Next Article in Journal
Low Carbon-Oriented Optimal Reliability Design with Interval Product Failure Analysis and Grey Correlation Analysis
Next Article in Special Issue
Analysis of Potential Rockfalls on a Highway at High Slopes in Cold-Arid Areas (Northwest Xinjiang, China)
Previous Article in Journal
On-Grid Solar PV versus Diesel Electricity Generation in Sub-Saharan Africa: Economics and GHG Emissions
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Managing Reputational Risk through Environmental Management and Reporting: An Options Theory Approach

by
Juan Pineiro-Chousa
1,
Marcos Vizcaíno-González
2,*,
María Ángeles López-Cabarcos
1 and
Noelia Romero-Castro
1
1
SVCO Research Group, Universidade de Santiago de Compostela, Santiago de Compostela 15782, Spain
2
Department of Financial Economics and Accounting, Universidade da Coruña, A Coruña 15071, Spain
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2017, 9(3), 376; https://doi.org/10.3390/su9030376
Submission received: 17 January 2017 / Revised: 14 February 2017 / Accepted: 27 February 2017 / Published: 4 March 2017
(This article belongs to the Collection Risk Assessment and Management)

Abstract

:
Reputation is a complex and multidimensional concept that may be organized in downside and upside reputational risk. In this article, we present a formal modelling for the management capabilities of environmental management and reporting over reputational risk, considering that reputational risk is becoming increasingly important for organizations and it directly depends on the information available about companies’ environmental performances. As long as the effectiveness of communication and disclosure plays a key role in the process, the usefulness of environmental management and reporting as a hedging instrument for reputational risk is addressed through different levels of information transparency. When considering a scenario of voluntary reporting, we show that environmentally concerned companies can reduce the cost of environmental management as a reputational risk strategy, as well as reducing the potential loss of reputational value from reputational threats and increasing the potential profit from reputational opportunities. In the context of mandatory reporting, we highlight the role of assurance companies as bearers of the risk of bad reputations for non-concerned companies. As a result, this novel approach applies theoretical oriented research from options theory to reputational risk management literature, so that it benefits from the option’s well known theory, robustness, and conclusions.

1. Introduction

Reputation is a complex and multidimensional concept [1] that, following the study of Reference [2], may be organized in downside and upside reputational risk. On the other hand, there is a growing political and academic interest in the use of information as a quasi-regulatory mechanism and its relation to organizational reputation [3,4,5], with the recent case of Volkswagen being a prominent one [6]. In this context, companies must be prepared to increase their reporting of non-financial information and to manage the impact of this information provision on their reputation. Environmental management can be defined as a set of corporate decisions and actions that aim to develop, deploy, execute, and control the corporate environmental policy. Environmental management is presented in this paper as a specific tool for reputational risk hedging, assuming that environmental management influences corporate reputation and customers’ satisfaction [7,8]. It is also assumed that for this idea to be true, environmental management has to improve corporate environmental performance and that this has to be effectively communicated to society, either directly (through company reporting and public relations) or indirectly (through governments and media coverage).
We developed a formal modelling to address the hedging capabilities of environmental management and reporting over reputational risk, using the flexibility granted by the options theory to consider different levels of information transparency. When considering a scenario of voluntary reporting, we show that environmentally concerned companies can reduce the cost of environmental management as a reputational risk strategy, as well as reduce the potential loss of reputational value from reputational threats and increase the potential profit from reputational opportunities. In the context of mandatory reporting, we highlight the role of assurance companies as bearers of the risk of bad reputations for non-concerned companies.
The rest of the manuscript is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the relation between environmental management and corporate reputation, pointing out how environmental reporting mediates in this relation. Section 3 presents the method and formalizes the hedging role of good and bad environmental practices over reputational risk using results from the options theory. Section 4 elaborates on the hedging capabilities of environmental management over reputational risk along different levels of information transparency. Finally, Section 5 concludes and outlines recommendations for future research.

2. Environmental Management as a Driver of Corporate Reputation: The Importance of Environmental Reporting

Environmental performance is related to corporate reputation and customers’ satisfaction [7,8], and normally it can be expected that bad environmental performers will be penalised with a bad reputation and that good environmental performers will be rewarded with a good reputation [9]. In this context, and assuming that environmental management leads to improved environmental performance [10], environmental management can be thought of as a specific tool for reputational risk management.
It is possible that environmental management in itself can contribute to the improvement of corporate reputation if some signalling option is in use, for example, certification [11]. Yet, obviously, as long as reputation depends on the information available and public perception, the effect of environmental management on reputation will be mediated by the reporting efforts of the company and other institutions (such as governments or mass media), as well as by how these efforts are perceived by the public. There is a risk that environmental reporting can be understood as green-washing [12]. In fact, some studies have examined the level and nature of the environmental information voluntarily disclosed by firms and found that they may not be indicative of their underlying environmental performance [13], pointing to the need to establish some mandatory framework to promote environmental reporting and even its assurance. The use of environmental disclosure or, more generally, Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) disclosure to acquire greater legitimacy has already been analysed and considered as a long-term investment in reputation [14,15]; some authors even point out that corporate reputation can be more influenced by what companies report than by what they actually do [9].
If corporate environmental management and reporting have an impact on corporate reputation, the regulatory authorities could promote the use of information about the environmental performance of companies as an environmental policy instrument. In this sense, Arora and Gangopadhyay [16] conclude that the public image of a company is a key driving force of voluntary over-compliance with environmental regulations. Additionally, Caplan [3] considers that under certain circumstances polluting firms self-regulate by internalizing the forward effect of their environmental reputation, and Banerjee and Shogren [17] advance that firms concerned about their reputation would exert at least the optimal level of effort in environmental protection. Johnstone and Labonne [11] consider that the environmental management area is characterized by strong information asymmetries, as its quality is not readily observable. The requirement to disclose information on the environmental performance of companies is a vehicle that environmental regulation could use in order to reduce these information asymmetries [5], encouraging stakeholders to exercise disciplinary pressure on the behaviour of firms. Mitchell [18] acknowledges also that disclosure-based policies can influence corporate behaviour, making targeted actors aware of their own behaviours and moving them to alter these behaviours in positive ways prior to (and independent of) the public disclosure process itself.
The relation between environmental performance and environmental reporting has also been studied, although offering mixed results depending on the theory applied to explain managerial behaviour [13]. In this paper, we adopt the perspective of the voluntary disclosure theory, which predicts that firms with superior environmental performance will have incentives to disclose in order to differentiate themselves. In addition, even in a mandatory reporting context, firms with better environmental records (measured by toxic emissions) have higher levels of environmental disclosures [19]. However, nowadays a credibility gap is acknowledged regarding sustainability reports, and assurance can play a valuable role in helping to ensure that the environmental information provided is reliable and credible. The concept of assurance includes not only reports verification, but also advice on environmental performance, corporate governance, stakeholder engagement, and other areas central to corporate responsibility, with the aim of reinforcing the credibility and quality of corporate sustainability strategies. The assurance market is a competitive and mainly unregulated market with various types of assurance suppliers from inside and outside the accounting profession [20], and it has two principal reference standards which try to ensure the quality of the assurance work: the International Standard on Assurance Engagement (lSAE) 3000, and the Account-Ability 1000 Assurance Standard (AA 1000AS). However, some individual countries’ accounting authorities have also issued specific standards for the auditing of sustainability reports. We refer to the work of Manetti and Becatti [21] to examine some critical points of present assurance services on sustainability reports, as well as a number of suggested improvements for future assurance standards. Ackers, Eccles, and Parker [22] state also that voluntary CSR assurance has resulted in the inconsistent application of CSR assurance practices, and argue that this deficiency may be overcome through the imposition of a mandatory CSR assurance regime. Furthermore, assurance is acquiring importance in the context of the expanding use of integrated reporting, which needs specific assurance standards for reports that combine financial and non-financial information.

3. An Options Theory Approach to Reputational Risk Hedging Through Environmental Management

3.1. Methods

Since the proposal of the Black-Scholes equation to calculate the premium of a European option [23], the method originally conceived for valuing financial options has been widely used for the analysis of different managerial decisions, including corporate valuation [24,25,26], investment projects [27,28,29,30], research and development [31,32], and budgeting [33].
Indeed, the options theory framework has already been applied in the fields of corporate social responsibility [34] and risk management [35], with some recent results related to reputational risk [36,37]. Thus, and following a similar approach, this article elaborates on a novel theoretical analysis of environmental management as a hedging instrument over reputational risk, considering that the options theory provides the flexibility needed in order to capture its varying hedging capability through different levels of information transparency. The valuation of the corporate reputation offered by the market will be represented by S . Consequently, considering that corporate reputation can be understood as an underlying asset, the value of which needs to be protected, and given that environmental management can be thought of as a hedging instrument over that underlying asset, we will be denoting the result of this reputational risk management strategy with V. The company that wants to get the protection has to pay a premium in terms of effort in environmental management. Moreover, this effort gives the company the right to reach a certain level of reputational valuation. From that strike valuation level onwards, the option results are activated and the company gets a reputational payoff.
For clarity purposes, in order to understand how the protection offered by environmental management works and to determine the reputational result of this hedging strategy, the companies will be classified into two different groups: companies whose reputational risk is actively managed through environmental management (these ones will be called A-companies) and companies whose reputational risk is not actively managed through environmental management (these ones will be referred to as B-companies). The A-companies and the B-companies are the agents involved in the formalization of the environmental management hedging capabilities, and this formalization has two dimensions depending on whether the market rewards good environmental management practices or penalizes bad environmental management practices: In the first case, companies develop environmental management to take advantage of reputational opportunities in order to build a good reputation; and in the second case, companies invest in environmental management in order to protect against reputational threats and avoid a bad reputation.

3.2. Environmental Management as an Option to Build a Good Reputation

Regarding the first dimension, the A-companies invest in environmental management in order to build a good reputation. On the other side, the B-companies, which do not carry out environmental management, are not prepared to react in the appropriate manner when reputational opportunities arise, so the potential reputational advantages of these opportunities will be lost. From this point of view, it can be stated that the A-companies are buying the chance to get positive reputational consequences and build a good reputation, that is, they are taking a long position in a call contract over the underlying asset of corporate reputation. On the other side, as B-companies are wasting reputational opportunities in favour of A-companies, it can be affirmed that they are selling the chance of building a good reputation for A-companies, that is, they are taking the complementary short position in that call contract over the corporate reputation asset. The long and short positions of the call contract are presented in Figure 1 [38].
The option gets activated when the valuation of the corporate reputation offered by the market is above the valuation level that the A-companies have the right to get according to the investment in environmental management quantified through the premium. This valuation level corresponds to the strike price of the option and is represented by K . If the market is especially sensitive to good environmental management practices and offers a high valuation of good environmental management, the A-companies have complete interest in disclosing their environmental commitment in order to get the reputational reward in terms of this higher valuation. Otherwise, if the market offers a low valuation of these good environmental management practices, the A-companies get a null reputational result from their investment in environmental management. The premium of the call contract that collects the investment in environmental management carried out by the A-companies depends on the valuation of corporate reputation offered by the market, as well as the volatility over that valuation. Thus, the environmental management effort demanded of the company from the market is larger when the market offers a bigger reward to good environmental management practices, or when the volatility observed in the market around that valuation increases. On the other hand, if the market does not offer a high valuation of good environmental management practices or the volatility around this valuation is small, the required amount of investment in environmental management decreases. While the valuation of good environmental management practices gets higher, the A-companies get a bigger reputational reward that compensates the initial effort quantified through the premium, and the A-companies are driven to a region of potentially unlimited reputational profits. Otherwise, if the market does not reward good environmental management practices, the A-companies lose the investment represented by the premium, this quantity being the limit of their potential loss. The reputational result for B-companies is the opposite of the reputational result for A-companies. Thus, when the market offers a high valuation of good environmental management practices, the B-companies do not get the reputational reward and suffer a reputational loss in terms of the opportunity cost related to the wasted reputational opportunities. On the other hand, when the market does not reward good environmental management practices, the B-companies get the benefit corresponding to the premium invested by the A-companies. Given that this is an investment that the B-companies do not accomplish, it can be considered as a minor cost for them, so compared with the A-companies, the B-companies have a benefit in terms of the free funds corresponding to the non-undertaken investment in environmental management, and this is the only potential benefit that they could accomplish [38].
Consequently, the call contract can be summarized by stating that it is a hedging instrument over the underlying asset of corporate reputation. When the reputational opportunities arise, the A-companies are in position of taking advantage of them, so their reputation improves. On the other hand, the B-companies have no chance to achieve the positive reputational consequences of those opportunities, so their reputation turns out to be poor compared with the reputation held by the A-companies. Thus, there is a transfer of good reputation in favour of the A-companies and to the detriment of the B-companies. It can be stated that the A-companies have the right to buy or get good reputation through the activation of the option, and when this occurs the B-companies have the obligation to sell and relinquish a good reputation.

3.3. Environmental Management as an Option to Avoid a Bad Reputation

Regarding the second dimension of the environmental management strategy, which comprises the protection against damages derived from reputational threats, the A-companies invest in environmental management in order to get far away from a bad reputation. Meanwhile, the B-companies do not accomplish this investment, so when reputational threats show up (for instance, in the regulatory demand of disclosure of information on environmental performance) they are not ready to respond in a suitable way (they cannot communicate a good environmental performance), and they cannot avoid the reputational damage. From this point of view, it can be stated that the A-companies are buying the chance to sell the negative consequences of reputational threats and avoid a bad reputation, that is, they are taking a long position in a put contract over the underlying asset of corporate reputation. On the other side, if the B-companies are suffering damage from reputational threats, it can be said that they are buying the bad reputation that the A-companies are selling, that is, they are taking the complementary short position in that put contract over the corporate reputation asset. The long and short positions are presented in Figure 2 [38].
The option gets activated when the valuation of bad environmental management practices derived from the market is below the strike valuation level that the A-companies have the right to reach, according to their investment in environmental management. If the market is especially sensitive to bad environmental management practices and reacts by penalizing them by offering a low reputational valuation, the A-companies will disclose their environmental commitment in order to avoid this reputational penalty and get the correct reputational valuation according to their reputational effort. Otherwise, if the market does not penalize bad environmental management practices and offers a high valuation of bad reputations, the A-companies get a null reputational result from their investment in environmental management. The premium of the put contract, which represents the investment carried out by A-companies in environmental management in order to protect against reputational threats and avoid a bad reputation, depends on the valuation of bad environmental management practices offered by the market, and on the volatility over that valuation. The reputational effort demanded by the company from the market in order to avoid the reputational damage related to bad environmental management practices is larger when the market offers a low valuation of them, that is, when the reputational penalty imposed by the market is higher, or when the volatility observed in the market valuation of bad environmental management practices increases. On the other hand, if the market does not offer a poor valuation of bad environmental management practices, or the volatility around this valuation is small, the amount of investment in environmental management required to avoid reputational damages decreases. While the valuation of bad environmental management practices gets lower, the A-companies avoid more severe reputational damage, and this profit in terms of the non-suffered reputational loss compensates for the initial effort quantified through the premium, driving the A-companies to a region of potentially unlimited reputational profits (by avoiding potentially unlimited reputational losses). Otherwise, if the market does not penalize bad environmental management practices, the A-companies lose the investment in avoiding the reputational damage represented by the premium, this quantity being the limit of their potential loss. The reputational result for the B-companies is the opposite of the reputational result for A-companies. Thus, when the market offers a low valuation of bad environmental management practices, the B-companies suffer the reputational damage and get the subsequent reputational loss. On the other hand, when the market does not penalize bad environmental management practices, the B-companies get the benefit corresponding to the premium invested by the A-companies in avoiding reputational damage. Once again, it can be considered as a minor cost for the B-companies, because compared with the A-companies they have a benefit in terms of the non-accomplished investment in environmental management, and this is the only potential benefit that they could accomplish [38].
Consequently, the put contract can be summarized by stating that it is another hedging instrument over the underlying asset of corporate reputation. When the reputational threats arise, the A-companies are in position of getting protection against them, so their reputational valuations do not suffer. On the other hand, the B-companies have no chance to avoid the negative reputational consequences of those threats, so their reputation turns out to be poor when compared with the reputation held by the A-companies. Thus, there is a transfer of bad reputation from the A-companies to the B-companies. It can be stated that the A-companies have the right to sell or get rid of a bad reputation through the activation of the option, and when this occurs the B-companies have the obligation to buy or get a bad reputation.
To sum up, the two dimensions of environmental management described above (to foster a good reputation or to avoid a bad reputation), it can be said that there is a bidirectional reputational flow between the companies in the market, where the A-companies have the right to get the good reputational consequences derived from reputational opportunities that the B-companies lose through a call contract, and simultaneously the A-companies have the right to avoid the bad reputational consequences derived from reputational threats that the B-companies are suffering through a put contract (Figure 3).

4. Consideration of Different Levels of Information Transparency

Due to the relevant role of communication in reputational risk management, and considering that the success of the communication process is directly related to the presence of information asymmetries, it seems appropriate to study the hedging capabilities of environmental management through different levels of information transparency. In fact, there are a few studies that have highlighted the connection between reputational risk and asymmetric information [39].

4.1. Adverse Selection due to Information Asymmetries

Starting by considering a context with asymmetry in the available information, the phenomenon of adverse selection arises [40], and the market cannot distinguish good reputations from bad reputations. That way, an average valuation is offered: The good environmental management practices do not get the correct reputational reward and become undervalued, while the bad environmental management practices do not suffer any reputational penalty and get overvalued. This means that the call and put contracts named above are both negotiated at the same strike valuation level. So, the A-companies have a long call position and a long put position both with the same strike valuation level, that is, the A-companies take a long straddle position. Meanwhile, the B-companies have the opposite schema: a short call position and a short put position both with the same strike valuation level, that is, B-companies take a short straddle position. The long and short positions of a straddle are presented in Figure 4 [41].
Thus, the A-companies will choose to activate the call contract if the market begins to be especially prone to good environmental management practices in order to get the reputational reward, and alternatively they will choose to activate the put contract if the market starts to be particularly sensitive to bad environmental management practices in order to avoid the reputational penalty. So, the environmental management value gets higher while the market increases its reward for good environmental management practices, or increases its penalty for bad environmental management practices. If the market does not opt for any of the two directions described above, either rewarding good environmental management practices or penalizing bad environmental management practices, the A-companies cannot use any of the options, and while this situation persists they are losing the amount compromised in environmental management through the premiums. But the options are still there, in a sleeping state, ready to be used when the situation requires the activation of one of them. When this arises, the A-companies are guided to a region of potentially unlimited reputational profits, thus compensating for the initial effort. The reputational result for the B-companies is the opposite of the reputational result held by the A-companies. This means that the B-companies only get a reputational profit in terms of the non-undertaken environmental management effort when the market remains immune to environmental management practices, either positive or negative. However, when the market changes this behaviour, the B-companies enter a region of potentially unlimited reputational losses, either by the reputational opportunity cost derived from the call contract, or by the reputational damage derived from the put contract [41].
If the situation of adverse selection persists, the growing lack of confidence that the market has will lead to a continuous decrease in the valuation offered. The A-companies would be driven out of the market by the B-companies, because their environmental management effort has few chances of being correctly recognized, rewarded, and compensated by the market. That is why the A-companies have an interest in informing the market about their environmental management commitment, fighting against adverse selection. In this way, the principle of full disclosure or unravelling result gets established [42,43]. According to this principle, under ideal conditions a company cannot hide significant information on its own reputational valuation from the market. In fact, the lack of disclosure can be interpreted as bad news by the market. However, the reality of the financial markets does not support the full disclosure principle, and partial disclosure equilibriums (or even no disclosure equilibriums) are usual. The reasons why companies do not communicate all significant information to the market and why investors do not succeed in discovering this lack of corporate transparency are explained by Caby and Piñeiro [44].

4.2. Voluntary Disclosure

Following the idea initially proposed by Fama [45], different types of efficiency can be identified in the market—weak, semi-strong, and strong—in order to explain how information is factored in prices. Similarly, in an environmental management and reporting context, different degrees of transparency or disclosure can be identified: low, medium and high. In these disclosure scenarios, the market anticipates that the communicative companies are those that invest in environmental management (A-companies) and, as a consequence, the non-communicative ones are the ones that do not invest in environmental management (B-companies). So, the market has a new information source that allows market members to differentiate good environmental management practices from bad environmental management practices, and this phenomenon leads to a new situation where the value of the reputations related to good practices increases, while the value of the reputations related to bad practices decreases. This means that the call and the put contracts do not have the same strike valuation level anymore: the call contract has a higher strike valuation level than the put contract. Furthermore, the difference between these two strike valuation levels is directly related to the degree of disclosure, that is, as long as the degree of disclosure gets higher that difference increases and the two strike valuation levels become increasingly distant from each other. As a consequence, the previous straddle scenario has evolved into a new strangle schema, where the long position is taken by the A-companies and the short position is taken by the B-companies. The long and short positions of a strangle are presented in Figure 5 [41].
Now the A-companies are in a better situation than before, because the market pays more attention to their environmental management commitment and offers a better valuation for it. Both premiums decrease compared with the previous scenario. This means that the quantity of the environmental management effort carried out by the A-companies is lower, because the market is more sensitive to environmental issues, so the investment in environmental management is better recognized and achieving a reputational profit is slightly easier. As a result, the A-companies have evolved into a position characterized by lower cost, lower maximum loss, and higher maximum profit than in the previous situation. Consequently, the B-companies are exposed to a lower maximum profit and a higher maximum loss [46].

4.3. Mandatory Reporting

Extending the analysis, a different scenario arises if environmental disclosure is no longer a voluntary activity and becomes mandatory, so that the companies have the need to protect themselves against potential damages derived from reputational threats through assurance of the reported environmental information, assuming that public confidence in environmental information may be enhanced by the reputational capital associated with the purchase of assurance [47], and that the risk of a bad reputation is transferred to the assurance company. In this situation, the presence of assurance breaks the bidirectional flow between the A-companies and the B-companies previously described. There is still a transfer of good reputational consequences derived from reputational opportunities in favour of the A-companies and to the detriment of the B-companies. However now, the bad reputational consequences derived from reputational threats are transferred from both the A-companies and the B-companies to the assurance companies (Figure 6).
Regarding the A-companies, there are no substantial changes from the previous situation and they are still holding a long strangle position. However, two slight differences concerning the put contract have to be pointed out: First, the premium of the put contract (that corresponded to the investment in environmental management and reporting in order to avoid the negative consequences of reputational threats) is now equal to the assurance fee that the A-companies pay; and second, the counterpart of the A-companies in this put contract is now the assurance companies.
On the other hand, the scenario for the B-companies is completely different. Choosing not to invest in environmental management and reporting is not an alternative anymore. The B-companies are required to carry out a primary reputational risk hedging strategy, consisting of managing the second dimension of reputational risk, that is, the one concerning the protection against reputational threats. This means that the B-companies are now holding a long position in a put contract, where the counterparts are the assurance companies. However, given that the first dimension (the one regarding taking advantage of reputational opportunities) is still not managed, they keep holding the short position in the call contract where the A-companies are taking the long position. This means that the B-companies are combining a long put position with a short call position, resulting in a short combo hedging strategy. The double counterpart of the B-companies, constituted by the A-companies and the assurance companies, holds the complementary long combo position. The short and long positions of the combo strategy are presented in Figure 7 [41].
In this situation, the B-companies are protected against reputational threats, but they are not prepared yet to exploit reputational opportunities. When reputational threats arise, the put option is activated and the B-companies get the reputational protection derived from the assurance contract, so the value of this strategy turns out to be positive. However, when there are reputational opportunities wasted by the B-companies, the value of this strategy is negative due to the opportunity cost in terms of the non-conquered reputational profit derived from those opportunities. The investment accomplished by the B-companies is the assurance fee that corresponds to the premium of the put contract, but it is compensated for by the non-undertaken investment in environmental management, which relates to the reputational opportunities that correspond to the premium of the call contract. Consequently, an interesting fact arises, because this reputational investment can be either positive or negative, depending on which of the two premiums is greater. Thus, it is positive when the assurance fee dominates, but becomes negative when the environmental management effort demanded by the market from the A-companies in order to earn positive reputational consequences derived from reputational opportunities (which is collected in the call premium) increases [41].
In this scenario, when the premise of mandatory environmental reporting is assimilated by the market after a certain time of maturity, the attitude towards bad environmental management practices changes because all potential reputational damages are covered by assurance. This means that there is no need for maintaining two different valuation schemas for good environmental management practices and for bad environmental management practices. From now on, a unique valuation schema is offered. As a consequence, the two strike valuation levels are no longer different. Consequently, the call contract and the put contract have the same strike valuation level. As a result, the A-companies return to the initial long straddle scenario, which means that the cost and the maximum loss increases and the maximum profit decreases, as a consequence of higher demands from a market that is increasingly concerned with environmental issues. On the other hand, the B-companies are holding a long put position and a short call position, as in the previous situation, but now they are valuated at the same strike valuation level. So, the hedging strategy carried out by the B-companies is transformed into a short synthetic future. The double counterpart of the B-companies, integrated by the A-companies and assurance companies, holds the complementary long synthetic future. The short and long positions of a synthetic future are presented in Figure 8 [38].
The value of this reputational risk management strategy for B-companies is positive when the market valuation of corporate reputations is below the strike valuation level that the company has the right to get, that is, when corporate reputation is underestimated and, as a consequence, there is a reputational loss that activates the protection offered by assurance. On the other hand, when the market valuation of the corporate reputation is above the strike valuation level that these companies have the right to get, this means that the market is rewarding good environmental management practices and the valuation offered is the one that the B-companies would get if they were not wasting reputational opportunities. Consequently, there is a reputational opportunity cost that explains the negative value of the reputational risk hedging strategy in this scenario. As in the previous situation, the effort of the B-companies is the assurance fee that corresponds to the premium of the put contract, which is compensated for by the premium of the call contract that represents the non-undertaken investment in detecting reputational opportunities. Once more, this reputational investment can be either positive or negative [38].

5. Conclusions

The main objective of this essay has been proposing a formal modelling for the hedging capabilities of environmental management and reporting over reputational risk. The review of previous literature on the relationship between environmental management and reputation has revealed that some important issues mediate in this relationship: environmental reporting, its voluntary or mandatory nature, and the need of assurance. Consequently, the link between environmental management and reputation can be analysed under different levels of transparency.
The options theory has been proposed as a convenient methodology due to its flexibility that allows the consideration of different levels of information asymmetry and several scenarios, showing that environmental management acts like a hedging instrument over the company’s reputation, contributing to the achievement of its objectives. When considering a scenario of voluntary reporting, we show that the environmentally concerned companies can reduce the cost of environmental management as a reputational risk strategy, as well as reduce the potential loss of reputational value from reputational threats and increase the potential profit from reputational opportunities. In the context of mandatory reporting, we have highlighted the role of assurance companies as bearers of the risk of bad reputations for non-concerned companies, to the extent that assurance companies get involved both in the design and implementation of their client’s sustainability strategies as well as in the verification of their sustainability reports. Table 1 summarizes the main findings for companies concerned with environmental management and reporting along with the different scenarios covered in the study.
In addition, Table 2 summarizes the main findings for non-concerned companies along the different scenarios:
Given that reputational risk is becoming increasingly important for companies, the corporate management field could benefit from this paper’s contributions, taking them as a starting point to reach a full integration of environmental management into corporate management as a reputational risk hedging strategy. Moreover, the proposed methodological framework would help to reduce the overall exposure of a company to reputational risk and, therefore, it would positively contribute to the shareholder value creation. This is also a contribution to the academic field, as there is an absence of studies that analyse the issue of “whether or not it pays to be green” that consider the intermediate variables that influence the performance links, such as reputation [8]. Consequently, there is an open avenue for further research to empirically examine the link between companies’ reputations and their corporate value, as well as to develop an empirical investigation of this paper’s theoretical propositions. From an academic perspective, this paper also advances the literature by integrating the consideration of environmental management, environmental reporting, and reputational risk under the framework provided by the options theory, something that to our knowledge has not been done yet. Finally, we have reviewed the concerns regarding the reliability of voluntary environmental disclosures, which signal a need for both enhanced mandatory reporting requirements and improved enforcement [13], and also for assurance of CSR information. Consequently, policy makers could also find our framework useful to analyse the suitability of incentives for environmental disclosures, or the need for a mandatory disclosure, to promote corporate environmental behaviour, which might imply a less active and costly role for the regulating authorities [3]. More concretely, national governments across the European Union that are having to transpose to their regulatory framework in accordance with the recent Directive on non-financial information disclosure, need to carefully analyse the implications of voluntary and mandatory reporting as well as the role of assurance, and could base such analysis on this paper’s contributions. As a final recommendation, corporate and public policies, as well as academic fields could take into account this paper’s contributions as a starting point to justify the need for demanding greater transparency and assurance on the environmental performance of companies, and the convenience of developing further research on the relationship between environmental management and reputational risk.

Acknowledgments

The authors thank the editors and anonymous referees who commented on this article.

Author Contributions

All of the authors contributed significantly to the completion of this manuscript, conceiving and designing the research and writing, and improving the paper. All authors have read and approved the manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Pineiro-Chousa, J.; Vizcaíno-González, M.; López-Cabarcos, M. Reputation, Game Theory and Entrepreneurial Sustainability. Sustainability 2016, 8, 1196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Comeig, I.; Holt, C.A.; Jaramillo-Gutiérrez, A. Dealing with Risk: Gender, Stakes, and Probability Effects; University of Valencia, ERI-CES: Valencia, Spain, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  3. Caplan, A.J. Reputation and the control of pollution. Ecol. Econ. 2003, 47, 197–212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Tietenberg, T.; Wheeler, D. Empowering the community: Information strategies for pollution control. Front. Environ. Econ. 2001, 1, 85–120. [Google Scholar]
  5. Cañón-de-Francia, J.; Garcés-Ayerbe, C.; Ramírez-Alesón, M. Analysis of the effectiveness of the first European Pollutant Emission Register (EPER). Ecol. Econ. 2008, 67, 83–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Siano, A.; Vollero, A.; Conte, F.; Amabile, S. “More than words”: Expanding the taxonomy of greenwashing after the Volkswagen scandal. J. Bus. Res. 2017, 71, 27–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Surroca, J.; Tribó, J.A.; Waddock, S. Corporate responsibility and financial performance: The role of intangible resources. Strateg. Manag. J. 2010, 31, 463–490. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  8. Tang, A.K.; Lai, K.; Cheng, T. Environmental governance of enterprises and their economic upshot through corporate reputation and customer satisfaction. Bus. Strateg. Environ. 2012, 21, 401–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Cho, C.H.; Guidry, R.P.; Hageman, A.M.; Patten, D.M. Do actions speak louder than words? An empirical investigation of corporate environmental reputation. Account. Organ. Soc. 2012, 37, 14–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. King, A.A.; Lenox, M.J.; Terlaak, A. The strategic use of decentralized institutions: Exploring certification with the ISO 14001 management standard. Acad. Manag. J. 2005, 48, 1091–1106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Johnstone, N.; Labonne, J. Why do manufacturing facilities introduce environmental management systems? Improving and/or signaling performance. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 68, 719–730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Lyon, T.P.; Maxwell, J.W. Greenwash: Corporate environmental disclosure under threat of audit. J. Econ. Manag. Strateg. 2011, 20, 3–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Clarkson, P.M.; Overell, M.B.; Chapple, L. Environmental reporting and its relation to corporate environmental performance. Abacus 2011, 47, 27–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Hassan, A.; Ibrahim, E. Corporate environmental information disclosure: Factors influencing companies’ success in attaining environmental awards. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2012, 19, 32–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Nikolaeva, R.; Bicho, M. The role of institutional and reputational factors in the voluntary adoption of corporate social responsibility reporting standards. J. Acad. Mark. Sci. 2011, 39, 136–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Arora, S.; Gangopadhyay, S. Toward a theoretical model of voluntary overcompliance. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 1995, 28, 289–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Banerjee, P.; Shogren, J.F. Regulation, reputation, and environmental risk. Econ. Lett. 2010, 106, 45–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Mitchell, R.B. Transparency for governance: The mechanisms and effectiveness of disclosure-based and education-based transparency policies. Ecol. Econ. 2011, 70, 1882–1890. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Clarkson, P.M.; Li, Y.; Richardson, G.D.; Vasvari, F.P. Revisiting the relation between environmental performance and environmental disclosure: An empirical analysis. Account. Organ. Soc. 2008, 33, 303–327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Cohen, J.R.; Simnett, R. CSR and Assurance Services: A Research Agenda. Audit. A J. Pract. Theory 2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Manetti, G.; Becatti, L. Assurance services for sustainability reports: Standards and empirical evidence. J. Bus. Ethics 2009, 87, 289–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Ackers, B.; Eccles, N.S.; Parker, L. Mandatory corporate social responsibility assurance practices: The case of King III in South Africa. Account. Audit. Account. J. 2015, 28, 515–550. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Black, F.; Scholes, M. The pricing of options and corporate liabilities. J. Polit. Econ. 1973, 81, 637–654. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Koller, T.; Goedhart, M.; Wessels, D. Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  25. Copeland, T.; Koller, T.; Murrin, J. Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies; Wiley: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  26. Sanchez, R. Strategic flexibility in product competition. Strateg. Manag. J. 1995, 16, 135–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Abel, A.B.; Dixit, A.K.; Eberly, J.C.; Pindyck, R.S. Options, the value of capital, and investment. Q. J. Econ. 1996, 111, 753–777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Copeland, T.; Antikarov, V. Real Options; Texere: New York, NY, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  29. Trigeorgis, L. Real Options: Managerial Flexibility and Strategy Inresource Allocation; The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  30. Dixit, A.K. Investment under Uncertainty; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  31. Eckhause, J.M.; Hughes, D.R.; Gabriel, S.A. Evaluating real options for mitigating technical risk in public sector R&D acquisitions. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2009, 27, 365–377. [Google Scholar]
  32. Schneider, M.; Tejeda, M.; Dondi, G.; Herzog, F.; Keel, S.; Geering, H. Making real options work for practitioners: A generic model for valuing R&D projects. R&D Manag. 2008, 38, 85–106. [Google Scholar]
  33. Costa, A.; Paixão, J.M. An approximate solution approach for a scenario-based capital budgeting model. Comput. Manag. Sci. 2010, 7, 337–353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Husted, B.W. Risk management, real options, corporate social responsibility. J. Bus. Ethics 2005, 60, 175–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Cruz, M.G. Modeling, Measuring and Hedging Operational Risk; John Wiley & Sons: New York, NY, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  36. Pineiro-Chousa, J.; Vizcaíno-González, M. A quantum derivation of a reputational risk premium. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2016, 47, 304–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Vizcaíno-González, M. Riesgo de reputación: Revision teórica y aproximación a su valoración. Revista Galega de Economía 2010, 19, 199–216. [Google Scholar]
  38. Hull, J.C. Options, Futures, and Other Derivatives; Pearson: Essex, UK, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  39. Scandizzo, S. A framework for the analysis of reputational risk. J. Oper. Risk 2011, 6, 41–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Akerlof, G.A. The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q. J. Econ. 1970, 84, 488–500. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Cohen, G. The Bible of Options Strategies: The Definitive Guide for Practical Trading Strategies; Pearson: Upper Saddle River, NJ, USA, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  42. Grossman, S.J. The informational role of warranties and private disclosure about product quality. J. Law Econ. 1981, 24, 461–483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Milgrom, P.R. Good news and bad news: Representation theorems and applications. Bell J. Econ. 1981, 12, 380–391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Caby, J.; Pineiro-Chousa, J. Voluntary disclosure of non-financial information and corporate social responsibility. In Coporate Social Responsibility, Volume I: Concept, Accountability and Reporting; Allouche, J., Ed.; Palgrave McMillan: Basingstoke, UK, 2006; Volume 1, pp. 205–218. [Google Scholar]
  45. Fama, E.F. Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work. J. Financ. 1970, 25, 383–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Poitras, G. Risk Management, Speculation, and Derivative securities; Elsevier: San Diego, CA, USA, 2002. [Google Scholar]
  47. Simnett, R.; Nugent, M.; Huggins, A.L. Developing an international assurance standard on greenhouse gas statements. Account. Horiz. 2009, 23, 347–363. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Environmental management as an option to get reputational opportunities.
Figure 1. Environmental management as an option to get reputational opportunities.
Sustainability 09 00376 g001
Figure 2. Environmental management as an option to avoid reputational threats.
Figure 2. Environmental management as an option to avoid reputational threats.
Sustainability 09 00376 g002
Figure 3. Bidirectional reputational flow between A-companies and B-companies.
Figure 3. Bidirectional reputational flow between A-companies and B-companies.
Sustainability 09 00376 g003
Figure 4. Hedging reputational risk in an adverse selection scenario.
Figure 4. Hedging reputational risk in an adverse selection scenario.
Sustainability 09 00376 g004
Figure 5. Hedging reputational risk in a voluntary disclosure scenario.
Figure 5. Hedging reputational risk in a voluntary disclosure scenario.
Sustainability 09 00376 g005
Figure 6. Reputational flows in a mandatory reporting scenario.
Figure 6. Reputational flows in a mandatory reporting scenario.
Sustainability 09 00376 g006
Figure 7. Hedging reputational risk in a mandatory reporting scenario.
Figure 7. Hedging reputational risk in a mandatory reporting scenario.
Sustainability 09 00376 g007
Figure 8. Hedging reputational risk in a mature mandatory reporting scenario.
Figure 8. Hedging reputational risk in a mature mandatory reporting scenario.
Sustainability 09 00376 g008
Table 1. Summary for concerned companies.
Table 1. Summary for concerned companies.
ScenarioCorporate Environmental Attitude (Strategy)Environmental Practices Valuation (Strike)Net Environmental Effort (Premium)Max. Reputational Loss (Max. Risk)Max. Reputational Profit (Max. Reward)
Information asymmetriesLong straddleGood = BadLowLowHigh
Voluntary disclosureLong strangleGood ≠ BadVery lowVery lowVery high
Mandatory reportingLong strangleGood ≠ BadVery lowVery lowVery high
Mature mandatory reportingLong straddleGood = BadLowLowHigh
Table 2. Summary for non-concerned companies.
Table 2. Summary for non-concerned companies.
ScenarioCorporate Environmental Attitude (Strategy)Environmental Practices Valuation (Strike)Net Environmental Effort (Premium)Max. Reputational Loss (Max. risk)Max. Reputational Profit (Max. Reward)
Information asymmetriesShort straddleGood = BadLow negativeHighLow
Voluntary disclosureShort strangleGood ≠ BadVery low negativeVery highVery low
Mandatory reportingShort comboGood ≠ BadAround zeroVery highVery high
Mature mandatory reportingShort synthetic futureGood = BadAround zeroHighHigh

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Pineiro-Chousa, J.; Vizcaíno-González, M.; López-Cabarcos, M.Á.; Romero-Castro, N. Managing Reputational Risk through Environmental Management and Reporting: An Options Theory Approach. Sustainability 2017, 9, 376. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9030376

AMA Style

Pineiro-Chousa J, Vizcaíno-González M, López-Cabarcos MÁ, Romero-Castro N. Managing Reputational Risk through Environmental Management and Reporting: An Options Theory Approach. Sustainability. 2017; 9(3):376. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9030376

Chicago/Turabian Style

Pineiro-Chousa, Juan, Marcos Vizcaíno-González, María Ángeles López-Cabarcos, and Noelia Romero-Castro. 2017. "Managing Reputational Risk through Environmental Management and Reporting: An Options Theory Approach" Sustainability 9, no. 3: 376. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9030376

APA Style

Pineiro-Chousa, J., Vizcaíno-González, M., López-Cabarcos, M. Á., & Romero-Castro, N. (2017). Managing Reputational Risk through Environmental Management and Reporting: An Options Theory Approach. Sustainability, 9(3), 376. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9030376

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop