Next Article in Journal
Evaluating Popular Statistical Properties of Incomplete Block Designs: A MATLAB Program Approach
Previous Article in Journal
Fire Risk Sub-Module Assessment under Solvency II. Calculating the Highest Risk Exposure
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Demand Subsidy versus Production Regulation: Development of New Energy Vehicles in a Competitive Environment

School of Business Administration, South China University of Technology, Guangzhou 510640, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Mathematics 2021, 9(11), 1280; https://doi.org/10.3390/math9111280
Submission received: 21 April 2021 / Revised: 26 May 2021 / Accepted: 28 May 2021 / Published: 2 June 2021
(This article belongs to the Section Mathematics and Computer Science)

Abstract

:
In the competitive market environment, the growth of new energy vehicles (NEVs) faces many obstacles. Demand subsidy or production regulation-related policies are widely used to promote the development of NEVs. A comparative analysis of the effects of the two types of policies on the competitive vehicle market requires further study. To fill this gap, we investigate which type of policy is more preferable from the perspective of the social planner. In this paper, we construct a Stackelberg game with a welfare-maximizing social planner and two profit-maximizing manufacturers producing NEVs and fuel vehicles (FVs), respectively. Interestingly, although both types of policies can increase the quantity of NEVs, demand subsidy also promotes the growth of total vehicles at the same time; in contrast, production regulation reduces the total vehicles. Moreover, compared with the benchmark that no policy intervention, demand subsidy generally improves social welfare, while production regulation improves social welfare only with high consumer preference for NEVs. Nevertheless, production regulation always has a positive impact on the environment, whereas demand subsidy may have a positive impact only when the NEV is very environment friendly. The numerical results show that consumer environmental preferences and the regulation of environmental impact determine which type of policy dominates the other.

1. Introduction

New energy vehicles is defined as four-wheel vehicles using alternative fuel sources as the power source instead of conventional oil and gas, which includes hybrid vehicle (HV), battery electrical vehicle (BEV), fuel cell electric vehicle (FCEV), hydrogen engine vehicle (HEV), dimethyl ether vehicle (DEV), and other new energy (e.g., high-efficiency energy-storage devices) vehicles. Facing the increasing energy and environmental pressures, the development of new energy vehicles (NEVs) has become an accessible way to save energy and to reduce emissions. The NEV industry is in an infancy and incubation period in recent years. The report released by global market research organization “Energy Trend” shows that the global NEV sales accounted for only 1% of the total vehicle market and expected to grow up to 5% of total global vehicle sales by 2020 ( https://www.credenceresearch.com/report/new-energy-vehicles-market, (accessed on 21 March 2021)). Many countries announce policies to encourage the development of environmentally friendly vehicle technologies and to accelerate the marketization process of NEVs [1,2]. There are two main types of policies that are widely used to promote the development of NEVs, i.e., demand subsidy and production regulation.
The demand subsidy policies mainly provide preferential and convenience for consumers to purchase and use NEVs [3]. For example, in the U.S., individuals and businesses who purchase NEVs in 2010 and after that year can obtain tax benefits from USD 2500 to USD 7500 based on the energy in the battery [4]. In Norway, local NEV owners enjoy great benefits and conveniences, including free parking, lower annual license fees, exemption from import duties, etc. [5,6].
Regulation policies require manufacturers to increase the output of NEVs and to tighten emission standards of fuel vehicles (FVs). California is the first region to implement the “Zero Emission Vehicles (ZEV)” mandate to regulate vehicle manufacturers, which set an “energy credit” for each NEV and stipulates that the energy credits of NEVs must account for a percentage of the total output [7,8]. Upon failure to meet the requirements, the vehicle manufacturer must pay a fine of USD 5000 per energy credit to the government [7,8]. Similarly, China proposes a dual-credit policy for the automobile industrial on the production standard of NEVs and FVs. The dual-credit policy consists of the corporate average fuel consumption credit (CAFC-credit) rules, which set targets for the average energy consumption rate for FVs, and the new energy vehicle credit (NEV-credit) rules, which stipulate energy credits by NEV type and require certain NEV energy credit quotas. Manufacturers can achieve targets by producing NEVs or by purchasing energy credit from the energy credit trading market. By establishing an energy credit trading mechanism, manufacturers are encouraged to follow the production regulation standard. For example, nearly USD 190 million of Tesla’s profit was earned by selling energy credits in Q3, 2018 ( https://www.thedrive.com/news/24659/nearly-190m-of-teslas-q3-profit-was-earned-by-selling-regulatory-credits-not-sales-revenue, (accessed on 21 March 2021)). On the other hand, the SAIC General Motors Company would cost 28 million to 42 million yuan to purchase energy credit upon failure to meet the production regulation standard.
China, as the world largest vehicle market, implemented the demand subsidy and production regulation policies from 2010 and 2018, respectively. The demand subsidy policies were confirmed effectively in promoting the rapid development of NEVs [9,10]. For example, since the Chinesegovernment introduced subsidy policy for NEV buyers when they purchase or enjoy free parking and charging, the sales of NEVs increased rapidly from 2014 to 2018 (see Figure 1), which also led to steady growth in overall vehicle sales from 2012 to 2017 (see Figure 2). However, it is interesting to note that the implementation of a dual-credit policy made a difference to the vehicle market. The overall vehicle sales slumped after the rapid growth in China in 2018. Moreover, the sales growth rate of NEVs also declined in 2019 after four years of rapid increase. Therefore, based on the observation from reality, we develop a model to explore the reasons behind these phenomena. When promoting the development of NEVs, how does demand subsidies and production regulation affect the optimal production decisions of manufacturers? Moreover, the purpose of promoting NEVs needs not only to protect the environment but also to consider the overall impact on consumers, manufacturers, and society. Hence, the social planner’s optimal decision when formulating corresponding policies considering social welfare and environmental impact are also worth studying further.
In this paper, we investigate the following research questions: (i) What are the impacts of the two types of policies on the NEV adoption process, including price, quantity, and profit of manufacturers? (ii) What is the optimal decision of a social planner that helps achieve the adoption of NEVs and balanced objectives for maximizing social welfare and controls the environmental impact in the NEV market? To answer these questions, we construct a Stackelberg game with a welfare-maximizing policymaker and two profit-maximizing firms competing in the vehicle market. Considering the economic and environmental performances, consumers are assumed to have a preference for environmental attributes and are sensitive to price. By use of backward induction analysis, the optimal price, quantity of each type of vehicle, and the profit of firms are derived under three scenarios, that is, benchmarks without social planner intervention, with demand subsidy policy, and with production regulation policy, respectively. Then, the optimal decision of social planner is derived.
Our results provide several insights. Interestingly, although both types of policies can increase the quantity of NEVs, demand subsidy also promotes the growth of total vehicles at the same time; in contrast, production regulation reduces the number of total vehicles. Moreover, compared with the benchmark without policy intervention, demand subsidy generally improves social welfare, whereas production regulation benefits social welfare only when consumers show a high preference for NEVs. Nevertheless, production regulation always has a positive impact on the environment, whereas demand subsidy may have a positive impact only when the NEV is very environment friendly. The numerical results show that two parameters, consumer environmental preferences and the regulation of environmental impact, determine which type of policy dominates the other, i.e., meets the environmental impact regulation and achieves more social welfare simultaneously.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. A brief review of the related research paper is presented in Section 2. In Section 3, we present model assumptions and descriptions and show the optimal quantity, price, and profit of two manufacturers under three scenarios. In Section 4, we focus on the optimal decision of a social planner with the goal of maximizing social welfare under environmental impacts constraints. Then, we present a numerical experiment to further explore the characteristics of the two types of policies. Finally, we discuss the managerial implications of our study and possible future work in Section 6.

