; Koo, E. Closed-form pricing formula for exchange option with credit risk. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2016, 91, 221–227. [Google Scholar]
  25. Jeon, J.; Yoon, J.H.; Kang, M. Pricing vulnerable path-dependent options using integral transforms. J. Comput. Appl. Math. 2017, 313, 259–272. [Google Scholar]
  26. Wang, C.; He, J.; Li, S. The European Vulnerable Option Pricing with Jumps Based on a Mixed Model. Discret. Dyn. Nat. Soc. 2016, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  27. Liang, G.; Wang, X. Pricing vulnerable options in a hybrid credit risk model driven by Heston–Nandi GARCH processes. Rev. Deriv. Res. 2020, 1–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Kim, G. A Probabilistic Approach for Valuing Exchange Option with Default Risk. East Asian Math. J. 2020, 36, 55–60. [Google Scholar]
  29. Wang, X. Pricing power exchange options with correlated jump risk. Financ. Res. Lett. 2016, 19, 90–97. [Google Scholar]
  30. Wang, X.; Song, S.; Wang, Y. The valuation of power exchange options with counterparty risk and jump risk. J. Futur. Mark. 2017, 37, 499–521. [Google Scholar]
  31. Xu, G.; Shao, X.; Wang, X. Analytical valuation of power exchange options with default risk. Financ. Res. Lett. 2019, 28, 265–274. [Google Scholar]
  32. Xiang, K.; Hu, P.; Shen, J. Pricing of Power Exchange Option with Jumps under the Double Risk of Exchange and Default. Math. Probl. Eng. 2020, 2020, 4268196. [Google Scholar]
  33. Pasricha, P.; Goel, A. Pricing vulnerable power exchange options in an intensity based framework. J. Comput. Appl. Math. 2019, 355, 106–115. [Google Scholar]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Kim, G. Valuation of Exchange Option with Credit Risk in a Hybrid Model. Mathematics 2020, 8, 2091. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8112091

AMA Style

Kim G. Valuation of Exchange Option with Credit Risk in a Hybrid Model. Mathematics. 2020; 8(11):2091. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8112091

Chicago/Turabian Style

Kim, Geonwoo. 2020. "Valuation of Exchange Option with Credit Risk in a Hybrid Model" Mathematics 8, no. 11: 2091. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8112091

APA Style

Kim, G. (2020). Valuation of Exchange Option with Credit Risk in a Hybrid Model. Mathematics, 8(11), 2091. https://doi.org/10.3390/math8112091

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop