1. Introduction
The theory of information-based asset pricing proposed by
Brody et al. (
2007,
2008a,
2008b) and
Macrina (
2006) is concerned with the determination of the price processes of financial assets from first principles. In particular, the market filtration is constructed explicitly, rather than simply assumed, as it is in traditional approaches. The simplest version of the model is as follows. We fix a probability space
. An asset delivers a single random cash flow
at some specified time
, where time 0 denotes the present. The cash flow is a function of a random variable
, which we can think of as a “market factor” that is in some sense revealed at time
T. In the general situation there will be many factors and many cash flows, but for the present we assume that there is a single factor
such that the sole cash flow at time
T is given by
for some Borel function
. For simplicity we assume that interest rates are constant and that
is the risk neutral measure. We require that
should be integrable. Under these assumptions, the value of the asset at time 0 is
where
denotes expectation under
and
r is the short rate. Since the single “dividend” is paid at time
T, the value of the asset at any time
is of the form
where
is the market filtration. The task now is to model the filtration, and this will be done explicitly.
In traditional financial modelling, the filtration is usually taken to be fixed in advance. For example, in the widely-applied Brownian-motion-driven model for financial markets, the filtration is generated by an
n-dimensional Brownian motion. A detailed account of the Brownian framework can be found, for example, in
Karatzas and Shreve (
1998). In the information-based approach, however, we do not assume the filtration to be given
a priori. Instead, the filtration is constructed in a way that specifically takes into account the structures of the information flows associated with the cash flows of the various assets under consideration.
In the case of a single asset generating a single cash flow, the idea is that the filtration should contain partial or “noisy” information about the market factor
, and hence the impending cash flow, in such a way that
is
-measurable. This can be achieved by allowing
to be generated by a so-called information process
with the property that for each
t such that
the random variable
is
-measurable. Then by constructing specific examples of cádlàg processes having this property, we are able to formulate a variety of specific models. The resulting models are finely tuned to the structures of the assets that they represent, and therefore offer scope for a useful approach to financial risk management. In previous work on information-based asset pricing, where precise definitions can be found that expand upon the ideas summarized above, such models have been constructed using Brownian bridge information processes (
Brody et al. (
2007,
2008a,
2009,
2010,
2011),
Filipović et al. (
2012),
Hughston and Macrina (
2012),
Macrina (
2006),
Mengütürk (
2013),
Rutkowski and Yu (
2007)), gamma bridge information processes (
Brody et al. (
2008b)), Lévy random bridge information processes (
Hoyle (
2010),
Hoyle et al. (
2011,
2015,
2020),
Mengütürk (
2018)) and Markov bridge information processes (
Macrina (
2019)). In what follows we present a new model for the market filtration, based on the variance-gamma process. The idea is to create a two-parameter family of information processes associated with the random market factor
. One of the parameters is the information flow-rate
. The other is an intrinsic parameter
m associated with the variance gamma process. In the limit as
m tends to infinity, the variance-gamma information process reduces to the type of Brownian bridge information process considered by
Brody et al. (
2007,
2008a) and
Macrina (
2006).
The plan of the paper is as follows. In
Section 2 we recall properties of the gamma process, introducing the so-called scale parameter
and shape parameter
. A standard gamma subordinator is defined to be a gamma process with
. The mean at time
t of a standard gamma subordinator is
t. In Theorem 1 we prove that an increase in the shape parameter
m results in a transfer of weight from the Lévy measure of any interval
in the space of jump size to the Lévy measure of any interval
such that
and
. Thus, roughly speaking, an increase in
m results in an increase in the rate at which small jumps occur relative to the rate at which large jumps occur. This result concerning the interpretation of the shape parameter for a standard gamma subordinator is new as far as we are aware.
In
Section 3 we recall properties of the variance-gamma process and the gamma bridge, and in Definition 1 we introduce a new type of process, which we call a normalized variance-gamma bridge. This process plays an important role in the material that follows. In Lemmas 1 and 2 we work out various properties of the normalized variance-gamma bridge. Then in Theorem 2 we show that the normalized variance-gamma bridge and the associated gamma bridge are jointly Markov, a property that turns out to be crucial in our pricing theory. In
Section 4, at Definition 2, we introduce the so-called variance-gamma information process. The information process carries noisy information about the value of a market factor
that will be revealed to the market at time
T, where the noise is represented by the normalized variance-gamma bridge. In Equation (
58) we present a formula that relates the values of the information process at different times, and by use of that we establish in Theorem 3 that the information process and the associated gamma bridge are jointly Markov.
In
Section 5, we consider a market where the filtration is generated by a variance gamma information process along with the associated gamma bridge. In Lemma 3 we work out a version of the Bayes formula in the form that we need for asset pricing in the present context. Then in Theorem 4 we present a general formula for the price process of a financial asset that at time
T pays a single dividend given by a function
of the market factor. In particular, the
a priori distribution of the market factor can be quite arbitrary, specified by a measure
on
, the only requirement being that
should be integrable. In
Section 6 we present a number of examples, based on various choices of the payoff function and the distribution for the market factor, the results being summarized in Propositions 1–4. We conclude with comments on calibration, derivatives, and how one determines the trajectory of the information process from market prices.
2. Gamma Subordinators
We begin with some remarks about the gamma process. Let us as usual write
for the non-negative real numbers. Let
and
m be strictly positive constants. A continuous random variable
on a probability space
will be said to have a gamma distribution with scale parameter
and shape parameter
m if
where
denotes the standard gamma function for
, and we recall the relation
. A calculation shows that
, and
. There exists a two-parameter family of gamma processes of the form
on
. By a gamma process with scale
and shape
m we mean a Lévy process
such that for each
the random variable
is gamma distributed with
If we write and for the so-called Pochhammer symbol, we find that . It follows that and , where and , or equivalently , and .
The Lévy exponent for such a process is given for
by
and for the corresponding Lévy measure we have
One can then check that the Lévy-Khinchine relation
holds for an appropriate choice of
p (
Kyprianou 2014, Lemma 1.7).
By a standard gamma subordinator we mean a gamma process for which . This implies that and . The standard gamma subordinators thus constitute a one-parameter family of processes labelled by m. An interpretation of the parameter m is given by the following:
Theorem 1. Let be a standard gamma subordinator with parameter m. Let be the Lévy measure of the interval for . Then for any interval such that and the ratiois strictly greater than one and strictly increasing as a function of m. Proof. By the definition of a standard gamma subordinator we have
Let
and note that the integrand in the right hand side of (
10) is a decreasing function of the variable of integration. This allows one to conclude that
from which it follows that
and hence
. To show that
is strictly increasing as a function of
m we observe that
where the so-called exponential integral function
is defined for
by
See
Abramowitz and Stegun (
1972), Section 5.1.1, for properties of the exponential integral. Next, we compute the derivative of
, which gives
where
We note that
which shows that the sign of the derivative in (
14) is strictly positive if and only if
But clearly
for
, which after a change of integration variables and use of (
15) implies
which is equivalent to (
17), and that completes the proof. □
We see therefore that the effect of an increase in the value of m is to transfer weight from the Lévy measure of any jump-size interval to any possibly-overlapping smaller-jump-size interval of the same length. The Lévy measure of such an interval is the rate of arrival of jumps for which the jump size lies in that interval.
3. Normalized Variance-Gamma Bridge
Let us fix a standard Brownian motion
on
and an independent standard gamma subordinator
with parameter
m. By a standard variance-gamma process with parameter
m we mean a time-changed Brownian motion
of the form
It is straightforward to check that
is itself a Lévy process, with Lévy exponent
The other object we require going forward is the gamma bridge (
Brody et al. (
2008b),
Emery and Yor (
2004),
Yor (
2007)). Let
be a standard gamma subordinator with parameter
m. For fixed
the process
defined by
for
and
for
will be called a standard gamma bridge, with parameter
m, over the interval
. One can check that for
the random variable
has a beta distribution (
Brody et al. 2008b, pp. 6–9). In particular, one finds that its density is given by
where
It follows then by use of the integral formula
that for all
we have
and hence
Accordingly, one has
and therefore
One observes, in particular, that the expectation of does not depend on m, whereas the variance of decreases as m increases.
Definition 1. For fixed , the process defined by for and for will be called a normalized variance gamma bridge.
We proceed to work out various properties of this process. We observe that
is conditionally Gaussian, from which it follows that
and
. Therefore
and
; and thus by use of (
28) we have
Now, recall (
Yor (
2007),
Emery and Yor (
2004)) that the gamma process and the associated gamma bridge have the following fundamental independence property. Define
Then, for every it holds that and are independent. In particular and are independent for and . It also holds that and are independent for and . Furthermore, we have:
Lemma 1. If and then and are independent.
Proof. We recall that if a random variable
X is normally distributed with mean
and variance
then
where
is defined by
Since
is conditionally Gaussian, by use of the tower property we find that
where the last line follows from the independence of
and
. □
By a straightforward extension of the argument we deduce that if and then and are independent. Further, we have:
Lemma 2. If and then and are independent.
Proof. We recall that the Brownian bridge
defined by
for
and
for
is Gaussian with
,
, and
for
. Using the tower property we find that
where in the final step we use (
30) along with properties of the Brownian bridge. □
A straightforward calculation shows that if
and
then
With this result at hand we obtain the following:
Theorem 2. The processes and are jointly Markov.
Proof. To establish the Markov property it suffices to show that for any bounded measurable function
, any
, and any
, we have
We present the proof for
. Thus we need to show that
As a consequence of (
38) we have
Therefore, it suffices to show that
Let us write
for the joint density of
. Then for the conditional density of
and
given
we have
Thus,
Similarly,
where for the conditional density of
and
given
we have
Note that the conditional probability densities that we introduce in formulae such as those above are “regular” conditional densities (
Williams 1991, p. 91). We shall show that
Writing
for the joint distribution function, we see that
where the last step follows as a consequence of Lemma 2. Thus we have
where the next to last step follows by virtue of the fact that
and
are independent for
and
. Similarly,
and hence
Thus we deduce that
and
and the theorem follows. □
5. Information Based Pricing
Now we are in a position to consider the valuation of a financial asset in the setting just discussed. One recalls that
is understood to be the risk-neutral measure and that the interest rate is constant. The payoff of the asset at time
T is taken to be an integrable random variable of the form
for some Borel function
h, where
is the information revealed at
T. The filtration is generated jointly by the variance-gamma information process
and the associated gamma bridge
. The value of the asset at time
is then given by the general expression (
2), which on account of Theorem 3 reduces in the present context to
and our goal is to work out this expectation explicitly.
Let us write
for the
a priori distribution function of
. Thus
and we have
Occasionally, it will be typographically convenient to write in place of , and similarly for other distribution functions. To proceed, we require the following:
Lemma 3. Let X be a random variable with distribution and let Y be a continuous random variable with distribution and density . Then for all for which we have where denotes the conditional distribution , and where Proof. For
any two random variables
X and
Y it holds that
Here we have used the fact that for each
there exists a Borel measurable function
such that
. Then for
we define
Hence
By symmetry, we have
from which it follows that we have the relation
Moving ahead, let us consider the measure
on
defined for each
by setting
for any
. Then
is absolutely continuous with respect to
. Indeed, suppose that
for some
. Now,
. But if
, then
, and hence
, and therefore
. Thus
vanishes for any
for which
vanishes. It follows by the Radon-Nikodym theorem that for each
there exists a density
such that
Note that
is determined uniquely apart from its values on
-null sets. Inserting (
73) into (
71) we obtain
and thus by Fubini’s theorem we have
It follows then that
is determined uniquely apart from its values on
-null sets, and we have
This relation holds quite generally and is symmetrical between
X and
Y. Indeed, we have not so far assumed that
Y is a continuous random variable. If
Y is, in fact, a continuous random variable, then its distribution function is absolutely continuous and admits a density
. In that case, (
76) can be written in the form
from which it follows that for each value of
x the conditional distribution function
is absolutely continuous and admits a density
such that
The desired result (
65) then follows from (
73) and (
78) if we observe that
and that concludes the proof. □
Armed with Lemma 3, we are in a position to work out the conditional expectation that leads to the asset price, and we obtain the following:
Theorem 4. The variance-gamma information-based price of a financial asset with payoff at time T is given for by Proof. To calculate the conditional expectation of
, we observe that
by the tower property, where the inner expectation takes the form
Here by Lemma 3 the conditional distribution function is
Therefore, the inner expectation in Equation (
81) is given by
But the right hand side of (
84) depends only on
and
. It follows immediately that
which translates into Equation (
80), and that concludes the proof. □
6. Examples
Going forward, we present some examples of variance-gamma information pricing for specific choices of (a) the payoff function
and (b) the distribution of the market factor
. In the figures, we display sample paths for the information processes and the corresponding prices. These paths are generated as follows. First, we simulate outcomes for the market factor
. Second, we simulate paths for the gamma process
over the interval
and an independent Brownian motion
. Third, we evaluate the variance gamma process
over the interval
by subordinating the Brownian motion with the gamma process, and we evaluate the resulting gamma bridge
. Fourth, we use these ingredients to construct sample paths of the information processes, where these processes are given as in Definition 2. Finally, we evaluate the pricing formula in Equation (
80) for each of the simulated paths and for each time step.
Example 1: Credit risky bond. We begin with the simplest case, that of a unit-principal credit-risky bond without recovery. We set
, with
and
, where
. Thus, we have
where
and
denotes the Dirac measure concentrated at the point
a, and we are led to the following:
Proposition 1. The variance-gamma information-based price of a unit-principal credit-risky discount bond with no recovery is given by Now let
denote the outcome of chance. By use of Equation (
57) one can check rather directly that if
= 1, then
, whereas if
= 0, then
. More explicitly, we find that
whereas
and the claimed limiting behaviour of the asset price follows by inspection. In
Figure 1 and
Figure 2 we plot sample paths for the information processes and price processes of credit risky bonds for various values of the information flow-rate parameter. One observes that for
the information processes diverge, thus distinguishing those bonds that default from those that do not, only towards the end of the relevant time frame; whereas for higher values of
the divergence occurs progressively earlier, and one sees a corresponding effect in the price processes. Thus, when the information flow rate is higher, the final outcome of the bond payment is anticipated earlier, and with greater certainty. Similar conclusions hold for the interpretation of
Figure 3 and
Figure 4.
Example 2: Random recovery. As a somewhat more sophisticated version of the previous example, we consider the case of a defaultable bond with random recovery. We shall work out the case where
and the market factor
takes the value
c with probability
and
is uniformly distributed over the interval
with probability
, where
. Thus, for the probability measure of
we have
and for the distribution function we obtain
The bond price at time
t is then obtained by working out the expression
and it should be evident that one can obtain a closed-form solution. To work this out in detail, it will be convenient to have an expression for the incomplete first moment of a normally-distributed random variable with mean
and variance
. Thus we set
and for convenience we set
Then we have
and of course
where
is defined by (
34). We also set
Finally, we obtain the following:
Proposition 2. The variance-gamma information-based price of a defaultable discount bond with a uniformly-distributed fraction of the principal paid on recovery is given bywhere Example 3: Lognormal payoff. Next we consider the case when the payoff of an asset at time
T is log-normally distributed. This will hold if
and
. It will be convenient to look at the slightly more general payoff obtained by setting
with
. If we recall the identity
which holds for
and
, a calculation gives
where
For
, the price is thus given in accordance with Theorem 4 by
Then clearly we have
and a calculation leads to the following:
Proposition 3. The variance-gamma information-based price of a financial asset with a log-normally distributed payoff such that is given for by More generally, one can consider the case of a so-called power-payoff derivative for which
where
is the payoff of the asset priced above in Proposition 3. See
Bouzianis and Hughston (
2019) for aspects of the theory of power-payoff derivatives. In the present case if we write
for the value of the power-payoff derivative at time
t, we find that
where
Example 4: Exponentially distributed payoff. Next we consider the case where the payoff is exponentially distributed. We let
, so
, and take
. A calculation shows that
where we set
and
As a consequence we obtain:
Proposition 4. The variance-gamma information-based price of a financial asset with an exponentially distributed payoff is given bywhere and are defined as in Example 2. 7. Conclusions
In the examples considered in the previous section, we have looked at the situation where there is a single market factor , which is revealed at time T, and where the single cash flow occurring at T depends on the outcome for . The value of a security with that cash flow is determined by the information available at time t. Given the Markov property of the extended information process it follows that there exists a function of three variables such that , and we have worked out this expression explicitly for a number of different cases, given in Examples 1–4. The general valuation formula is presented in Theorem 4.
It should be evident that once we have specified the functional dependence of the resulting asset prices on the extended information process, then we can back out values of the information process and the gamma bridge from the price data. So in that sense the process
is “visible” in the market, and can be inferred directly, at any time, from a suitable collection of prices. This means, in particular, that given the prices of a certain minimal collection of assets in the market, we can then work out the values of other assets in the market, such as derivatives. In the special case we have just been discussing, there is only a single market factor; but one can see at once that the ideas involved readily extend to the situation where there are multiple market factors and multiple cash flows, as one expects for general securities analysis, following the principles laid out in
Brody et al. (
2007,
2008a), where the merits and limitations of modelling in an information-based framework are discussed in some detail.
The potential advantages of working with the variance-gamma information process, rather than the highly tractable but more limited Brownian information process should be evident—these include the additional parametric freedom in the model, with more flexibility in the distributions of returns, but equally important, the scope for jumps. It comes as a pleasant surprise that the resulting formulae are to a large extent analytically explicit, but this is on account of the remarkable properties of the normalized variance-gamma bridge process that we have exploited in our constructions. Keep in mind that in the limit as the parameter
m goes to infinity our model reduces to that of the Brownian bridge information-based model considered in
Brody et al. (
2007,
2008a), which in turn contains the standard geometric Brownian motion model (and hence the Black-Scholes option pricing model) as a special case. In the case of a single market factor
, the distribution of the random variable
can be inferred by observing the current prices of derivatives for which the payoff is of the form
for
. The information flow-rate parameter
and the shape parameter
m can then be inferred from option prices. When multiple factors are involved, similar calibration methodologies are applicable.