2.1. First Generation of Empirical Studies
Although Maisel [
29] provides a description of builders of single-family housing in the USA, namely in the San Francisco area, and the factors that influence their construction decisions, in the literature on housing supply Muth [
30] is considered the first empirical study. Muth [
30] assumes a neoclassical-efficient-markets view of the housing market, where supply responsiveness is infinitely elastic in the long run. He develops a stock adjustment model and tests the relationship between the price and quantity of new housing construction. He is unable to reject the null hypothesis of a perfectly elastic supply. However, there are several problems with this analysis. One of the problems is the small sample: annual data from 1915 to 1934 and with the war years being omitted. Another critique is the fact that his estimation does not adjust for serial correlation or for the possibility of simultaneity bias between the price and quantity of new housing construction. Olsen [
19] also points out significant methodological problems, particularly on the issue of including both input prices and quantity in the reduced form model. Leeuw and Ekanem [
31] use a reduced-form model with information on rent differences among metropolitan areas in the USA to estimate the elasticity of the supply of rental housing. Using cross-sectional data, they estimate two equations and combine the results of the reduced form estimation with information from other studies on the parameters of the demand equation to draw conclusions about the behavior of the supply of housing services. They estimate an elasticity of supply from 0.3 to 0.7, suggesting that the supply of housing is inelastic. In addition, they suggest that diseconomies of scale are one of the sources of this inelasticity. Follain [
32] follows the formulation of Muth [
30]. He uses annual aggregated data from 1947 to 1975 and employs two measures of the quantity of new housing stock. He finds no significant positive relationship between quantity and price and concludes that the hypothesis of a perfectly elastic long-run supply of new construction cannot be rejected. Using quarterly data from 1955 to 1972 for the UK, Whitehead [
33] develops and estimates a series of related stock adjustment models. The results for the PES range from 0.5 to 2.
Another important and very complete study of the price elasticity of housing supply is Rydell [
34]. He examines the components of supply response to demand shifts. He argues that the supply of housing services available to consumers can increase in three ways: (i) existing housing can be upgraded by repair; (ii) the housing inventory can be expanded either by using existing residential land more intensely or by increasing the amount of residential land; (iii) the proportion of existing housing that is occupied can be increased. As such, the overall supply elasticity is a composite of these three components. His study supports the conclusion that the repair elasticity is very low, that the inventory elasticity is very large, and that the occupancy elasticity is greater than zero. Using cross-sectional data from 59 metropolitan areas in the USA, in the years 1974 and 1976 and considering a reduced form estimation, he estimates a long-run PES of 11.3. He finds that the short-run PES is lower (0.24 or 0.83), depending on the market occupancy rate.
The attempts to directly model housing supply in the 1980s come from the theoretical background of the investment literature. These models assume that the home-building industry is composed of competitive firms. Two reference studies are Poterba [
25] and Topel and Rosen [
26].
Poterba [
25] models the housing market using an asset approach and defines supply as net investment in structures. He assumes that investment supply depends on real house prices, the real price of alternative investment projects, and construction wage rates. To explain the impact of credit rationing he includes alternative indicators of credit availability. Knowing that houses take time to build, he uses one-quarter-ahead forecasts of real house prices and the real price of alternative investment projects. Since new houses take time to sell, he adjusts real house prices to reflect interest costs incurred during the period from completion to sale. He estimates various linear models using quarterly data from 1964 to 1982. Investment supply is measured as the value of one-family structures put in place or as a rate of new housing investment defined relative to aggregate real output. In the best-fitting models, the elasticity of the rate of new construction with respect to real house prices varies from 0.5 to 2.3. The author detects a significant relationship between credit availability and the rate of housing investment, supporting the “supply effect” hypothesis that credit availability affects the flow of new construction. The measures of construction costs, such as construction wage, produce unexpected signs and have no statistical significance.
Topel and Rosen [
26] study new housing supply by considering whether current asset prices are sufficient for housing investment decisions. If they are, then the short-run and long-run investment supplies are identical; if they are not, because of costs associated with moving resources between industries, then the short-run supply is less elastic than the long-run supply. As a result, builders and developers must anticipate future asset prices in making current construction decisions. They incorporate these supply dynamics by specifying the industry’s cost function in terms of both the level and the rate of change in construction, along with cost variables. They estimate a myopic model and then a model with expectations and internal adjustment costs. In their myopic model, production costs are unaffected by the rate of change in construction activity so current construction decisions are based solely on current asset price and marginal cost. If production costs are affected by the rate of change in construction activity, then internal adjustment costs are present and short-run supply is less elastic than long-run supply. These internal adjustment costs introduce expectations of future asset prices as determinants of new housing supply, since current prices by themselves fail to reflect all relevant information. Using quarterly data for 1963 through 1983, the authors estimate alternative versions of their myopic and internal adjustment cost models. They measure new housing investment as the number of single-family housing starts. The expected real interest rate, the expected inflation rate, the lags of these rates, and alternative measures of construction input prices are included as cost shifters. The number of months from start to sale for single-family homes is included as an indicator of market conditions. In both the myopic and adjustment cost frameworks, nominal interest rates influence construction activity, but construction costs have insignificant effects on housing investment. The myopic model generates new housing supply elasticities ranging from 1.2 to 1.4. They find that the short-run PES is lower (approximately 1). Their empirical results reject the myopic model in favor of the adjustment cost model. Supply elasticities are calculated to reveal the investment impact of both transitory and permanent housing price shocks. The presence of the time to sale variable considerably reduces the magnitude of the supply responses. For their preferred model, a permanent 1% rise in housing price increases housing investment by about 1.7% in the short run and 2.8% in the long run. However, nearly all the change in construction activity occurs within one year. As in Poterba [
25], their measures of construction costs do not have a significant impact on housing starts and the cost of capital to the builders is explained by real interest rates. They also conclude that real interest rates and expected inflation have a significant impact on housing starts. They argue that the impact of inflation is difficult to explain and that the magnitude of the coefficient on real interest rates is too big to just reflect the cost of capital. The authors also argue that the impact of inflation may reflect changes in the velocity at which houses are sold at market prices. To test this explanation, they put the median months on the market for new houses. Their results show a significant and negative impact of that variable on housing starts. But again, the effect is too big to reflect the holding costs related to sales delay.
Table 1 summarizes the earlier empirical studies, indicating the country, sample period, estimation method, whether the regression was estimated in levels or differences, and finally the estimates of the PES.
2.2. Second Generation of Empirical Studies (Contemporary)
The contributions from the investment literature, such as Poterba [
25] and Topel and Rosen [
26], do not consider the importance of land as an input. However, as we know from the literature on urban spatial theory, land is different from other factors of production. Urban spatial theory incorporates the land market in its theory and gives us equilibrium models in which the stock of houses always equals the urban population.
DiPasquale and Wheaton’s [
27] approach reflects the dynamic nature of housing supply by incorporating a stock adjustment process and a long-run equilibrium framework based on urban spatial theory. The latter theory implies that urban spatial growth generates higher land prices to attract the land necessary for new housing. By definition, the net change in the housing stock equals the difference between new construction and replacement investment. New construction in turn reflects how quickly the housing stock adjusts to its long-run equilibrium level. The long-run equilibrium housing stock depends on housing prices and input prices. This housing supply framework has two important implications for understanding the new housing supply. First, it implies that construction activity reflects the adjustment process as the current stock moves to its long-run equilibrium level. Second, it indicates that the housing price level affects new construction only to the extent that the current housing stock differs from its long-run equilibrium level for this price level. As such, changes in housing prices rather than their level attract the land necessary for long-run urban spatial growth. DiPasquale and Wheaton [
27] specify new construction (housing starts) as a linear function of new housing price, the short-term real interest rate (the real cost of short-term construction financing), the price of agricultural land, construction costs (indices for construction), and lagged housing stock. The change in aggregate employment and the number of months from completion to the sale for new homes are also introduced as indicators of housing market conditions. The authors estimate alternative linear versions of their supply framework using aggregate annual data from 1963 to 1990. They restrict the analysis to single-family housing and measure new construction as the number of single-family housing starts. In all specifications, the coefficient on housing price is significantly positive. Their estimates of the long-run PES range from 1.0 to 1.2. They conclude that the stock adjusts very slowly to its long-run equilibrium through new construction (the rate of adjustment is about 2% per year). On the other hand, real short-term interest rates have a significant negative impact on construction, whereas land costs do not have a significant impact. Just like Topel and Rosen [
26] and Poterba [
25], the authors did not find a significant relationship between construction costs and the level of construction. Following Topel and Rosen [
26], they add months on the market for new homes to the supply equation and they also find that sales time has a large impact on construction. They argue that the magnitude of the coefficients of sales delays and interest costs is too large, and that the importance of those variables indicates that price is not enough to explain housing starts. They also argue that the magnitude of the coefficient appears to be too large to simply reflect holding costs associated with sales delays. They include, as a market indicator, the change in employment, a variable that has a positive impact on construction. Adding this variable and the sales time to the model improved its fit. Lastly, the authors present strong evidence of a gradual price adjustment process in the market for single-family housing in contrast to previous studies that made assumptions of instantaneous market clearing. Their results confirm the idea that the housing market functioning is very different from other financial asset markets.
Blackley [
35] uses annual data from the USA for the period 1950 to 1994. The basic model expresses residential construction as a linear function of new housing prices, the prices of construction materials and labor, the real interest rate, and the expected inflation rates. He also considers the effects of land price, lagged housing stock and the price of nonresidential construction. The variables are expressed in levels. The first conclusion is that the new housing supply is relatively price-elastic in the long run. Estimates of the long-run price elasticity of new housing supply range from 1.6 to 3.7. However, in the models with variables expressed in differences, the long-run elasticity is lower, about 0.8. The second conclusion is that nominal interest rates influence the new housing supply directly. Lastly, the temporal properties of each data series should be considered when specifying and estimating time-series models of new housing supply; for example, with variables expressed in levels, supply is elastic, but with explanatory variables expressed in differences, supply is inelastic.
A great majority of the studies that try to estimate the supply concentrates on the problem of single-family housing starts, but DiPasquale and Wheaton [
36] study the problem of the supply of multifamily housing. They estimate a construction equation for multifamily rental housing where the level of multifamily construction, measured by the units in structures with more than one unit, depends on how the asset price of rental housing compares with construction costs. Asset prices are a function of rents, vacancies, and the capitalization rate. The estimated model explains variation in construction with rents, vacancies, the capitalization rate, construction costs, lagged construction, and construction by the federal government of the USA. With this model, they estimate a long run rent elasticity of supply of 6.8. The construction costs are statistically significant and have the expected negative sign.
Using quarterly data at Ireland’s national level, Kenny [
37] estimated a unit price elasticity of supply, concluding that the Irish housing supply is less elastic than the housing supply in other countries. Wang et al. [
38] used data from China, from 1998 to 2009, showing that the Chinese price elasticity of house supply lies between 2.8 and 5.6. Chow and Niu [
39] use a simultaneous equations model, for the study of both the demand and the supply of residential housing in China. The data is annual from 1987 to 2012. The supply of housing is explained by the cost of construction and by the relative prices. They conclude that the PES is approximately 0.5. In their paper, Levin and Pryce [
40] work out the UK market. They give a great contribution to the problem of the price elasticity of supply, first by demonstrating that it varies over time due to changes in real interest rates. They conclude that increases in the long-run real interest rates lead to house price rises and a low elasticity of supply, this in the absence of restrictive regulation and market imperfections. They also consider how some market imperfections can interact with planning constraints and building regulations to form the response of supply to price changes. They argue that these may lead to cyclical asymmetry in the price elasticity of supply, that is, the propensity for the quantity supplied to respond very slowly to outward shifts of demand, but very rapidly to inward shifts.
In their model, Mayer and Somerville [
28] incorporate the time taken in the development process. In addition, they use more recent time series econometrics methods. One of the differences between this model relative to DiPasquale and Wheaton [
27] is that they use price and cost changes and not their levels. They argue that housing starts is a flow variable so it should be a function of flow variables. Consequently, they use lagged price changes and lagged cost changes in their model. The results of this model are a price elasticity of housing starts of about 6.0 and a low-price elasticity of the stock of about 0.08. They justify that difference by saying that the low-price elasticity of the stock is due to the fact that housing starts are a small percentage of the stock. They also find that changes in construction costs are not statistically significant, and that time to sales is statistically significant with a large coefficient, which means that time to sales has a significant impact on construction.
Malpezzi and Maclennan [
41] estimate the PES of housing for the USA and the UK. Using a long time series for both countries, they split the sample between prewar and postwar years. The results for the PES reveal greater values for the USA in comparison with the UK, concluding that the USA market is more elastic. Moreover, the values of PES are higher in the prewar period both in the USA and the UK. Ball et al. [
42] argue that different spatial scales reveal different aspects of the problem. Therefore, they conclude that there is a need for comparing different scales: international, national, local and firm levels. Their study includes an econometric comparison of Britain and the USA/Australia with comparable data sets in order to see if the price elasticities of supply are different, or if the difference arises from the model specification. Their results show that the elasticity of housing supply with respect to the change in prices is larger in the USA than in Britain, supporting that this is not a question of methodology. Their results show that the elasticity of housing supply with respect to the change in prices is greater than the levels elasticity. The local data indicate that the supply elasticities vary a lot and are related to the topology, planning policy, and land-use patterns. The results of the model of supply constructed on firm-level data show great differences in the behavior of the bigger firms from the global market. The largest firms are more responsive to changes in market conditions. The authors argue that there is evidence that the responsiveness of housing supply to market conditions is lower in Britain than in the USA or Australia.
Somerville [
43] uses USA data for three metropolitan areas and first introduces micro-data on housing construction costs, discussing the relation between the supply of new housing and the cost of construction in the USA. He estimates a long-run PES from 5.61 to 14.76. He argues that there is an incorrect measure of labor costs in the literature, and he finds that there is a strong and negative relationship between housing starts and construction costs. Follain et al. [
44] use quarterly data for four metropolitan areas in the USA. Their econometric model estimates a short-run elasticity between 1 and 2, and a long-run elasticity between 3 and 5. The long-run price elasticity is aligned with other papers that used national data for the USA. Harter-Dreiman [
45] estimates a two-equation vector error correction system and uses panel data. The unit observation is the Metropolitan Statistical Area (MSA), annual data from 76 MSA for the period 1980 to 1998 in the USA. The results indicate an elastic long-run supply function, with a supply elasticity from 1.8 to 3.2, depending on the assumptions about the income and the price elasticities of demand. Green et al. [
46] estimate supply elasticities for 45 metropolitan areas in the USA, following the model of Mayer and Somerville [
28]. They conclude that the estimates of the PES vary significantly according to the metropolitan area. Metropolitan areas that are strongly regulated show low elasticities, while metropolitan areas that are less regulated show a wider range. In particular, metropolitan areas with low regulation and with fast growth tend to have high price elasticities, whereas those with slow growth have low-price elasticities. They also conclude that population density is an important variable in explaining supply elasticity and that metropolitan areas with high population density have lower elasticities. Hwang and Quigley [
47] analyze USA metropolitan areas, considering annual data from 1987 to 1999. They model new housing supply as a function of changes in prices, input costs and macroeconomic conditions, following Mayer and Somerville [
28]. The estimated PES is very small, from 0.01 to 0.09, but highly significant. Saiz [
48] estimate the PES for the USA, using a time series for the metro areas with a population greater than 500,000. The estimates range from 0.6 to 5.45. They conclude also that housing supply elasticities can be characterized as functions of both physical constrains and regulatory constraints. This is one of the more recent considerations of physical constrains in the estimation of PES. The author concludes that areas that are inelastic are in fact land-constrained by the topography. Aastveit et al. [
49] use quarterly data for a panel of 254 USA metropolitan areas, between 1996 and 2017, and consider a single-equation approach. This recent study concludes that the local supply elasticities in the USA have fallen in recent years, namely since 2012. This implies that the price responsiveness to a demand shock can be very high in current days and the increase in quantity should be smaller. Ihlanfeldt and Mayock [
50] estimate the supply elasticity with local data from Florida—USA, using panel data of stocks and housing prices for 63 of Florida’s 67 counties and consider supply stock-adjustment models like DiPasquale and Wheaton [
27]. They obtain an average short-run price elasticity of 2, with a maximum of 8.
Pryce [
51] uses data from England, at a local district level, and considers a simultaneous equation model of housing construction. The model compares elasticities of supply between two cross-sectional periods, a boom in 1988 and a slump in 1992. The paper discusses rationality and tests the existence of a backward-bending supply relationship. He concludes that supply is concave in both periods and that it bends backward during the boom period. The author finds a structural break between the boom and the bust period - the elasticity of supply is higher in the slump period (1.03) and smaller in the boom (0.58) -, but he concludes that there are considerable variations across districts. Wang et al. [
38] study also the 35 major cities in China and conclude that the significant determinants of the variation in the PES are a geographical constraint, average built-up urban area, the rate of population growth, and restrictions on land use. Accetturo et al. [
52], using data from 40 years for more than one hundred Italian cities, bring one of the more relevant recent studies in Europe. The authors estimate a PES of 0.12. This PES is lower in Europe compared with the USA, which is evidence from earlier and from more recent work on the field. We know that the current rigidities in housing supply in European cities derive from historical landmarks. Saiz [
48] concludes also that land use restrictions and other government regulations have a big impact: the regulations lower the PES. Accetturo et al. [
52] used physical constraints instead of land regulation as determinants of the PES. In more recent years a considerable number of studies used geographical constraints instead of land regulations with a lot of success; in fact, geographical constraints are positively correlated with land regulation.
Malpezzi and Mayo [
53] indicate that there are significant differences in supply elasticities between countries. They argue that those differences seem to be correlated with the stringency of the regulatory framework in place for land and housing developers. Goodman [
54] also says that supply conditions vary within a country. Meen [
55] states that, in comparison with the USA, the price elasticities of supply in England are low and that England’s price elasticities of supply have been falling since 1970. He concludes that the PES is low in all regions of England (price elasticities are approximately 0 since 1990 in all of them). He argues that it is difficult to incorporate information about planning controls into the time-series models, although that may partially explain the results as Malpezzi and Mayo [
53] state. By introducing dummy variables, the paper concludes that there are additional factors that explain the low PES.
The comparative analysis provided by the two generations of models that can be performed comparing
Table 1 and
Table 2 prove that the estimate of the long-run PES of housing varies considerably across studies. However, excluding some earlier studies like Muth [
30] and Follain [
32], we can reject a perfectly elastic supply of housing, and we can conclude that at least in the long-run supply is elastic with respect to price. Another conclusion that can be extracted across studies is that the PES of housing varies at a regional and a local level. There are several studies that conducted this analysis and draw the same conclusion. We can state that the short-run PES is lower than the long-run PES. We can also state that the results vary with the econometric models used and with the specification. For example, the use of variables in differences seems to lead to lower values in the long-run PES of housing. Lastly, there is evidence of significant differences in supply elasticities between countries. We can conclude also from recent studies that the PES of housing is higher in the USA than in the UK.
2.3. Determinants of Housing Supply
In the last two subsections, empirical studies were systematically analyzed. In this subsection the regressors of the housing supply models are summarized. However, it is worthwhile to summarize the various categories of explanatory variables that were used as well as the results that have been obtained. This will give us an overall picture of the results from the existing empirical evidence.
The set of explanatory variables and the results regarding their impact on housing supply have varied across studies. Classifying the regressors into eight categories,
Table 3 shows selected references that include in their study that category of regressors.
As we can see by the number of references in
Table 3, the most common regressors are those related to financing costs and construction costs.
To have a clearer view of the sign and significance of the regressors classified in the same category in
Table 3,
Table 4 summarizes the number of papers where each regressor is statistically significant, with positive or negative impact, and the number of papers where each regressor is not statistically significant.
In the category of financing costs, which includes the interest rate in various forms, almost all empirical studies conclude that the cost of financing negatively influences the housing starts. This result is consistent with theory.
Theoretically, construction costs should be an important determinant of housing supply and should have a negative sign, reflecting the negative relation between housing starts and construction costs. However,
Table 4 shows that the results for the category of construction costs (which include material costs, wage costs, or an index of both) are inconclusive. Although the expected negative impact is attained in seven papers, five papers show a positive impact and in three other papers construction costs are not statistically significant. As DiPasquale [
21] refers, most of the empirical literature on housing supply faces the problem of construction cost measurement. Thus, one possible explanation for the inconclusive results is the quality of the data used to measure these costs. It is interesting to note that studies that use more disaggregated data, such as Somerville [
43], conclude that the variable has a significant and negative impact on housing supply.
The vacancy rate appears in only a few papers, being included in two papers as a regressor. One of these papers finds a negative impact, in accordance with theory, while the other paper finds out that the variable is not statistically significant. Sales delay is included only in four papers. However, its impact on housing supply is negative and statistically significant in three papers reviewed, which is theoretically consistent: if the houses take a very long time to sell, the consequence is fewer housing starts. It is also worthwhile to note that the magnitude of the impact of sales delay is quite big in the papers that include this variable. The three papers that include the inflation rate as a regressor show a significant and negative effect on housing starts, which is also consistent with theory. The evidence regarding the impact of the stock of housing (normally with a lag) on housing starts is inconclusive: three papers reveal a negative impact, two papers show a non-significant impact, and one paper finds a positive impact. Similarly, the effect of the price of agricultural land is also not clear, as the three papers that include this variable reach completely different results.
In the category of regulation we included the planning controls, which are used in five papers. The reason why this type of regressor is not used more often is probably related to the lack of information, since it is difficult to have a time series of this variable. In theory, when the regulatory controls are more restrictive there are fewer housing starts, hence the sign of the coefficient should be negative. Four of the five papers that include regulation show the expected theoretical result, whereas in one paper the variable is not statistically significant. It is important to mention that Green et al. [
46] conclude that metropolitan areas that were more regulated have lower PES. In some of the more recent papers, like Accetturo et al. [
52] and Saiz [
48], physical constraints are used instead of land regulation as a determinant of PES, this regressor is statistically significant and has the expected negative sign.
2.4. Strategic Interaction Models
In the previous subsections, we revised the empirical literature on housing supply. However, within the housing supply literature there are other studies that we would like to highlight. We also review the application of game theory and industrial organization to model housing supply. Unfortunately, as we will show, there are very few studies in this area.
One of the most important applications of game theory to the housing market is Baudewyns [
56]. This paper focuses on the strategic interactions of land developers in an imperfectly competitive market, analyzing the decisions made by two land developers that decide two variables independently: price and quality. He assumes that one firm is in the Central Business District (CBD) and builds houses in this location while the other builds in a more decentralized area. In the first stage the duopolists choose the level of housing quality, where the quality is defined as a function of accessibility and housing quality. In the second stage, the two firms simultaneously compete in prices to attract potential clients. The author concludes that the decentralized developer can adopt two kinds of strategies depending on the distance and the anticipated level of quality at the CBD. If the centralized land developer offers high-quality apartments, then the decentralized developer offers low-quality housing units in the CBD. The decentralized developer’s reasoning is to differentiate its residential quality to soften price competition in the second stage. In the suburban areas, it offers a higher quality of housing, but the residential quality is lower, because of the transportation costs. Another important paper on housing supply examines the home-building industry and its structure. Somerville [
57] states that his paper is the first analytical treatment of the industrial organization of housing supply. He says that traditional studies of housing markets assume that house building is a perfectly competitive industry. Metropolitan area level data on the average size of homebuilder firms and homebuilder market concentration is used to analyze the market structure of the industry. The author concludes that there is a systematic variation across metropolitan areas in the housing market. This variation occurs in the average size of builders and the market share for the largest builders. Hence, he argues that the results are more consistent with treating the industry as monopolistically competitive. He also concludes that homebuilders are larger in more active housing markets, and they are also larger where there is a bigger supply of developed land adequate for larger developments. The author argues that the type of regulating jurisdiction that establishes land-use regulation has an influence on the builder size and market concentration. Wang and Zhou [
58] study one well-documented problem in the real-estate markets literature: the excess vacancy or overbuilding in the market. They model overbuilding as a two-stage infinite-horizon non-cooperative game between land developers. In the first stage, each developer simultaneously and independently decides to build a certain number of real properties to meet the demand level. In the second stage, given the available supply and demand of the market, developers select the optimal rental price for their properties. They conclude that it is natural to observe oversupply in real-estate markets, since developers have the incentive to build once they find a development opportunity. Therefore, developers as a whole will supply more houses into the market than the level of demand. After the oversupply, developers will stop building until demand absorbs the existing supply. Their model explains the long-lasting overbuilding in real-estate markets without some traditional explanations such as agency costs, irrational behavior, or uncertainty of demand.
Ball [
59] examines the way that the housebuilding industry is organized and tries to identify some implications for the wider operation of housing markets. He argues that there are several characteristics of the industry that seem to reject the idea of a competitive industry. First, there are different institutional forms within and across countries, and housebuilding industrial structures vary considerably. Second, firms adopt strategies, and they know, from experience, that they are important in determining profit. The author states that strategic behavior cannot have an effect on market outcomes in a competitive model. The paper analyzes potential economies of scale, market factors, information asymmetries, regulation, and risk. He argues that the great variety of ways in which housing is built is not the reason that explains its industrial organization. Factors like market instability, locational specificity, the markets where the houses are sold, information, strategic behavior, regulation in labor markets, land availability, and the regulation, affect the size of firms. He also states that strategic behavior is important in this industry, particularly through behavior regarding the land market and residential development strategies.
Ong et al. [
60] apply a game theoretic Nash equilibrium approach to the issue of planning flexibility within land use zoning. The paper is based on the land use planning in Singapore and focuses on the “white sites” program in that country. They claim that flexibility in land use may be valuable, but it potentially introduces a supply inefficiency through uncertainty in the development decision-making process. The main proposition is that interaction between developers of proximate sites may result in a suboptimal supply situation. They demonstrate that a first-mover advantage exists such that subsequent “white sites” released shortly after the first “white sites” are likely to fetch lower land prices.
Chu and Sing [
61] incorporate strategic interaction in the modeling of optimal timing decisions for real-estate development projects. They examine the subgame perfect equilibrium strategies for a duopoly real option model, with two firms with asymmetric demand functions. Facing preemptive threats, firms may forgo the waiting options, and invest earlier than what the monopolistic real option models would predict. In their symmetric duopoly model, firms are identical, and products are homogeneous. Thus, there are no relative advantages in the price function of the first mover over the next one. Short bursts and recession-induced overbuilding are two outcomes in this paper. The model predicts that these two phenomena occur in earlier phases of market cycles, and not in the state of recession. In a market in recession with high volatility, the two firms will choose the waiting strategies. Costa and Samanez [
62] apply a mathematical model based on game theory and real options. The basic idea is to have a balance between the supply and demand of houses in Rio de Janeiro (Brazil), considering the effect on the price of the houses and on the attitude of competitors in the market. Using the cost and price parameters of the properties, the model determines the optimal investment strategy. The strategy depends on the relationship between the sale price and construction cost for each investor, and the number of active competitors in the market. LaCour-Little and Yang [
63] analyze mortgage products and construct a game theory model of contract choice with uncertain future income and house prices. The results show that deferred amortization contracts are most likely to be chosen in the housing markets with greater price appreciation and by households with a higher tolerance for risk.
Mu and Ma [
64] analyze the price decision of land and housing, starting from a model that is composed of a land developer, a real estate developer, and the government. They discuss the equilibrium solutions in a cooperative game and in a non-cooperative game. The results show that cooperation is the optimal strategy and that regulating the tax rate can be an efficient way for the government to increase profit while decreasing the house prices to have social stability. Yue et al. [
65] apply a game theoretical model to explain the housing price in Hong Kong. They have a different approach, since they consider that the housing market in Hong Kong is oligopolistic. They present a game with a windfall tax and a game without a windfall tax. In the game without windfall tax, the high land price policy is the result of the Hong Kong market. If the government wants to lower the house price in the market, the suggestion is that they enforce a windfall tax. However, they indicate that there are limitations in the applications of game theory to the housing market, especially in Hong Kong. They state that the pricing strategies are very dependent on specific environmental factors. Another limitation is that the interactions between the government and property developers are very complex and unpredictable.
Samsura et al. [
66] study the utility and the limitations of game theory for the analysis and for the prediction of the behavior of the actors in the decision-making process, with regard to the development of land. The paper shows that game theory is useful for identifying strategic land development decisions, showing the different payoffs to stakeholders for their strategies, and selecting the equilibrium where all are better off.
The analysis of the papers that use game theory and industrial organization models applied to the housing market shows that the strategic interaction between land developers is still understudied. We consider that this new branch of the literature can provide an important theoretical contribution to the housing supply and, thus, there is a huge potential in exploring this type of model.