2. Literature Review

Our work builds on and contributes to previous literature on sustainable operations, economics, and operations management in the vehicle field. Therefore, the literature reviewed here primarily relates to two streams of research: (i) the effect of NEV-promoting policies on the manufacturer’s production decision, and (ii) the impact of adopting NEVs on environmental and socioeconomic performance.
Most research concentrates on demand subsidy policies that target the financial incentives such as purchase subsidies, fuel subsidies, and nonfinancial incentives such as free parking and high-occupancy vehicle lane access [11]. From the perspective of the supply chain, several research confirmed that subsidies have a positive role in promoting the development of electric vehicles (EVs). Huang et al. constructed a duopoly model under a government’s subsidy incentive scheme, including an FV supply chain and an EV–FV supply chain. They concluded that a subsidy incentive scheme can help improve social welfare, can increase the sales of NEVs, and can reduce environmental hazards [9]. After that, Luo et al. investigated an automobile supply chain consisting of one supplier and one retailer serving heterogeneous customers [12]. Shao et al. compared the effectiveness of the subsidy scheme and the price discount incentive plan under two different structures: monopoly and duopoly. The consumers’ low-carbon awareness was also taken into account [10]. However, some research showed that subsidies are not significant for the development of EVs. Han et al. presented that the implementation of the EV Subsidy Scheme in China did not successfully promote EV market presentation due to technical limitations of Li-ion batteries for EVs [13]. Diamond found that the subsidy policy and the adoption of EV show a weaker relationship [14]. Moreover, subsidies to promote the application of green technologies in the supply chain have also been confirmed by Wang et al. [15].
To make up for the shortcomings of financial burden caused by subsidies, the production regulation policies are proposed to compulsorily regulate the production decision of manufacturers [16]. Production regulation mainly refers to policies that require manufacturers to tighten emission standards of fuel vehicles (FVs), such as the Corporate Average Fuel Economy(CAFE) standard, and to increase the output of NEVs, such as California’s ZEV mandate and dual-credit policy. To comply with the CAFE regulation, Al-Alawi and Bradley showed that plug-in hybrid electric (PHEV) have advantages that save costs compared to conventional technologies [17]. Sen et al. revealed that the CAFE regulation is indeed an effective policy solution that does increase the adoption of EVs, whether implemented alone or in conjunction with another policy, e.g., government incentives [18]. Moreover, ZEV regulation and dual-credit policy also contribute to the output of NEVs. Greene et al. pointed out that ZEV regulation plays an important role in achieving the transition to EVs despite the market’s many uncertainties [19]. Zhou et al. examined the impact of the dual-credit system on green technology investment and pricing decisions in a two-echelon supply chain [20]. Compared with demand subsidy, Li et al. showed that the dual-credit policy can effectively promote the development of NEVs [21]. Furthermore, Li et al. studied the subsidy policy and dual-credit policy on NEV and conventional vehicle (CV) production decisions from an across-chain perspective. CVs refer to four-wheel vehicles using conventional oil and gas as the source of power. They found that the dual-credit policy can improve the profit of NEV manufacturers and the total supply chain profit with the optimal credit price [22]. Although the impact of the dual-credit policy on manufacturers’ decisions has been studied, our paper focuses on the impact of production regulation from the perspective of the social planner with the goal of maximizing social welfare and controlling the environmental impact in the vehicle market.
As for the study related to the environmental impact of NEVs, early researches found that the adoption of NEVs can significantly reduce greenhouse gas emissions such as carbon dioxide, which is beneficial to the environment [23,24]. Over time, much research extended the assessment of the environmental impact of NEVs to the entire life-cycle from exploitation to utilization. Faria et al. presented an environmental and economic Life-Cycle Assessment for conventional and NEV technology [25]. However, some studies found that NEVs may not be as environmentally friendly as people think. Wu and Zhang pointed out that the impact of using NEVs on the environment should be considered from the perspective of the entire life cycle consisting of the process of exploitation, production, and utilization of energy and further proposed that the different utilization rates of energy in developed and developing countries lead to different effects [26].
In general, existing studies have established a mature framework for NEV industry policies. However, there is a lack of studies on the comparative analysis of the demand subsidy and production regulation in the competitive environment, especially from the perspective of the decision of a social planner. Therefore, by constructing a duopoly model, we compare the production decision under production regulation and demand subsidy scenario. In addition, the social planner’s optimal decisions are also considered.

3. Model Description

We consider two competing manufacturers, M e and M f , which produce and sell the NEVs and FVs, respectively. The two manufacturers M e and M f simultaneously choose product prices p e and p f to maximize their profits. Due to the expensive cost of batteries, the unit production cost of the NEV is higher than that of the FV, i.e., c e > c f . Without loss of generality, we assume that the unit cost of FV is normalized to zero (this assumption is not essential and is for convenience; our result remains valid under c f > 0 ).
We assume consumer heterogeneity with respect to the consumer willing-to-pay for FVs and NEVs. Denote θ as the consumer’s valuation for purchasing the FV, which is subject to a uniform distribution from [ 0 , 1 ] . Considering that the NEV brings extra green utility δ to consumers [27], we obtain the valuation for purchasing the NEV as ( 1 + δ ) θ ( δ > 0 ) , which is widely used, such as in Shao et al. [10]. Table 1 summarizes the key notations in our following model development.
The sequence of the three-stage Stackelberg game is as follows: first, the social planner acts as the leader to set the per unit subsidy or production regulation standard to maximize social welfare. Then, depending on the subsidy or the regulation standard, the manufacturer decides the optimal retail price to maximize their profits. Finally, consumers choose to buy the NEV/FV or to remain inactive.
Next, we explore the impact of different types of policies on the promotion of NEVs. According to backward induction, we first consider the second stage for the manufacturer’s decision. To evaluate the performance of different types of policies, we first seek the scenario without social planner intervention as a benchmark in the next section.

3.1. The Basic Scenario

In the basic scenario, two competing manufacturers decide the retail price p e B , p f B of the NEV and FV simultaneously to maximize their profits without social planner involvement. We use superscript B to represent the basic scenario. First, we analyze the consumers’ optimal strategies with the given retail prices to derive the demand functions of NEVs and FVs. Consumers face three choices, i.e., buy a NEV, buy a FV, or remain inactive. Denote U e ( U f , U r ) as the utility function of buying a NEV (or a FV, or to remain inactive); then, the three utilities for consumers is shown as follows:
U i = ( 1 + δ ) θ p e , i f i = e θ p f , i f i = f 0 , i f i = r
Suppose that the consumer is rational, that is, the consumer chooses a product with higher nonnegative net utility. For example, a consumer with U e > U f and U e > 0 buys the NEV and a consumer with U f < U e and U f > 0 buys the FV. We set the boundary between the purchase of the FV and the NEV to θ 1 = p e B p f B δ , which yields from Equation (1). Similarly, the indifference point for buying a FV and not buying is θ 2 = p f B . With these conditions, given the specific retail price, each manufacture’s sales quantity in the basic scenario is specified in Table 2.
Base on the demand function, the decision problem faced by manufacturer M e is
m a x Π e B ( p e B ) = ( p e B c e ) q e B
and the decision problem faced by manufacturer M f is
m a x Π f B ( p f B ) = p f B q f B
where q e B and q f B denote the quantity of NEVs and FVs determined by the selling price, respectively.
Proposition 1.
For the basic scenario, the optimal decision of manufacturers M e and M f are as follows:
(1)
if δ + 1 2 < c e < 1 , manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f B * = 1 2 ;
(2)
if 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < c e < δ + 1 2 , manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f B * = c e δ ; and
(3)
if 0 < c e < 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ , both firms compete in the market and set the optimal price ( p e B * , p f B * ) = ( 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) 3 + 4 δ , δ + c e 3 + 4 δ ) .
All of the proofs are provided in Appendix A. Proposition 1 shows that the equilibrium state is determined by the unit production cost of the NEV. When the unit production cost of NEV is high enough, i.e., δ + 1 2 < c e < 1 , due to the cost advantages ( c f < c e ), manufacturer M f always provides a lower price than that offered by manufacturer M e to obtain profits as long as p f B > 0 . Thus, manufacturer M f dominates the market with the price p f B * = 1 2 . Manufacturer M e cannot enter the market successfully. As technology advances, the production cost of NEVs declines ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < c e < δ + 1 / 2 ), i.e., the NEV has the potential to enter the market [28]. However, to resist the entry of the NEV, manufacturer 2 sets a lower price for the FV to force the NEV out of the market, i.e., p f B * = c e δ < 1 2 . The price of a FV is already lower than the cost of a NEV, i.e., p f B * = c e δ < c e . To compete with manufacturer M f , if manufacturer M e adopts a price lower than the production cost, the marginal profit is negative, so the only choice is to quit the market. Although manufacturer M f still monopolizes the market, its profit is lower than before due to the impact of the NEV (see Table 3 for detail).
When the unit production cost of the NEV is further reduced, i.e., 0 < c e < 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ , the NEV successfully enters the market and sets price p e B * = 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) 3 + 4 δ . Wu et al. showed that the NEV can become more economic than FVs after 2025, which provides technical support and theoretical basis for the full popularity of the NEV [29]. In this case, even if the price of the NEV is higher than that of the FV, some consumers still choose the NEV owning to consumers’ environmental preferences. Compared with the FV monopoly case, some customers move to buy the NEV, which results in the loss of customers for manufacturer M f . As a response, manufacturer M f raises prices to fully extract consumer surplus. The optimal quantity, price, and profit of manufacturer M e and manufacturer M f in the benchmark scenario are shown in Table 3 and Table 4, respectively.

3.2. The Demand Subsidy Scenario

Under the demand subsidy scenario, the social planner provides certain subsidies for consumers at the time of purchasing the NEV or brings convenience for using the NEV to improve the consumers’ satisfaction, such as free parking or special license plate to get on the road. Hence, consumers have extra utility s when choosing a NEV. In this scenario, the consumer also has three options: buy a NEV, buy a FV, or remain inactive. The utility function of the customer is as follows:
U i = ( 1 + δ ) θ p e + s , i f i = e θ p f , i f i = f 0 , i f i = r
where the utility function for buying a FV and remaining inactive are the same as Equation (1). Similar to the previous section, consumers aim at maximizing their nonnegative utility. Based on the above information, the demand function for NEVs and FVs are shown in Table 5.
Therefore, the problem of manufacturer M e and manufacturer M f can be described as follows:
m a x π e D ( p e D ) = ( p e D c e ) q e D m a x π f D ( p f D ) = p f D q f D
Proposition 2.
For the demand subsidy scenario, when the subsidy is given, the optimal decision of manufacturers M e and M f are as follows:
(1)
if 0 < s s 1 , then manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f D * = 1 2 ;
(2)
if s 1 < s s 2 , then manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f D * = c e s δ ;
(3)
if s 2 < s s 3 , both manufacturers exist in the market, then
( p e D * , p f D * ) = ( ( 1 + 2 δ ) s + 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( c e + δ ) 3 + 4 δ , δ + c e 3 + 4 δ ) ;
(4)
if s 3 < s s 4 , then manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M e posts the optimal price p e D * = s ; and
(5)
if s > s 4 , then manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M e posts the optimal price p e D * = 1 + s + δ + c e 2 ,
where s 1 = c e δ 1 2 , s 2 = c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ , s 3 = c e + δ , s 4 = c e + δ + 1 .
When the subsidy is very low, i.e., s < s 1 , such an inefficient subsidy cannot compensate for the disadvantages of high unit production costs of the NEV. Thus, manufacturer M f dominates the market with the FV and posts price p f D * = 1 2 . As the subsidy increases, i.e., s 1 < s < s 2 , to resist the entry of the NEV, manufacturer M f sets price p f D * = c e s δ . Compared with the basic scenario, the implement of demand subsidy policies forces manufacturer M f to deal with a more serious market crisis, so they cut prices more than before, i.e., p f D * = c e s δ < c e δ = p f B * , resulting in an increase in the quantity of FVs, i.e., q f D * = 1 + s + δ c e > 1 c e + δ = q f B * . In this case, it is worth noting that the incentive not only fails to promote the NEV but also indirectly increases the quantity of the FV.
As the subsidy further increases, manufacturer M e enter the market to compete with manufacturer M f . As the incentive continues to increase, the advantage of manufacturer M e pushing manufacturer M f out of the market grows. Even if manufacturer M f sets the price of an FV to 0, the consumer still chooses a NEV instead of a FV due to their environment preferences. Finally, when the subsidy is very high, i.e., s > s 4 , manufacturer M e dominates the market with price p e D * = 1 + s + δ + c e 2 > 1 2 . Thus, a relatively high price is drawn to fully extract the consumer surplus. The optimal quantity, price, and profit of manufacturer M e and manufacturer M f in the demand subsidy scenario are shown in Table 6 and Table 7, respectively.
Proposition 3.
When NEVs and FVs both exist in the market, i.e., s 2 < s s 3 ,
  • the optimal price and quantity of the NEV both increases with the incentive. Thus, the profit of manufacturer M e increases with incentive, i.e., p e D * s > 0 , q e D * s > 0 , π e D * s > 0 ;
  • the optimal price and quantity of the FV both decrease with the incentive. Thus, the profit of manufacturer M f decreases with incentive, i.e., p f D * s < 0 , p f D * s < 0 , π f D * s < 0 ; and
  • the total quantity of vehicles in the market is larger than that of basic scenario, i.e., q e D * + q f D * > q e B * + q f B * .
Proposition 3 states that, when NEVs and FVs both exist in the market, manufacturer M e produces more NEVs and manufacturer M f produces less FVs with higher subsidy, which is consistent with our intuition. Furthermore, consumers’ utility increases with higher incentive, which indicates consumers are more willing to pay for the NEV. Thus, manufacturer M e posts higher retail prices for NEVs. Conversely, manufacturer M f cuts the prices of FVs to attract consumers. With the increase incentived, the profit of manufacturer M e increases while the profit of manufacturer M f decreases. Furthermore, from q e D * s = 1 + 2 δ δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) > q f D * s = 1 + δ δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) , we can obtain that the growth rate of the NEVs is greater than the decline rate of the FV. Hence, demand subsidy always increases the total quantity of vehicles on the market.

3.3. The Production Regulation Scenario

To promote the production of NEVs from the supply side, the social planner introduces a series of measures, such as a ZEV mandate and a dual-credit policy to require manufacturers to achieve the regulation. The dual-credit policy can be regarded as an enhanced version of ZEV mandate, which not only requires a certain quota energy credit to meet the standards but also penalizes unqualified FVs. We assume that the production of NEVs generates positive energy credit and that the production of FVs produces negative energy credits. If the manufacturer cannot clear the negative credits during the year-end accounting, it bears high fines. Without loss of generality, we assume that each NEV generates 1 energy credit and that each FV generates −1 energy credit. Moreover, the social planner specifies the green credit quota (GCQ) for manufacturers, which requires that the energy credit of the NEV to the energy credit of total vehicles is above a certain threshold, denoted as τ .
Manufacturers can obtain positive energy credit in the following two ways. One is to produce NEVs to generate the required GCQ. If they cannot produce as many as required, they can make up the gap by purchasing energy credits from the energy credit market, where other manufacturers sell extra energy credits. In our model, manufacturer M e only produces an NEV, so it can sell all energy credits generated. Manufacturer M f only produces FVs and needs to purchase additional energy credit depending on their production strategy. The market structure with energy credit trading system is shown in Figure 3. For example, “The average fuel consumption of passenger car companies and the new energy vehicle credit management platform” in China provides a market for credit trading for vehicle manufacturers (http://cafcnev.miit-eidc.org.cn/, (accessed on 21 March 2021)). Thus, in the energy credit trading market, manufacturer M e can sell all energy credits generated and manufacturer M f needs to purchase energy credits depending on the total production quantity, which is τ q f R + 1 * q f R , where τ q f R is the required energy credits and 1 * q f R is to offset the negative energy credit generated by producing FVs. Hence, the problems of the manufacturers are as follows:
m a x π e R ( p e R ) = ( p e R c e ) q e R + p z q e R m a x π e R ( p f R ) = p f R q f R p z τ q f R p z q f R
Proposition 4.
For the production regulation scenario, when GCQ is given, the optimal decision of manufacturers M e and M f are as follows:
(1)
if 0 < τ τ 1 , manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f R * = 1 + τ p z 2 ;
(2)
if τ 1 < τ τ 2 , manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f R * = c e p z δ ;
(3)
if τ 2 < τ τ 3 , both manufacturers exist in the market, then
( p e R * , p f R * ) = ( ( 1 + δ ) ( 2 ( δ + c e ) ( 1 τ ) p z ) 3 + 4 δ , δ + c e ( 1 2 ( τ + 1 ) 2 δ ( τ + 1 ) ) p z 3 + 4 δ ) ;
(4)
if τ 3 < τ τ 4 , manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M e posts the optimal price p e R * = ( 1 + δ ) ( τ + 1 ) p z ; and
(5)
if τ > τ 4 , manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M e posts the optimal price p e R * = 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ,
where τ 1 = 1 2 δ + 2 c e 3 p z p z , τ 2 = 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ( 2 + 3 δ ) p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z τ 3 = δ + c e 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z , τ 4 = 1 + δ + c e ( 3 + 2 δ ) p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z .
Under the production regulation scheme, the equilibrium prices depend on the GCQ τ set by the social planner. We provide some explanation based on τ . In the early stage of policy implementation, when the GCQ is relatively small, i.e., 0 < τ τ 1 , manufacturer M e does not have enough incentive to enter the market. Manufacturer M f dominates the market and posts the price p f R * = 1 + τ p z 2 . Compared with the basic scenario, manufacturer M f purchases the energy credit and transfers this cost to consumers, which indicates a higher retail price, i.e., p f R * = 1 + ( τ + 1 ) p z 2 > 1 2 . Due to the monopoly of manufacturer M f , consumers have no choice but to pay a higher price than before if they want to purchase a FV. When the GCQ becomes larger, i.e., τ 1 < τ τ 2 , manufacturer M e has the possibility to enter the market subject to policy incentives. Manufacturer M f chooses to set lower prices c e p z δ to resist the NEV entering the market, which increases the quantity of the FV. As the policy is further tightened, manufacturer M e enters the market and competes with manufacturer M f , who sets a higher price ( p e R * = ( 1 + δ ) ( 2 ( δ + c e ) ( 1 τ ) p z ) 3 + 4 δ > p f R * = δ + c e ( 1 2 ( τ + 1 ) 2 δ ( τ + 1 ) ) p z 3 + 4 δ ) to share the market with manufacturer M f . When τ 3 < τ τ 4 , the marginal benefit of manufacturer M f to produce an FV is less than 0, i.e., p f R * ( τ + 1 ) p z < 0 . Manufacturer M e posts the price p e R * = ( 1 + δ ) ( τ + 1 ) p z and drives manufacturer M f out of the market. Finally, if τ > τ 4 , manufacturer M e has monopolized the market and is not subject to production regulation scheme. Therefore, they set a higher price than before to fully extract consumer surplus. The equilibrium price, quantity, and profit of manufacturers are shown in Table 8 and Table 9.
Proposition 5.
When NEVs and FVs both exist in the market, i.e., τ 2 < τ τ 3 ,
  • the optimal price, quantity of the NEVs both increases with GCQ, Thus, the profit of manufacturer M e increases with incentive, i.e., p e R * τ > 0 , q e R * τ > 0 , π e R * τ > 0 ;
  • the optimal price of the FVs increase with the GCQ, while the quantity of FVs and the profit of manufacturer M f both decrease with incentive, i.e., p f R * τ < 0 , p f R * τ > 0 , π f R * τ < 0 ; and
  • the total quantity of vehicles in the market is lower than that of basic scenario, i.e., q e R * + q f R * < q e B * + q f B * .
Proposition 5 shows that, when NEVs and FVs both exist in the market, manufacturer M e produces more NEVs and manufacturer M f produces less FVs with higher GCQ, which is consistent with our intuition. The increase of GCQ requires manufacturer M f to purchase more energy credits. Manufacturer M f increases the retail price to cover the cost due to energy credits. Then, we can obtain that the profit of manufacturer M f decreases with the GCQ while the profit of manufacturer M e increases. Furthermore, the impact of the production regulation on the total vehicles is negative. From q e R * τ = ( 1 + δ ) p z δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) < q f R * τ = ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) , we know that the growth rate of NEVs is less than the decline rate of FVs.
Recall proposition 3 in which the demand subsidy stimulates the overall sales of vehicles whereas production regulation reduces the total number of vehicles in the market. This result provides an explanation for the decrease in overall sales in the vehicle market after China implemented the dual-credit policy in 2018. The overall sales of NEVs were 1.25 million in 2018, which was 110% higher than that in 2017. However, the total sales of the vehicle market were 28.08 million, which decreased by 2.8% compared to that in 2017. The implementation of dual-credit policy promotes the growth of NEVs but suppresses the development of FVs effectively, thereby reducing overall sales.

