2.2. The Concept of Productivity and Labor Productivity
Different definitions of productivity have been expressed in the literature, most of them called productivity as the ratio of output to input (
Proverbs et al. 2000;
Jarkas and Bitar 2012;
Thomas et al. 1990;
Hanna et al. 2005;
Shehata and El-Gohary 2011). The concept of productivity can be applied to any economy: small, medium, and large businesses, governments, and individuals. The goal of productivity is the maximum use of resources to produce as many goods and services as consumers desire at the lowest possible cost. Productivity is the production ratio in time to input in the same period (
Helmer and Suver 1988). In other words, productivity in activities means achieving the maximum benefit through the efficient and optimal use of expert staff, used machines, places of activity, etc., to improve welfare at the community level. In addition, productivity can be considered as the ratio of the work performed to the work that should be performed (
Landier et al. 2013).
On the other hand, productivity has been widely studied in developed countries to identify opportunities for improvement. The most essential elements to improve productivity are managing materials, equipment, and labor (
Banik 2017). In 1766 AD, the issue of exploitation and its surrounding issues were raised worldwide. In the next century, a new definition of labor productivity was presented, which pointed out that power means the ability of people to produce. This issue has expanded with extensive changes at the international level and the need for a solid force to carry out activities. Today, human power has been the focus of much research due to its increasing importance in economic development. The productivity of human resources is one of the most fundamental factors in achieving the progress and expansion of organizational performance and economic development in countries. Human resource efficiency can be defined as the effective and efficient use of human resources to achieve organizational goals.
Nojedehi and Nasirzadeh (
2017) classified twenty-six labor productivity factors into five categories: motivational factors, factors related to working conditions, political factors, labor-related factors, and management-related factors. A study conducted by
Hickson and Ellis (
2014) ranked the factors affecting labor productivity and reported that a lack of labor supervision is the most influencing factor of labor productivity, followed by unrealistic planning, lack of skilled labor, lack of construction, management experience, delays in requesting information, delays in the payment of wages to the labor force, poor communication on site, and bad weather conditions.
Jamadagni and Birajdar (
2015) identified the most critical factors affecting labor productivity as overtime, clarification of technical documentation, labor fatigue, delays in payment of labor, change in order change delays, poor management communication, and a lack of labor training.
Mahamid (
2014) believes that factors such as the country’s political situation, lack of equipment, old equipment, lack of work experience, and poor management have a negative impact on labor productivity. However, these techniques differ from one industry (
Pheng and Meng 2018;
Thomas and Daily 1983). Achieving higher productivity is the goal of any organization because it sets the foundation for cost savings and plays a crucial role in careful planning. Moreover, financial success plays a role. Researchers in their countries have identified 16 different labor productivity factors (
Maloney 1983). Hence, similar studies should be conducted in other developing countries and cultures to determine whether the meaning of labor productivity and its causes and determinants are immutable. According to
Zahoor et al. (
2017), a stronger focus on cross-cultural studies would help explain how critical determinants of labor productivity vary across national contexts.
2.4. Hypothesis Development
With the expansion of global markets and the increasing number of companies, one of the main challenges companies face is providing the resources they need. In this regard, trying to use various resources effectively and efficiently, the most important of which is human resources, is the vital goal of managers of organizations, commercial and industrial units, and service institutions (
Davenport 2011). A suitable structure for a company, effective implementation of methods, and sufficient and quality equipment are among the necessary things to increase the workforce’s productivity. The company’s workforce and employees are part of its capital and valuable resources, and its productivity is essential for organizations. Labor productivity shows employees’ knowledge, ability, and valuable criteria, so companies must identify factors affecting labor productivity to achieve labor efficiency. The past literature and recent studies have measured the impact of various criteria on labor productivity. For example,
Ryan (
2012) found that the resources spent on employee training positively affect workforce productivity. In addition,
Bukit et al. (
2018) showed that better planning in human resources, employment, and selection strategies has a significant and positive effect on workforce productivity. Despite the studies that were conducted, the critical point that needs to be more evidenced is the effect of the CEO’s power, as the main feature of the role of the CEO and his effectiveness in the organization, on the productivity of the company’s workforce.
The board of directors elects the highest-ranking CEO in the business to act as an intermediary between the board of directors and the stakeholders. Based on the theory of games, it is argued that the CEO has the best performance in the hierarchy of an organization (
Menon et al. 2000). When a CEO is more powerful, the CEO’s relative performance is more potent, as is the ability to increase labor productivity. As a result, powerful CEOs better manage the company’s resources (including labor), leading to higher labor productivity. As one of the primary factors in making decisions and guiding organizational strategies, the CEO’s power can significantly impact employee performance. Managers with high power can draw policies and strategies that improve efficiency and increase workforce productivity. This impact may come through motivating employees, optimizing work processes, and effectively interacting with work teams. Hence, we expect a positive relationship between CEO power and labor productivity.
Several studies have been conducted in this field, including
Holzer (
2015), showing that salary, experience, current job tenure, hours spent in training, and workers’ gender positively relate to labor productivity. Also, the results of
Dyer and Reeves (
1995) indicate that a company’s success is strongly related to labor productivity. In this regard,
Breit et al. (
2019) addressed the impact of CEO power on workforce productivity and showed a positive relationship between CEO power and workforce productivity. Companies with more powerful executives show higher labor productivity.
Kudyba (
2003) found that employees’ skills can be improved through proper training, which can increase the organization’s efficiency.
Han et al. (
2016) found a positive and significant relationship between CEO power and labor productivity. They further decompose labor productivity into efficiency and cost components and find a positive (negative) relationship between CEO power and labor efficiency (cost), suggesting that more powerful CEOs improve labor efficiency by managing and controlling labor costs. In other words, according to the tournament theory, labor productivity is higher in companies that have more powerful CEOs.
Creemers et al. (
2023) showed that family ownership generates a productivity advantage for firms located in the lower tail of the labor productivity distribution. In contrast, it negatively affects labor productivity in the upper tail compared to their nonfamily counterparts.
Shi (
2024) suggests that both augmented innovation investment and alleviated bankruptcy costs explain the reduction in labor income shares. Heterogeneity tests also show that the effect is more pronounced in firms with weaker political connections, higher institutional ownership, higher customer concentration, and in state-owned firms. Therefore, the first hypothesis of the research is as follows:
H1. A positive and significant relationship exists between the CEO’s power and the workforce’s productivity.
According to the theories about the behavior of costs, the change in the cost amount depends on the companies’ activity level. In other words, the only factor of change in cost is the amount of change in the activity level. In this regard, costs are divided into two general groups: fixed and variable. Variable costs change with changes in the organization’s activity level; fixed costs are permanently fixed and unrelated to the business’s activities. These costs for organizations are always a fixed amount (
Horngren et al. 2002); however, now, the basis of the cost has changed, and discussions about cost stickiness have been raised. Cost stickiness can be defined as when sales decrease, the ratio of reduction that occurs in fixed costs is lower than when sales increase and costs increase. CEO characteristics may impact the firms’ strategic decision-making process. For example,
Salehi et al. (
2020a) investigate the impact of managerial ability on investment efficiency. Accordingly, we expect that CEO power might be influential in this regard. When the organization’s managers become powerful, they can influence resources and other employees more and show more opportunistic behaviors (
Dichev et al. 2013). The presence of powerful CEOs means that the employees are under the CEO’s power, and the management can easily manage their expenses. Therefore, the stickiness of the manager reduces labor costs. The CEO’s power in long-term decisions and setting financial policies can impact labor cost stickiness. Managers with more power may formulate financial policies in a way that helps regulate and predict labor costs. These measures can reduce financial uncertainty and create peace in the work environment, and as a result, increase labor cost stickiness. Supportively,
Salehi et al. (
2018) have argued that cost stickiness is likely to impact firms’ financial reporting quality.
Sun and Yu (
2015), using a list of member companies of the China Stock Exchange, show that socially responsible companies show lower labor force stickiness.
Deshmukh et al. (
2013) found that when managers have too much confidence and trust in their behavior when the company is financing, they prefer to reduce the dividend to avoid foreign investment and impose more costs on the company.
Chen et al. (
2013) believed that managers overestimate demand and, as a result, predicted a small probability of reducing general, administrative, and sales costs when sales decrease. Finally, the results of this research show their significant role.
Lee et al. (
2020) showed that the CEO’s financial expertise has a negative effect on cost stickiness. Also, a negative and significant relationship exists between CEO power and labor cost stickiness. Short-sighted managers may manage profits by reducing expenses when sales decrease to prevent losses and costs from creating stickiness. Managers’ short-term attitude has a negative relationship with cost stickiness. On the other hand, when the level of sales and incomes decrease, managers with more power act to reduce costs, including labor costs and the stickiness of labor costs.
Recent investigations also suggest that CEO power has a positive and significant effect on stickiness, and free cash flow has a positive and significant impact on cost stickiness (
Tajedini 2024).
Jeon and Ra (
2024) uncover that higher CEO risk-taking incentives are associated with increased cost stickiness. Moreover, they observe that this relationship is strengthened under specific conditions, namely when financial leverage is lower, corporate governance is weaker, equity market uncertainty is higher, and real investment opportunities are limited.
Zhang et al. (
2023) document that cost stickiness is negatively associated with internal governance after controlling for legitimate economic reasons for cost stickiness, suggesting that internal governance mitigates agency-based cost stickiness. Consistent with the agency’s explanation, their results show that the impact of internal governance on cost stickiness is stronger for firms with lower future value creation of selling, general, and administrative (SG&A) costs. In addition, they contend that the impact of internal governance on cost stickiness is more pronounced for firms with more-effective board monitoring.
Therefore, the second hypothesis of the research is as follows:
H2. There is a negative and significant relationship between CEO power and labor cost stickiness.
Given that managers and senior managers are recognized as critical factors in financing, investment, and other strategic decisions, their opinions about the company profoundly affect the company’s practices and results. Several recent studies try to fill this gap and raise this critical question: Do the behaviors and characteristics of managers affect the company’s activities and strategies? For example,
Van den Steen (
2005) explicitly incorporates the CEO’s perspective into his corporate policy model.
Bertrand and Schoar (
2003) report strong evidence of director-fixed effects for various corporate decisions. Overall, the empirical evidence supports that director-level characteristics affect firm outcomes. An essential dimension of top management team characteristics is power. When a company’s decision-making power is more concentrated in the hands of the CEO, he will have more authority to influence decisions. Thus, his opinions will be more directly reflected in the company’s results. This has positive and negative implications for stakeholders, as CEOs can use this dominant role to set company policy better or advance their goals.
Various studies have been conducted on the above topic that showed a positive and significant relationship between CEO power and company value. However, this effect is driven by competition in the product market because the power of CEO has a positive effect on the company’s value only in highly competitive markets and has no effect on the company’s value in low-competition markets. The results show that CEO power positively relates to firm value in highly competitive markets when corporate governance is vital, suggesting that corporate governance and competition are complementary. In other words, the results show that the competition in the product market motivates powerful CEOs to use their power to increase the company’s value.
Mousa et al. (
2023) showed that organizations with excess human capacity provide more investment in research and development on average, and in concentrated industries where executives are less under competitive pressure, powerful CEOs intervene in this strategic choice and the relationship between slack and innovation (slack–innovation relationship). Although CEOs in this context may have sufficient slack resources, they appear inclined to allocate such resources to goals other than innovation.
Chu et al. (
2023) showed that companies with more powerful CEOs are less involved in CSR activities, and this negative relationship is intensified by younger, more competent, and overconfident CEOs. However, this negative relationship is exacerbated by women CEOs.
Garcia-Sanchez et al. (
2021) found that CEOs with more power oppose integrated information disclosure, and more significant growth opportunities increase CEO opposition to integrated information disclosure about value creation.
Brahma and Economou (
2024), in a literature review, show that the existing findings are mixed in relation to the effects of CEO power on firm strategies. Overall, the negative impact of CEO power on firm performance is attributed to agency theory, where CEOs pursue their own vested interests, thereby leading to weak corporate governance. Their review reveals that the positive impact of CEO power on corporate outcomes is due to effective board monitoring, a powerful board, and high market competition. Their study also shows that most prior studies have adopted
Finkelstein’s (
1992) four sources of CEO power but have taken different proxies to measure these powers.
Saleh et al. (
2024) show that institutional ownership and CEO power positively affect firm performance. In addition, it has been established that CEO power strengthens the relationship between institutional ownership and performance. Thus, it can be summarized that institutional ownership improves firm performance; however, with powerful CEO intervention, the performance will improve even more.
Saiyed et al. (
2023) indicate that entrepreneurial orientation has an inverted U-shaped relation with firm performance. Strong support is also found for a negative moderating influence of CEO power on the inverted U-shaped relationship between entrepreneurial orientation and firm financial performance, suggesting that powerful CEOs eventually harm entrepreneurial firms.
Therefore, the third hypothesis of the research is as follows:
H3. A positive and significant relationship exists between the CEO’s power and the company’s value.
Studies have investigated the factors and consequences of the asymmetric behavior of costs. In other words, while the traditional variable-fixed cost model emphasizes the automatic reaction of the cost to the change in activity levels, the literature and background of asymmetric cost behavior emphasize the critical role of insight and management understanding that can influence how resources are managed and how costs occur and are eliminated. In this regard, cost stickiness affects managers’ performance and strategies. The existence of stickiness in the cost of labor affects various aspects of the company’s performance and ultimately affects the value of the company (
Aboody et al. 2005).
Gong et al. (
2010) showed that in companies suspected of profit management, the cost behavior is different from those not suspected of management, which shows a relationship between profit management and cost stickiness.
Xu et al. (
2023) find that agency cost mediates the effect of a privately owned business group (POBG) on labor cost stickiness.
Tileal et al. (
2023) showed that labor cost stickiness is higher in government and family firms than in non-government and non-family businesses.
Ma et al. (
2023) found that CSR suppresses cost stickiness. The higher the performance level, the lower the cost stickiness and agency cost partially moderates the relationship between CSR and cost stickiness.
Costa and Habib (
2023) find a robust negative relationship between cost stickiness and firm value. They then explore whether the resource adjustment, managerial expectations, and agency theories of cost stickiness affect the negative relation and find support for the managerial expectation and agency theories. Furthermore, they find evidence that the detrimental impact of cost stickiness on firm value is mediated partially through the cost of equity and cash flow channels. Further investigation suggests that the adverse effects of cost stickiness on firm values are stronger in the presence of high information asymmetry. The study of
Kong et al. (
2023) reveals that labor cost changes driven by the adjustment of employee education levels are sticky. The standard adjustment cost theory cannot explain this stickiness. This further shows that firms that actively adjust their employee quality during downturns experience improved future performance.
Xu et al. (
2023) find that, on average, a privately owned business group-affiliated firm entirely mitigates labor cost stickiness when it has a decrease in sales. In addition, they document that, to adjust its labor cost downward, a privately owned business group-affiliated firm hires fewer employees rather than paying lower wages. They show that the lower labor cost stickiness is due to the movement of employees from the focal firm to other firms within the same privately owned business group. When sales fall, the privately owned business group reallocates excess employees at the focal firm to other firms within the business group via an internal labor market, and the focal firm thereby increases its per capita profit. Moreover, they find that agency cost mediates the impact of a privately owned business group on labor cost stickiness. When the external market is less effective, or the privately owned business group headquarters have strong incentives, the effect of privately owned business group affiliation on reducing an affiliated firm’s labor cost stickiness is more salient. Therefore, the fourth hypothesis of the research is as follows:
H4. A positive and significant relationship exists between labor cost stickiness and company value.