4. The Social Planner Decisions

Recall that the main purpose of promoting NEVs is to improve the environment. We first explore the effects of two types of policies on the environment impact. Denote the unit environmental impact of the NEV and the FV as e 1 and e 2 , respectively. The total environmental impact of the vehicle market can be computed as E i = e 1 q e i * + e 2 q f i * ( i = B , D , R ) , where e 1 q e i * and e 2 q f i * represent the total environmental impacts of the NEVs and the FVs. Since the impact of vehicles on the environment is generally harmful, we assume that the environmental impact of vehicles is better smaller.
Proposition 6.
Compared with no policy intervention, production regulation always reduces environmental impact, i.e., E R < E B . However, demand subsidy may increase environmental impact, depending on the environmental attributes of NEVs, i.e., E D E B if e 1 < e 2 2 and s 3 < s s 4 , otherwise, E D > E B .
Proposition 6 reveals the effect of two types of policies on environmental impact. Production regulation not only increases the quantity of NEVs but also cuts down the total amount of vehicles, thereby reducing the environmental impact. However, demand subsidy always increases the total amount of vehicles. Therefore, only when the NEVs are very environmentally friendly ( e 1 < e 2 2 ) does demand subsidy benefit the environment.
Then, to investigate how the social planner decides on the optimal subsidy or the GCQ τ with the goal of maximizing social welfare, we assume that there is an upper bound for environmental impact, which is an exogenous parameter E 0 in the following model. For nontrivial analysis, we assume E 0 > m i n { e 1 , e 2 2 } . The social welfare consists of the manufacturers’ total profits, the consumer surplus, the social planner expenditure, or the profit of energy credit trading market.
Consumer surplus (CS) is defined as the aggregate utility of consumers in the vehicle market. Following, the CS in the production regulation scenario can be constructed as follows:
C S R = θ 1 1 U e ( θ ) d θ + θ 2 θ 1 U f ( θ ) d θ + 0 θ 2 U r ( θ ) d θ = 1 + δ 2 ( q e R ( 2 q e R ) ) p e R q e R + q f R 2 ( 2 ( 1 q e R ) q f R ) p f R q f R
When demand subsidy is adopted, the consumer’s utility function changes; thus, the CS in the demand subsidy scenario is
C S D = θ 1 1 U e ( θ ) d θ + θ 2 θ 1 U f ( θ ) d θ + 0 θ 2 U r ( θ ) d θ = 1 + δ 2 ( q e D ( 2 q e D ) ) ( p e D s ) q e D + q f D 2 ( 2 ( 1 q e D ) q f D ) p f D q f D
Thus, the problem of social planner to implement the demand subsidy is shown as follows:
m a x s S W D = π e D + π f D + C S D s q e D s . t . e 1 q e D + e 2 q f D E 0
The optimal demand subsidy s * of social planner is presented in Table 10.
Table 10 shows the optimal subsidy selection follows three parameters, including the unit production cost of NEV c e , the unit environment impact of the NEV e 1 , and the environment impact upper bound E 0 . We divided equilibrium into four cases based on the unit NEV production cost c e and unit NEV environmental impact e 1 : (1) high cost and low environmentally friendly, i.e., c e > c ¯ , e 1 > e 2 2 , which indicates that adopting high cost produces a low environmentally friendly NEV; (2) high cost and high environmentally friendly: c e > c ¯ , e 1 < e 2 2 , which represents that adopting high cost produces a high environmentally friendly NEV; (3) low cost and low environmentally friendly: c e < c ¯ , e 1 > e 2 2 ; and (4) low cost and high environmentally friendly: c e < c ¯ , e 1 < e 2 2 .
Proposition 7.
From Table 10, we have following result:
  • in cases 1 and 3, the optimal subsidy decreases in E 0 , i.e., s * E 0 < 0 ;
  • in cases 2 and 4, the optimal subsidy increases in with E 0 , i.e., s * E 0 > 0 ; and
  • when E 0 is large enough, i.e., E 0 > E ¯ , the optimal subsidy is s * = ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) , which is independent of E 0 .
We observe that, in cases 1 and 3, the optimal subsidy s * decreases with E 0 , i.e., small E 0 induces large s * . In this case, the NEV is very environmentally friendly ( e 1 < e 2 2 ), so when the environmental impact upper bound is small ( E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 ), increased subsidy promotes the production of NEVs, regardless of whether the production cost c e is high or low. Second, in cases 2 and 4, the optimal subsidy s * increases with E 0 , i.e., small E 0 induces small s * . This reason is as follows. Recall Proposition 1 that the rising subsidy leads to an increase in overall quantity of vehicles. As the unit environment impact of the NEV is low environmentally friendly ( e 1 > e 2 2 ), increased subsidy cannot improve the environment. Last, when the environmental impact upper bound is large enough, the amount of subsidy is independent on E 0 , which is common in four cases.
Next, we study the social planner’s optimal decisions of GCQ under a production regulation scenario. The problem in model R is shown as follows:
m a x τ S W R = π e R + π f R + C S R p z ( q e R ( τ + 1 ) q f R ) s . t . e 1 q e R + e 2 q f R E 0
The optimal GCQ decision τ of social planner is presented in Table 11.
Proposition 8.
From Table 11, we have following result:
  • when E 0 is relatively small, the optimal GCQ τ decreases with E 0 , i.e., τ * E 0 < 0 if E 1 < E 0 E 2 ;
  • production regulation cannot always improve social welfare.
When adopting production regulation policies, we find that the optimal decision on τ is independent of the unit environment impact of the NEV e 1 , which is different from the optimal decision of demand subsidy policy. First, we observe that, when E 0 is small, the optimal GCQ decreases with E 0 , i.e., small E 0 results in large τ . which indicates that the stricter the environmental impact constraints, the higher the value of GCQ. The reason is that the increase in GCQ always decreases the total number of vehicles, which leads to a positive environmental impact. Recall that the implementation of production regulation policies does have a positive impact on the environment. However, proposition 8 indicates that production regulation cannot always improve social welfare. When the environmental impact upper bound is large, we find that not implementing GCQ maximizes social welfare, i.e., τ * = 0 . This is because the positive impact of the implementation of GCQ on the environment cannot offset the negative impact of the decline in manufacturers’ profit and consumer surplus.
In summary, demand subsidy can change the environmental impact positively or negatively, depending on the environmental properties of the NEVs, but it improves social welfare. Production regulation has a positive impact on the environment, but this result comes at the expense of social welfare.

5. Numerical Analysis

In this section, we compare the trend of social welfare with environmental impact upper bound E 0 under two types of policies. Due to the complexity of equilibrium, we show the results with numerical examples. Recall that S W D and S W R are the social welfare under demand subsidy and production regulation scenario, respectively. Based on the survey report in China Association of Automobile Manufacturers (http://www.caam.org.cn/chn/21.html, (accessed on 21 March 2021)), we obtain the parameters as follows: c e = $ 10 , 800 , p z = $ 300 , e 1 = 72 g/mile, and e 2 = 150 g/mile. Without loss of generality, we normalized the parameters to values in [0,1].
The dashed line ( S W = 0.375 ) parallel to the x-axis in the Figure 4 represents the value of social welfare without social planner . From Figure 4, we observe that production regulation better controlling the environmental impact of vehicles than demand subsidy. For example, if the environmental impact upper bound is large ( E 0 > 0.0062 ), there is S W D > S W R with the same E 0 . Demand subsidy now dominates over production regulation, controlling the environmental impact with E 0 while obtaining more social welfare than production regulation. In summary, production regulation can achieve stricter environmental impact limits but at the expense of social welfare. Demand subsidy is preferred when restrictions are looser, while performing ineffective if E 0 is small. Then, when could the production regulation dominate?
Figure 5 shows the optimal social welfare with the change in E 0 . The only difference between the parameters used in Figure 4 and Figure 5 is δ , which changes from δ = 0.1 to δ = 0.2 . We can see that there is an interval such that, given the same E 0 , the social welfare under production regulation is larger than that of demand subsidy, i.e., S W R > S W D . Therefore, when consumers have a higher preference for NEVs, production regulation is preferred.

6. Conclusions

NEVs, a new type of green vehicle, has received global attention due to the energy crisis and environmental pollution caused by global automobiles. Countries have implemented various policies related to demand subsidy and production regulation to promote the development of NEVs. In this paper, we constructed three competitive environments for FV and NEV manufacturers, namely, without social planner intervention, with demand subsidy, and with production regulation. Based on game models, we derived the manufacture’s optimal price and quantity under three scenarios. Considering social welfare and environmental impact, the social planner’s decision on subsidy and GCQ are also obtained. The main findings are as follows.
Economically, without social planner intervention, only when the production cost of NEVs is low enough can NEVs enter the market and compete with FVs. The social planner’s policy to promote the development of NEVs can offset the disadvantages of production costs. It turns out that the implementation of the two types of policies can effectively increase the quantity of NEVs. However, the impact of the two types of policies on the structure of the vehicle market is different. Demand subsidy increases the overall number of FVs and NEVs. While the production regulation reduces the total number of vehicles while developing NEVs. This result inspires that we can apply these policies in different scenarios. For regions economically developed and with high car parc, although demand subsidy promotes the development of NEVs, they also increase the total number of vehicles, thus making the traffic load heavier. Therefore, production regulation is an ideal choice. On the contrary, for regions less economically developed and with low car parc, demand subsidy can not only promote the adoptions of NEVs but also increase overall car quantity to boost the economic development, which kills two birds with one stone.
Socially, the optimal social welfare is determined by the environmental impact upper bound, the unit production cost of NEVs , and the environmental attributes of NEVs. Moreover, compared with the benchmark with no policy intervention, demand subsidy policies generally improve social welfare while production regulation improves social welfare only with a high consumer preference for NEVs. Nevertheless, production regulation always has a positive impact on the environment, whereas the impact of demand subsidy policies on the environment depends on the environmental properties of NEVs. Numerical analysis shows that consumer environmental preferences and the regulation of environmental impact determine which type of policy dominates the other. In summary, if social planners pay more attention to improving social welfare, then demand subsidy is the optimal choice. Otherwise, social planners prefer production regulation to more emphasis on improving the environment.

Author Contributions

Writing—original draft preparation, Z.W.; writing—review and editing, Z.W. and X.L. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the anonymous referees for their valuable remarks.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Proof of Results in Table 1.
According to Equation (1), U e = ( 1 + δ ) θ p e B , and U f = θ p f B , we have the following three cases:
(i)
When U e > U f > 0 , i.e., < ( 1 + δ ) p f B < p e B < δ + p f B , the customer buys an EV or a FV or nothing. Let U e = U f , U f = 0 , we can obtain θ 1 = p e B p f B δ and θ 2 = p f B , respectively. Then, q e B = 1 θ 1 = δ p e B + p f B δ and q f B = p e B ( 1 + δ ) p f B δ .
(ii)
When U f > 0 > U e , i.e., p e B > δ + p f B , the customer either buys an FV or nothing. Let U f = 0 and θ 2 = p f B . Thus, q f B = 1 θ 2 = 1 p f B and q e B = 0 .
(iii)
When U e > 0 > U f , i.e., p e B < ( 1 + δ ) p f B , the customer either buys an EV or nothing. Let U e = 0 and θ 3 = p e B 1 + δ . Then, q e B = 1 θ 3 = 1 p e B 1 + δ .
 □
Proof of Proposition 1.
The profit functions of manufacturer M e and manufacturer M f are π e B = ( p e B c e ) q e B ( p e B , p f B ) and π f B = p f B q f B ( p e B , p f B ) , respectively. Denote p e B ( p f B ) as the best response of manufacturer M e , given that manufacturer M f posts price p f B . In other words, p e B ( p f B ) is the best response function. It is easy to see that
p e B ( p f B ) = δ + c e + p f B 2 δ c e < p f B < δ + c e 1 + 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) p f B δ + c e 1 + 2 δ < p f B < 1 + δ + c e 2 ( 1 + δ ) 1 + δ + c e 2 p f B > 1 + δ + c e 2 ( 1 + δ ) , p f B ( p e B ) = p e B 2 ( 1 + δ ) p e B < 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ p e B δ 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < p e B < 1 2 + δ 1 2 p e B > 1 2 + δ
Hence, when δ + c e > 1 2 and c e < 1 , the unique Nash equilibrium is that manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f B * = 1 2 . When δ 1 + 2 δ < δ + c e < 1 2 , the unique Nash equilibrium is that manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts the optimal price p f B * = c e δ . When δ 1 + 2 δ > δ + c e , both manufacturer exists in the market and ( p e B * , p f B * ) = ( 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) 3 + 4 δ , δ + c e 3 + 4 δ ) . □
Figure A1. Best response curve.
Figure A1. Best response curve.
Mathematics 09 01280 g0a1
Proof of Proposition 2.
The best responses of manufacturer M e and manufacturer M f are given as follows (see Figure A1):
(1) [Manufacturer M e ’s response] When δ 1 + 2 δ < s δ + c e , the best response of manufacturer M e is to quit the market. When s δ + c e < δ 1 + 2 δ , manufacturer M e enters the market and the optimal price is given by
p e D ( p f ) = s + δ + c e + p f D 2 p f D < s + δ + c e 1 + 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) p f D + s s + δ + c e 1 + 2 δ < p f D < 1 s + δ + c e 1 + 2 δ 1 2 ( 1 + s + δ + c e ) p f D > 1 s + δ + c e 1 + 2 δ
(2) [Manufacturer M f ’s response] if s + δ + c e < 0 , the best response of manufacturer M f is to quit the market. If s + δ + c e > 0 , manufacturer M f enters the market and the optimal price is given by
p f D ( p e D ) = s + p e D 2 ( 1 + δ ) p e D < s + 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ p e D s δ s + 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < p e D < 1 2 + s + δ 1 2 p e D > 1 2 + s + δ
When p f 1 > p f * , manufacturer M e quits the market, manufacturer M f posts price 1 2 , the quantity of FV q f D * = 1 p e D = 1 2 , and the profit of manufacturer M f is π f D * = 1 4 . When p f 4 < p f 1 < p f * , it follows that manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts price c e δ , the quantity of FV q f D * = 1 p e D = 1 + δ c e , and the profit of manufacturer 2 is π f D * = ( c e δ ) ( 1 + δ c e ) . When p f 1 < p f 4 and p f 2 > 0 , the two best response curves cross only once. Manufacturer M e posts price p e D * = ( 1 + 2 δ ) s + 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( c e + δ ) 3 + 4 δ , and manufacturer M f posts price p f D * = s + δ + c e 3 + 4 δ . When p f 2 < 0 , p f 3 > 0 , manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M f posts price p e D * = s When p f 3 < 0 , manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M e posts price p e D * = 1 + s + δ + c e 2 . □
Proof of Proposition 3.
It is easy to obtain that p e D * s = 1 + 2 δ 3 + 4 δ > 0 , q e D * s = 1 + 2 δ δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) > 0 , p f D * s = 1 3 + 4 δ < 0 , q f D * s = 1 + δ δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) < 0 . As for the profit, π f D * s = 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( s + δ + c e ) δ ( 3 + δ ) . Recall that, in period 3, s < c e + δ . Thus, π f D * s < 0 . Similarly, we have π e D * s > 0 . □
Figure A2. Best response curve.
Figure A2. Best response curve.
Mathematics 09 01280 g0a2
Proof of Proposition 4.
The best responses of manufacturer M e and manufacturer M f are given as follows (see Figure A2):
(1) [Manufacturer M e ’s response] When ( 1 + δ ) τ p z < 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) , the best response of manufacturer M e is to quit the market. When ( 1 + δ ) τ p z > 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) , manufacturer M e enters the market and the optimal price is given by
p e R ( p f ) = s + δ + c e + p f p z 2 p f < δ + c e p z ( 1 + δ ) p f δ + c e p z < p f < δ + c e p z 1 + 2 δ 1 2 ( 1 + δ + c e + p z ) p f > δ + c e p z 1 + 2 δ
(2) [Manufacturer M f ’s response] If τ ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z > δ + c e p z , the best response of manufacturer M f is to quit the market. If τ ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z < δ + c e p z , manufacturer M f enters the market and the optimal price is given by
p f R ( p e R ) = p e R + ( 1 + δ ) τ p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p e R < ( 1 + δ ) τ p z p e R δ ( 1 + δ ) τ p z < p e R < ( 1 + δ ) ( 2 δ + τ p z ) 1 + 2 δ 1 2 ( 1 + τ p z ) p e R > ( 1 + δ ) ( 2 δ + τ p z ) 1 + 2 δ
Proof. 
When p f 1 > p f * , manufacturer M e quits the market, manufacturer M f posts price p f R * = 1 2 ( 1 + τ p z ) , the quantity of FV q f R * = 1 p e = 1 2 ( 1 + τ p z ) , and the profit of manufacturer M f is π f R * = 1 4 ( 1 τ p z ) 2 . When p f 4 < p f 1 < p f * , it follows that manufacturer M e quits the market and manufacturer M f posts price p f R * = c e δ p z , the quantity of FV q f R * = 1 p e R = 1 + δ c e + p z , and the profit of manufacturer M f is π f R * = ( c e + δ ( 1 + τ ) p z ) ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) . When p f 1 < p f 4 and p f 2 > 0 , the two best response curves cross only once. Manufacturer M e posts price p e R * = ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( 2 ( δ + c e ) + ( τ 2 ) p z ) 3 + 4 δ , and manufacturer M f posts price p f R * = δ + c e p z + ( 1 + δ ) 2 τ p z 3 + 4 δ . When p f 2 < 0 , p f 3 > 0 , manufacturer M f quits the market and manufacturer M f posts price p e R * = ( 1 + δ ) τ p z When p f 3 < 0 , manufacturer M f quits the market, manufacturer M e posts price p e R * = 1 + δ + c e p z 2 . □
Proof of Proposition 5.
It is easy to obtain that p e R * τ = ( 1 + δ ) p z 3 + 4 δ > 0 , q e R * s = ( 1 + δ ) p z δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) > 0 , p f R * τ = 2 p z ( 1 + δ ) 3 + 4 δ > 0 , q f R * τ = ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) < 0 . As for the profit,
π f R * τ = 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z ( ( 1 + τ + 2 δ τ ) p z + δ + c e ) δ ( 3 + δ ) 2 . Recall that, in period 3, τ < δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z . Thus, π f R * τ < 0 . Similarly, we have π e R * τ > 0 . □
Proof Proposition 6.
The environment impact under production regulation and demand subsidy is shown in Figure A3 and Figure A4. □
Figure A3. Changes in environmental impact under production regulation policies.
Figure A3. Changes in environmental impact under production regulation policies.
Mathematics 09 01280 g0a3
Figure A4. Changes in environmental impact under demand subisdy policies.
Figure A4. Changes in environmental impact under demand subisdy policies.
Mathematics 09 01280 g0a4
Proof of Proposition 7.
The social welfare S W ( s ) under purchase-oriented policy is as follows:
S W ( s ) = { 3 8 s < c e δ 1 2 1 2 ( 1 s δ + c e ) ( 1 + s + δ c e ) c e δ 1 2 < s < c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ 1 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 ( 2 s δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 5 + 4 δ ) s 2 ( 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) + δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 9 + δ ( 23 + 12 δ ) ) + 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( s + 4 s δ δ ( 7 + 12 δ ) ) c e + ( 5 + 3 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) c e 2 ) c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < s < c e + δ 1 2 ( 1 2 s + δ 2 c e ) c e + δ < s < c e + δ + 1 ( 3 5 s + 3 δ 3 c e ) ( 1 + s + δ c e ) 8 ( 1 + δ ) s > c e + δ + 1
If s < c e δ 1 2 , S W s = 0 .
If c e δ 1 2 < s < c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ , S W s = R δ + c e , S W 2 s 2 = 1 . The SW is concave on s. The optimal subsidy is s * = c e δ . Due to c e δ > c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ . Therefore, SW increases with s in region 2.
If c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < s < c e + δ , S W s = 1 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 5 + 4 δ ) 2 s ( 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) + 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e ) , S W 2 s 2 = 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 . The SW is concave on s. The optimal subsidy is s * = ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e ) δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) . When c e > δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 , s * < s 2 , the optimal s is c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ . When c e < δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 , s 2 < s * < s 3 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e ) δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) .
If c e + δ < s < c e + δ + 1 , S W s = 1 , SW decreases with s.
If s > c e + δ + 1 , S W s = 1 + 5 s + δ c e 4 + 4 δ < 0 , SW decreases with s.
Next, we discuss the environment impact of vehicles with the change in s.
E ( s ) = e 2 2 s < c e δ 1 2 ( 1 + s + δ c e ) e 2 c e δ 1 2 < s < c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ e 1 ( 1 + 2 δ ) s + 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) + e 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( s + δ + c e ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < s < c e + δ e 1 c e + δ < s < c e + δ + 1 e 1 1 + s + δ c e 2 + 2 δ s > c e + δ + 1
According to the relationship between e 1 and e 2 , there are three cases of changes in E. (1) When e 1 > 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , E increase with s. case a: c e > δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 . If E 0 < e 2 2 , there is no optimal s that satisfies the conditions. If e 2 2 E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) e 2 + c e e 2 + E 0 e 2 . If 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 E 0 , the optimal s is c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ . case b: c e < δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 . If E 0 < e 2 2 , there is no optimal s that satisfies the conditions. If e 2 2 E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) e 2 + c e e 2 + E 0 e 2 . If 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 E 0 < E 1 , the optimal s is ( ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 If E 1 E 0 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) ( δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) .
(2) When e 2 2 e 1 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , E first increases with s, then decreases, and finally increases. case a: c e > δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 . If E 0 < e 2 2 , there is no optimal s that satisfies the conditions. If e 2 2 E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) e 2 + c e e 2 + E 0 e 2 . If 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 E 0 , the optimal s is c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ . case b: c e < δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 . If E 0 < e 2 2 , there is no optimal s that satisfies the conditions. If e 2 2 E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) e 2 + c e e 2 + E 0 e 2 . If 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 E 0 < E 1 , the optimal s is ( ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 If E 1 E 0 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) ( δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) .
(3) When e 1 e 2 2 , case a: c e > δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 . If E 0 < e 1 , there is no optimal s that satisfies the conditions. If e 1 E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , the optimal s is ( ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 . If 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 E 0 , the optimal s is c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ . case b: c e < δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 . If E 0 < e 1 , there is no optimal s that satisfies the conditions. If e 1 E 0 < 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 , the optimal s is ( ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 . If 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 E 0 , the optimal s is ( 1 + δ ) ( δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) . □
Proof of Proposition 8.
The social welfare S W ( τ ) of the production-oriented policy is as follows:
S W ( τ ) = 1 8 ( 1 τ p z ) ( 3 + τ p z ) τ < 1 p z ( 1 δ + 2 c e 2 p z ) 1 2 ( 1 δ + c e p z ) ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) 1 p z ( 1 δ + 2 c e 2 p z ) < τ < 2 δ 2 δ 2 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z 1 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 ( ( 5 + 3 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) c e 2 + T + K ) 2 δ 2 δ 2 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z < τ < δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z 1 2 ( 1 τ p z ) ( 1 + δ 2 c e + ( 1 + δ ) τ p z ) δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z < τ < 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z ( 3 + 3 δ 3 c e p z ) ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) 8 ( 1 + δ ) τ > 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z
where K = ( 1 + δ ) ( δ ( 9 + δ ( 23 + 12 δ ) ) + 2 δ ( 1 + 4 δ + τ ) p z ( ( 1 + τ ) 2 + δ ( 4 + ( 5 + 4 δ ) τ 2 ) ) p z 2 ) , T = 2 c e ( δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 7 + 12 δ ) + ( 2 ( 1 + τ ) + δ ( 5 + 6 τ + 4 δ ( 1 + τ ) ) ) p z ) .
If τ < 1 p z ( 1 δ + 2 c e 2 p z ) , S W τ = 1 4 ( 1 + τ p z ) < 0 , SW decreases with τ . If 1 p z ( 1 δ + 2 c e 2 p z ) < τ < 2 δ 2 δ 2 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z , S W τ = 0 . If 2 δ 2 δ 2 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z < τ < δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z , S W 2 τ 2 = ( 1 + δ ) ( 2 + 2 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) p z 2 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 < 0 . SW is concave on τ . If δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z < τ < 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z , S W 2 τ 2 = ( 1 + δ ) 2 p z < 0 . SW is concave on τ . If τ > 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z , S W τ = 0 .
Next, we discuss the environment impact of vehicles with the change in τ .
E ( τ ) = 1 2 ( 1 τ p z ) e 2 τ < 1 p z ( 1 δ + 2 c e 2 p z ) ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) e 2 1 p z ( 1 δ + 2 c e 2 p z ) < τ < 2 δ 2 δ 2 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z e 1 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e + ( 1 + τ + δ ( 2 + τ ) ) p z δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) + e 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ( 1 + τ + 2 δ τ ) p z ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 δ 2 δ 2 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e p z ) ( 1 + δ ) p z < τ < δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z ( 1 τ p z ) e 1 δ + c e p z ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z < τ < 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z 1 + δ c e + p z 2 + 2 δ e 1 τ > 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) p z
We find that the environment impact decreases with τ . Then, we discuss the optimal decision on τ with the limited environment impact E 0 .
(1) c e > 1 + δ p z . If 1 + δ c e + p z 2 + 2 δ e 1 < E 0 < 1 + δ c e + p z 1 + 2 δ e 1 , the optimal τ * = e 1 E 0 e 1 p z . If 1 + δ c e + p z 1 + 2 δ e 1 < E 0 < ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) e 2 , the optimal τ * = arg max τ = τ a , τ 4 ( S W ( τ ) ) . If E 0 > ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) e 2 , the optimal τ * = e 2 2 E 0 e 2 p z .
(2) c e < 1 + δ p z . Denote τ b = δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 + ( 1 + δ ) e 2 ( δ + c e p z ) + e 1 ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e + ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z ) ( 1 + δ ) ( e 1 + ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 2 ) p z If 1 + δ c e + p z 2 + 2 δ e 1 < E 0 < 1 + δ c e + p z 1 + 2 δ e 1 , the optimal τ * = e 1 E 0 e 1 p z . If E 0 > 1 + δ c e + p z 1 + 2 δ e 1 , the optimal τ * = e 2 2 E 0 e 2 p z , τ * = arg max τ = τ b , τ c ( S W ( τ ) ) . □

References

  1. Du, H.; Liu, D.; Sovacool, B.K.; Wang, Y.; Ma, S.; Li, R. Who buys new energy vehicles in china? Assessing social-psychological predictors of purchasing awareness, intention, and policy. Transp. Res. 2018, 58, 56–69. [Google Scholar]
  2. Du, J.; Ouyang, M.; Chen, J. Prospects for chinese electric vehicle technologies in 2016–2020: Ambition and rationality. Energy 2017, 120, 584–596. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Soylu, T.; Anderson, J.E.; Bttcher, N.; Wei, C.; Kuhnimhof, T. Building up demand-oriented charging infrastructure for electric vehicles in germany. Transp. Res. Procedia 2016, 19, 187–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Jenn, A.; Azevedo, I.L.; Ferreira, P. The impact of federal incentives on the adoption of hybrid electric vehicles in the united states. Energy Econ. 2013, 40, 936–942. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Bjerkan, K.Y.; Norbech, T.E.; Nordtomme, M.E. Incentives for promoting battery electric vehicle (BEV) adoption in norway. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2016, 43, 169–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Mersky, A.C.; Sprei, F.; Samaras, C.; Qian, Z.S. Effectiveness of incentives on electric vehicle adoption in Norway. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2016, 46, 56–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  7. Wesseling, J.H.; Farla, J.C.M.; Hekkert, M.P. Exploring car manufacturers’ responses to technology-forcing regulation: The case of California’s ZEV mandate. Environ. Innov. Soc. Transit. 2015, 16, 87–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Majumdar, S.R. A Prospect Theory Analysis of California’s Initiatives in Implementation of its Zero Emission Vehicles (ZEV) Mandate. Rev. Policy Res. 2005, 22, 157–169. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Huang, J.; Leng, M.; Liang, L.; Liu, J. Promoting electric automobiles: Supply chain analysis under a government’s subsidy incentive scheme. IEEE Trans. 2013, 45, 826–844. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Shao, L.; Yang, J.; Min, Z. Subsidy scheme or price discount scheme? Mass adoption of electric vehicles under different market structures. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 262, 1181–1195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Melton, N.; Axsen, J.; Goldberg, S. Evaluating plug-in electric vehicle policies in the context of long-term greenhouse gas reduction goals: Comparing 10 canadian provinces using the “pev policy report card”. Energy Policy 2017, 107, 381–393. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Luo, C.; Leng, M.; Huang, J.; Liang, L. Supply chain analysis under a price-discount incentive scheme for electric vehicles. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2014, 235, 329–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Hao, H.; Ou, X.; Du, J.; Wang, H.; Ouyang, M. China’s electric vehicle subsidy scheme: Rationale and impacts. Energy Policy 2014, 73, 722–732. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Diamond, D. The impact of government incentives for hybrid-electric vehicles: Evidence from US states. Energy Policy 2009, 37, 972–983. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Wang, M.; Lian, S.; Yin, S.; Dong, H. A three-player game model for promoting the diffusion of green technology in manufacturing enterprises from the perspective of supply and demand. Mathematics 2020, 8, 1585. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Zhou, Y.; Wang, M.; Hao, H.; Johnson, L.; Wang, H. Plug-in electric vehicle market penetration and incentives: A global review. Mitig. Adapt. Strateg. Glob. Chang. 2015, 20, 777–795. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Al-Alawi, B.M.; Bradley, T.H. Analysis of corporate average fuel economy regulation compliance scenarios inclusive of plug in hybrid vehicles. Appl. energy 2014, 113, 1323–1337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Sen, B.; Noori, M.; Tatari, O. Will Corporate Average Fuel Economy (CAFE) Standard help? Modeling CAFE’s impact on market share of electric vehicles. Energy Policy 2017, 109, 279–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Greene, D.L.; Park, S.; Liu, C. Analyzing the transition to electric drive vehicles in the U.S. Futures 2014, 58, 34–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Zhou, D.; Yu, Y.; Wang, Q.; Zha, D. Effects of a generalized dual-credit system on green technology investments and pricing decisions in a supply chain. J. Environ. Manag. 2019, 247, 269–280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Li, Y.; Zhang, Q.; Liu, B.; McLellan, B.; Gao, Y.; Tang, Y. Substitution effect of new-energy vehicle credit program and corporate average fuel consumption regulation for green-car subsidy. Energy 2018, 152, 223–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Li, J.; Ku, Y.; Yu, Y.; Liu, C.; Zhou, Y. Optimizing production of new energy vehicles with across-chain cooperation under China’s dual credit policy. Energy 2020, 194, 116832. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Rolim, C.C.; Gonçalves, G.N.; Farias, T.L.; Rodrigues, Ó. Impacts of electric vehicle adoption on driver behavior and environmental performance. Procedia Soc. Behav. Sci. 2012, 54, 706–715. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Hawkins, T.R.; Gausen, O.M.; Strømman, A.H. Environmental impacts of hybrid and electric vehicles—A review. Int. J. Life Cycle Assess. 2012, 17, 997–1014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Faria, R.; Marques, P.; Moura, P.; Freire, F.; Delgado, J.; De Almeida, A.T. Impact of the electricity mix and use profile in the life-cycle assessment of electric vehicles. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2013, 24, 271–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Wu, Y.; Zhang, L. Can the development of electric vehicles reduce the emission of air pollutants and greenhouse gases in developing countries? Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2017, 51, 129–145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Feng, Z.; Tan, C. Pricing, green degree and coordination decisions in a green supply chain with loss aversion. Mathematics 2019, 7, 239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  28. Delucchi, M.A.; Lipman, T.E. An analysis of the retail and lifecycle cost of battery-powered electric vehicles. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2001, 6, 371–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  29. Wu, G.; Inderbitzin, A.; Bening, C. Total cost of ownership of electric vehicles compared to conventional vehicles: A probabilistic analysis and projection across market segments. Energy Policy 2001, 80, 196–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. China’s new energy vehicle sales trends. Note: source: China Association of Automobile Manufacturers (http://www.caam.org.cn/english, (accessed on 21 March 2021)).
Figure 1. China’s new energy vehicle sales trends. Note: source: China Association of Automobile Manufacturers (http://www.caam.org.cn/english, (accessed on 21 March 2021)).
Mathematics 09 01280 g001
Figure 2. China’s vehicle sales trends. Note: source: China Association of Automobile Manufacturers (http://www.caam.org.cn/english, (accessed on 21 March 2021)).
Figure 2. China’s vehicle sales trends. Note: source: China Association of Automobile Manufacturers (http://www.caam.org.cn/english, (accessed on 21 March 2021)).
Mathematics 09 01280 g002
Figure 3. Market structure with energy credit trading system.
Figure 3. Market structure with energy credit trading system.
Mathematics 09 01280 g003
Figure 4. The social welfare under two types of policies with the change in the environment impact upper bound E 0 ( δ = 0.1 ) .
Figure 4. The social welfare under two types of policies with the change in the environment impact upper bound E 0 ( δ = 0.1 ) .
Mathematics 09 01280 g004
Figure 5. The social welfare under two types of policies with the change in the environment impact upper bound E 0 ( δ = 0.2 ) .
Figure 5. The social welfare under two types of policies with the change in the environment impact upper bound E 0 ( δ = 0.2 ) .
Mathematics 09 01280 g005
Table 1. Abbreviation
Table 1. Abbreviation
ParametersDefinition
θ Consumer’s valuation for the purchase of the FV
δ Consumer’s green utility of environmental awareness
c e Unit production cost of a NEV
c f Unit production cost of a FV (Normalized to 0)
q e i , q f i Quantity of NEVs or FVs, i B , D , R
π e i , π f i Profit of the manufacturers M e or M f , i B , D , R
Decisions
p e i Retail price of a NEV set by the manufacturer M e , i B , D , R
p f i Retail price of a FV set by the manufacturer M f , i B , D , R
sSubsidy to NEV buyers set by the social planner
τ Green credit quota regulation to FV manufacturer set by the social planner
Superscripts
BThe scenario that without social planner intervention
DThe scenario that with demand subsidy policies
RThe scenario that with production regulation policies
Table 2. Sales quantities of firms under the basic scenario.
Table 2. Sales quantities of firms under the basic scenario.
Condition q e B q f B
p e B < ( 1 + δ ) p f B 1 p e B 1 + δ 0
( 1 + δ ) p f B < p e B < δ + p f B δ p e B + p f B δ p e B p f B δ p f B
δ + p f B < p e B 0 1 p f B
Table 3. Equilibrium profit under the basic scenario.
Table 3. Equilibrium profit under the basic scenario.
Conditions π e B * π f B *
δ + 1 2 < c e < 1 0 1 4
2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < c e < δ + 1 2 0 ( 1 + δ c e ) ( c e δ )
0 < c e < 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2
Table 4. Equilibrium price and quantity under the basic scenario.
Table 4. Equilibrium price and quantity under the basic scenario.
Conditions p e B * p f B * q e B * q f B *
δ + 1 2 < c e < 1 0 1 2 0 1 2
2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ < c e < δ + 1 2 0 c e δ 0 1 + δ c e
0 < c e < 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) 3 + 4 δ δ + c e 3 + 4 δ 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ )
Table 5. Sales quantities of manufacturers under the demand subsidy scenario.
Table 5. Sales quantities of manufacturers under the demand subsidy scenario.
Conditions q e D q f D
p e D < ( 1 + δ ) p f D + s 1 p e D s 1 + δ 0
( 1 + δ ) p f D + s < p e D < δ + p f D + s δ p e D + p f D + s δ p e D p f D s δ p f D
δ + p f S + s < p e D 0 1 p f D
Table 6. Equilibrium price and quantity under the demand subsidy scenario.
Table 6. Equilibrium price and quantity under the demand subsidy scenario.
Conditions p e D * p f D * q e D * q f D *
0 < s s 1 0 1 2 0 1 2
s 1 < s s 2 0 c e s δ 0 1 + s + δ c e
s 2 < s s 3 ( 1 + 2 δ ) s + 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( c e + δ ) 3 + 4 δ s + δ + c e 3 + 4 δ ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( s c e ) + 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e s ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ )
s 3 < s s 4 s010
s > s 4 1 + s + δ + c e 2 0 1 + s + δ c e 2 ( 1 + δ ) 0
Table 7. Equilibrium profit under the demand subsidy scenario.
Table 7. Equilibrium profit under the demand subsidy scenario.
Conditions π e D * π f D *
0 < s s 1 0 1 4
s 1 < s s 2 0 ( 1 + δ c e + s ) ( c e δ s )
s 2 < s s 3 ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) ( c e s ) ) 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e s ) 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2
s 3 < s s 4 s c e 0
s > s 4 ( 1 + δ c e + s ) 2 4 ( 1 + δ ) 0
Table 8. Equilibrium price and quantity under the production regulation scenario.
Table 8. Equilibrium price and quantity under the production regulation scenario.
Conditions p e R * p f R * q e R * q f R *
0 < τ τ 1 0 1 + ( τ + 1 ) p z 2 0 1 ( τ + 1 ) p z 2
τ 1 < τ τ 2 0 c e p z δ 0 1 + δ c e + p z
τ 2 < τ τ 3 ( 1 + δ ) ( 2 ( δ + c e ) ( 1 τ ) p z ) 3 + 4 δ δ + c e ( 1 2 ( τ + 1 ) 2 δ ( τ + 1 ) ) p z 3 + 4 δ K δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ( 2 + τ + 2 δ ( τ + 1 ) ) p z ) δ ( 3 + 4 δ )
τ 3 < τ τ 4 ( 1 + δ ) ( τ + 1 ) p z 0 1 ( τ + 1 ) p z 0
τ > τ 4 1 + δ + c e p z 2 0 1 + δ + c e p z 2 ( 1 + δ ) 0
Table 9. Equilibrium profit under the production regulation scenario.
Table 9. Equilibrium profit under the production regulation scenario.
Conditions π e R * π f R *
0 < τ τ 1 0 1 4 ( 1 ( ( τ + 1 ) p z ) 2 )
τ 1 < τ τ 2 0 ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) ( c e δ ( 2 + τ ) p z )
τ 2 < τ τ 3 ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e + ( 2 + τ + δ ( 3 + τ ) ) p z ) 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ( 2 + τ + 2 δ ( τ + 1 ) ) p z ) 2 δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) 2
τ 3 < τ τ 4 ( 1 ( τ + 1 ) p z ) ( ( 1 + δ ) ( τ + 1 ) p z c e ) 0
τ > τ 4 ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) 2 4 ( 1 + δ ) 0
Table 10. The optimal decision on s.
Table 10. The optimal decision on s.
Equilibrium Condition s *
(1). e 1 e 2 2
c e > c ¯ e 1 < E 0 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2
E 0 > 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ
c e c ¯ e 1 < E 0 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2
E 0 > 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ )
(2). e 2 2 < e 1 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2
c e > c ¯ e 1 < E 0 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 c e e 2 + E 0 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 e 2
E 0 > 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ
c e c ¯ e 2 2 < E 0 E ¯ c e e 2 + E 0 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 e 2
E 0 > E ¯ ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ )
(3). e 1 > 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2
c e > c ¯ e 2 2 < E 0 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 c e e 2 + E 0 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 e 2
E 0 > 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 c e 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) 1 + 2 δ
c e < c ¯ e 2 2 < E 0 1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 c e e 2 + E 0 ( 1 + δ ) e 2 e 2
1 + δ 1 + 2 δ e 2 < E 0 < E ¯ ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e ) e 2 + δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) e 2
E 0 > E ¯ ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 4 δ ) c e δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ )
Note: c ¯ = δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 , E ¯ = ( δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 3 + 8 δ ) 2 ( 1 + 2 δ ) 2 c e ) e 1 + 2 ( 1 + δ ) ( δ ( 2 + 3 δ ) + ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e ) e 2 δ ( 7 + 5 δ ( 5 + 4 δ ) ) .
Table 11. The optimal decision on τ .
Table 11. The optimal decision on τ .
Equilibrium Condition τ *
E 1 < E 0 E 2 e 1 E 0 e 1 p z
E 2 < E 0 E 3 c e > 1 + δ p z arg max τ = τ b , τ 4 ( S W ( τ ) )
c e < 1 + δ p z arg max τ = τ b , τ c ( S W ( τ ) )
E 3 < E 0 E 4 c e > 1 + δ p z arg max τ = τ a , τ 4 ( S W ( τ ) )
c e < 1 + δ p z arg max τ = 0 , τ c ( S W ( τ ) )
E 0 > E 4 c e > 1 + δ p z arg max τ = 0 , τ 4 ( S W ( τ ) )
c e < 1 + δ p z arg max τ = 0 , τ c ( S W ( τ ) )
Note: E 1 = 1 + δ c e + p z 2 + 2 δ e 1 , E 2 = 1 + δ c e + p z 1 + 2 δ e 1 , E 3 = ( 1 + δ c e + p z ) e 2 , E 4 = e 2 2 , τ a = e 2 2 E 0 e 2 p z , τ b = δ ( 3 + 4 δ ) E 0 + ( 1 + δ ) ( δ + c e p z ) e 2 + ( 2 δ ( 1 + δ ) ( 1 + 2 δ ) c e + ( 1 + 2 δ ) p z ) e 1 ( 1 + δ ) ( ( 1 + 2 δ ) e 2 e 1 ) p z , τ c = c e ( 1 + δ ) p z .
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, Z.; Li, X. Demand Subsidy versus Production Regulation: Development of New Energy Vehicles in a Competitive Environment. Mathematics 2021, 9, 1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9111280

AMA Style

Wang Z, Li X. Demand Subsidy versus Production Regulation: Development of New Energy Vehicles in a Competitive Environment. Mathematics. 2021; 9(11):1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9111280

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Zixuan, and Xiuzhang Li. 2021. "Demand Subsidy versus Production Regulation: Development of New Energy Vehicles in a Competitive Environment" Mathematics 9, no. 11: 1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9111280

APA Style

Wang, Z., & Li, X. (2021). Demand Subsidy versus Production Regulation: Development of New Energy Vehicles in a Competitive Environment. Mathematics, 9(11), 1280. https://doi.org/10.3390/math9111280

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop