Next Article in Journal
Shipyard Manpower Digital Recruitment: A Data-Driven Approach for Norwegian Stakeholders
Previous Article in Journal
State-Dependent Phillips Curve
Previous Article in Special Issue
Interrelationship and Volatility Dynamics Among the Seven Main NYSE Mineral ETFs
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Identification and Visualization of Clusters Using Network Theory Methods: The Case of the Greek Production System

by
Dimitris Foutakis
Department of Surveying and Geoinformatics Engineering (Serres), International Hellenic University, 62124 Serres, Greece
Economies 2025, 13(1), 15; https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13010015
Submission received: 2 December 2024 / Revised: 24 December 2024 / Accepted: 27 December 2024 / Published: 11 January 2025

Abstract

:
The interest in clusters in the economy and regional space, which has persisted for nearly three decades, has reignited the understanding of the economy as a system of interdependencies between industries. Although the concept of clusters can be traced back to contributions dating from the early 20th century, they have become a central focus of regional development policies in recent decades, as they have been linked to enhancements of innovation, the knowledge economy, and ultimately, territorial competitiveness. Arguably, the most effective and comprehensive way to present the systemic nature of the economy is through input–output tables. The main feature of these tables, on which this work is based, is that they describe the relationships and flows between industries (or products) during the production process. These fundamental relationships among the industries in the production system are depicted in the inter-industry (and intra-industry) transaction matrix of an economy’s input–output tables. To analyze these relationships, we use network theory, in the context of which the transaction matrix can be seen as the adjacency matrix of a directed, weighted graph (or network) with loops. In this study, clusters are identified for the case of Greece, using two different approaches based on the modularity of the network, utilizing the 2010 input–output tables for this country. As a result, five clusters of industries that structure the country’s production system across 62 industries are identified, which are also presented through graphical visualizations.

1. Introduction

The aim of this article is to present a method for identifying and visualizing clusters, using the production system of Greece as a case study. Although the concept of clusters appeared in economic theory as “industrial districts” (Marshall, 1890/1964, Chapter 10) as early as the late 19th century (1890), it re-emerged in work by Porter (1998) and others at the end of the 20th century with a rather ambiguous content.1 However, the geographical level of reference remains unclear: it could refer to a neighborhood in a metropolitan area, a region (however defined), a country, or even groups of countries (Martin & Sunley, 2003). Furthermore, ambiguity exists regarding the types of industries involved, whether they are similar or complementary, as well as the nature of their relationships. Despite these uncertainties, clusters are considered crucial elements of regional policy within various versions of new regionalism (Amin & Thrift, 1995; Amin, 1999; Cook, 2002; Cook & Morgan, 1998; Florida, 1995; Morgan & Nauwelaers, 1999; Morgan, 1997; Storper, 1997), as they are seen as key drivers for promoting innovation, the “knowledge economy”, and ultimately, the competitiveness of regions and countries.
Regardless of any conceptual ambiguities or weaknesses, the discussion regarding clusters brings to the forefront the issue of the division of labor and the interdependent nature of economic activity. In this regard, the overall economic activity functions as a system of interdependent, separate economic activities carried out by independent economic units linked through exchange relationships, either as inputs or as outputs of intermediate or final goods, means of production, or services. The intensity of these relationships is not uniformly distributed among industries but tends to concentrate around specific industries or groups of industries and has a dynamic and changing character. The geographical scale of industries’ concentration, which is addressed by contemporary cluster theory, remains an open research question.
In this paper, a methodological approach for identifying and visualizing clusters is first presented. Then, in Section 3, this approach is applied, using Greece as a case study, based on the analysis of the transaction matrix from the 2010 Greek input–output tables (Eurostat, 2013), using tools from graph/network theory. In this section, the results of applying this methodology are also presented, which leads to the identification of five clusters in the Greek production system. Section 4 features a detailed discussion about the composition and internal function of these clusters, and the paper then proceeds to Section 5.2

2. Method for the Identification and Visualization of Clusters, and Data Handling

2.1. Identification of Clusters

Identifying subdivisions or clusters within a network (graph) is both conceptually and computationally complex, with numerous methods and algorithms proposed for solving this problem (Fortunato, 2010). In the context of input–output tables, the existence of functional subdivisions has been known about since the 1950s and 1960s (see Leontief, 1986), taking forms such as strategic industries, industry hierarchies, or cohesive groupings (clusters).3 The methodological approach of this study views the input–output table as a graph (or network), a perspective that aligns with a scientific trend from the early 2000s, which established network science as a separate field focused on real-world networks (social, technological, biological, cognitive) (Newman, 2010; Barabási, 2014).4
The transaction matrix of the input–output table is treated as the adjacency matrix of a directed, weighted network (with or without loops), allowing the use of the network’s topological characteristics and associated quantitative data (weights of links). This framework enables the identification of subgroups or clusters based on the transactions between industries. The search for cohesive structures within a complex network, described by a matrix or graph, is a problem in matrix and graph theory, which is known as partitioning. The goal is to divide the adjacency matrix into submatrices (subgraphs) in a way that minimizes the links between them, forming groupings with more internal links (edges) than external ones.
This problem is very challenging to solve practically, even in its simplest form, which is the bisection (splitting into two equal parts) of a graph. In this seemingly straightforward case, the graph, i.e., its corresponding adjacency matrix, must be divided into two subgraphs (submatrices) with an equal number of nodes (vertices). However, the number of possible ways to bisect the graph is approximately 2(n+1)/√n, where n is the number of nodes/vertices (Newman, 2010, p. 359; Barabási, 2014, Chapter 9, pp. 8–9). This means that the number of solutions increases exponentially with the increase in the number of nodes of the graph, with the result being that when the number of nodes of the graph exceeds a few dozen, finding and evaluating solutions is computationally infeasible in practice. If the number of divisions is not predetermined, the number of possible solutions increases even faster than exponentially, as described by the Bell number, which approximates the number of partitions (Barabási, 2014, Chapter 9, p. 9; Fortunato, 2010, p. 87).
There are numerous approaches to solving the problem of network division and numerous corresponding algorithms, as detailed in an extensive review by Fortunato (2010). The large number of methods and algorithms can be attributed not only to the computational complexity of the problem—being NP-hard, which undoubtedly contributes to the development of many algorithms—but also to the inherent ambiguity in defining what constitutes a cohesive subgroup. This ambiguity leads to multiple, sometimes slightly varied definitions and terms being used to describe the same phenomenon (or ontology). In the literature, terms such as graph partitioning, modules, clusters, and communities are used interchangeably or alternatively (Newman, 2010; Fortunato, 2010; Fortunato & Castellano, 2012; Barabási, 2014). The term “communities” is the most recent and is often preferred in approaches that identify substructures without predefining the number or other characteristics of these subgroups.
The algorithms developed from such an approach emerged primarily during the early 2000s, driven significantly by the involvement of physicists in the field. These “physicists entered the game, bringing in their tools and techniques: spin models, optimization, percolation, random walks, synchronization, etc., became ingredients of new original algorithms” (Fortunato & Castellano, 2012, p. 492). In contrast, earlier algorithms, which relied on the prior specification of certain parameters for the subdivisions of a graph or network under study, were primarily the result of research within the domain of social network analysis (Wasserman & Faust, 1994; Scott, 2000). K-means clustering and hierarchical clustering are the most commonly used algorithms in social network analysis. The first has the serious limitation that the number of clusters to be formed must be specified in advance. The second does not have this limitation but “it does not provide any a way to discriminate between the many partitions obtained by the procedure, and to choose that or those that better represent the community structure of the graph” (Fortunato & Castellano, 2012, p. 498).
This differentiation among algorithms enables an initial classification of the various approaches based on a seemingly “technical” criterion. Specifically, these methods are divided into (a) those that predetermine the number of partitions or the size of the groupings (number of nodes) to be formed, or the degree centrality (number of edges or links) for each node in the subgraphs created, and (b) those that partition the graph without any prior specification of the number, size, or other characteristics of the subdivisions (Newman, 2010, pp. 354–358).
The first class of methods rely on a framework of assumptions or a model regarding the graph’s structure, expressed through parameters that define the number and features of the partitions. In contrast, the second approach does not make any assumptions about the graph’s structure or the number or size of its cohesive structures and relies solely on the graph’s inherent data, producing a solution (or solutions) by optimizing an evaluation index derived from comparisons with a “null model”. This null model is a random graph that maintains certain structural characteristics of the graph under study (Fortunato, 2010, p. 86).5 It is crucial to note that in both approaches, partitioning is based solely on topological features.
This second method uses an index called the network modularity, which compares the links (edges) within each subgroup (cluster/community) in a proposed partition to the number expected if the network was random (Newman & Girvan, 2004). Mathematically, modularity quantifies this comparison (Fortunato & Castellano, 2012, p. 493; Barabási, 2014, Chapter 9, p. 20) as follows:
Q = c = 1 n c l c m d c 2 m 2
where nc is the total number of subgroups, lc is the number of edges within subgroup c, m is the total number of edges in the network, and dc is the total degree of the nodes within the same subgroup c. This mathematical formulation clarifies that modularity depends on the difference between two quantities: the first is the ratio of the edges within a subgroup to the total number of edges in the network, and the second is the ratio of the expected edges within the same subgroup to the total number of edges in the network, assuming that the network’s nodes are randomly connected but retain their original degree.
In this study, the method of maximizing modularity is used to identify clusters within Greece’s production system. Despite having some disadvantages, this method has a significant advantage: it does not require any preconceived judgment or assumption about the network’s structure. This is unlike many established methods from social network analysis and hierarchical clustering, which depend on such assumptions.
However, this method is not without its problems: (a) it misclassifies subgroups that are smaller than a certain resolution limit, as it cannot distinguish them from the null model (Fortunato & Castellano, 2012, p. 501), and (b) rather than having a single optimal maximum, there is often a range of near-optimal solutions forming a plateau instead of a unique peak (Barabási, 2014, Chapter 9, p. 24). Nevertheless, algorithms based on modularity maximization are generally trusted by the scientific community and it is considered that “modularity offers a first principle understanding of a network’s community structure” (Barabási, 2014, Chapter 9, p. 24).
Modularity always takes values less than one. Positive values (Q > 0) indicate a good partition, with higher values representing better results. A value of zero (Q = 0) means there is no significant clustering, while negative values (Q < 0) imply that the random graph’s internal connections are better than those of the given subdivision, indicating an unacceptable partition. This subdivision is considered unacceptable because a random graph yields better results. The index takes strongly negative values when each node in the network is treated as a separate subgroup. Generally, negative modularity values indicate the absence of meaningful subgroups or communities within the network structure. This is a clear signal that the division does not exhibit the expected community characteristics, implying that the network lacks cohesive internal groupings. In practice, acceptable modularity values range from 0.3 to 0.7, although higher values may occasionally appear (Newman & Girvan, 2004, p. 7).
Maximizing modularity is known to be an NP-hard problem, meaning that it can only be approximated using heuristic and approximation algorithms (Fortunato & Castellano, 2012, p. 500). Fortunato (2010), in his comprehensive review of community detection in graphs, discusses various classes of heuristic algorithms, such as greedy, genetic, simulated annealing, spectral, and tabu search, each offering different levels of success depending on the network’s size and complexity.
To divide Greece’s production system into clusters, two different modularity-based approaches were used: (a) the Louvain method reported by Blondel et al. (2008) and (b) the Girvan–Newman method modified by Arenas et al. (Girvan & Newman, 2002; Newman, 2004; Arenas et al., 2007, 2008). Both methods are tailored to directed, weighted networks and use the modularity index to evaluate the network partitions they produce, ultimately proposing an optimal division into clusters.6
The first method, Louvain, aggregates each node with others in the network, recalculating the modularity at each step until the division that maximizes the modularity is found (Blondel et al., 2008, pp. 3–4). The second method successively splits the network by removing edges with the highest betweenness and recalculates the modularity at every stage. These two methods differ in the algorithms they use to calculate modularity. Given that the computation of modularity falls into the category of NP-hard problems (Fortunato & Castellano, 2012, p. 500), it can only be addressed using stochastic, heuristic optimization algorithms. The Louvain method employs a greedy algorithm (Fortunato, 2010, pp. 101–102), while the modified Girvan–Newman method, as adapted by Arenas et al., uses a different optimization approach called tabu search. Even though both methods use the modularity as the criterion for evaluating network partitions, they fundamentally differ in their strategies to achieve partitioning and in how they optimize the modularity.
The Louvain method was implemented using Pajek network analysis software 4.10 (Mrvar & Batagelj, 2016). Arenas et al.’s method—a modified version of the Girvan–Newman method—was implemented using Radatools software suite 4.0 (Gómez & Fernández, 2016). Thus, even though both approaches seek to maximize the modularity, their methodologies and algorithmic implementations are distinct, affecting their performance and results in terms of network partitioning.

2.2. Visualization of Results

The visualization of graphs/networks, and consequently, of clusters, is an inherent advantage and key feature of network analysis. For graphs with a relatively limited number of nodes (vertices), such as a few dozen, representation can be relatively simple, often taking the form of a grid. Another option is a circular diagram, which offers an aesthetically appealing result (Krzywinski et al., 2009; Crnovrsanin et al., 2014). However, for graphs or networks with several dozen or even hundreds of nodes, these methods become impractical. In such cases, visualization involves linking nodes/vertices with lines where links exist.
The challenge in these more complex networks is that there is no single way to represent the network graphically (Di Battista et al., 1994, p. 236). Instead, there are theoretically infinite ways to arrange the nodes and edges, as shown in the following figure. For instance, even a simple graph with four vertices and five edges can be represented in at least three equally valid ways (Figure 1). These representations maintain the relationships between nodes (vertices), as indicated by the connecting lines (edges/links), but result in visually different diagrams.
The inherent flexibility in visualizing graphs/networks, and consequently, clusters, introduces subjectivity into how graphs/networks are represented. This characteristic of graphs certainly qualifies the value of immediacy and ease in understanding the relationships depicted through a graphical representation. The final visualization of a graph is not a single, “objective” mathematical outcome but rather a result of a creative design and, ultimately, the researcher’s intent. This flexibility can potentially lead to the “misguiding” of the reader (or even the researcher themselves) since it allows for the presentation of data in a way that might emphasize certain aspects of the relationships—which may not be the most important ones—that are described by the graph.
This issue has led to the development of a subfield within graph theory focused specifically on visualization. This area addresses two interconnected core concerns: (a) aesthetic rules that ensure the readability and understanding of the graph and (b) the creation of algorithms for efficient computer-based graph rendering. The first aspect is directly related to the clarity and interpretability of graphs, while the second focuses on the computational efficiency of algorithms used for visualization. As Di Battista et al. (1999, p. 14) note, “aesthetics specify graphic properties of the drawing that we would like to apply, as much as possible, to achieve readability”. Examples of aesthetic rules include minimizing the crossing of edges, reducing the total diagram area, and ensuring uniformity in the edge length (Di Battista et al., 1999, pp. 15–16).
When it comes to algorithms for implementing graph design rules, it should be noted that these are essentially optimization problems that may not be simultaneously solvable and are also computationally difficult (NP-hard). Considering the issue of computational efficiency, it becomes necessary to prioritize the aesthetic criteria for graph layout. As a result, the final output of these algorithms often involves a combination of “approximation strategies and heuristics” (Di Battista et al., 1999, pp. 16–17). Despite the variety of algorithms available for graph drawing, they generally share a common foundation. Many algorithms used to achieve the final layout rely on a force-directed approach, a model inspired by the basic principles of mechanics (Eades, 1984). The core idea involves treating the edges (links) as springs, which helps to distribute the nodes (vertices) in a balanced way across a two-dimensional space, such as a computer screen, a printer, or a plotter. Variations of this approach underpin the algorithms used in modern software for social network analysis and specialized mathematical tools.
For this article, the Fruchterman and Reingold (1991) algorithm was used, incorporating Lombardi-style curves to aesthetically enhance the diagrams by giving the edges a curved shape (Duncan et al., 2012). The network diagram was created using Gephi ver. 0.901 software (Bastian et al., 2009; Jacomy et al., 2014). The grid-based layout was created using Pajek ver. 4.10 software (Mrvar & Batagelj, 2016), and the circular diagram was created with Circos Table Viewer v. 0.63-10 software (Krzywinski et al., 2009).

2.3. Handling of Data

The data used in this study were from the domestic input–output table for the year 2010 (product by product) in current basic prices (in millions of EUR). This table originates from the official input–output tables for Greece in 2010 (Eurostat, 2013), provided by the European Statistical Office (Eurostat).7 The classification of products and industries follows the Classification of Products by Activity-CPA 2008 (European Union, 2008) for goods and services, and the NACE Rev. 2 Statistical classification of economic activities in the European Community (Eurostat, 2008) for economic activities. The Eurostat data categorize 65 products/industries: 64 according to CPA/NACE classifications plus 1 additional industry, “L68A: Imputed rents of owner-occupied dwellings”.
For simplification, three industries with zero or exceptionally low values in the transactions matrix were removed, as well as five negative values that were economically meaningless, because they reversed the direction of flows and impacts. These values appeared in the output of two industries: N78 (“Employment services”) and I (“Accommodation and food services”). Specifically, the negative values amounted to EUR 0.48 million for N78 (across three entries) and EUR 1.06 million for I (across two entries). These were adjusted to zero, with a negligible overall impact, as the matrix’s total transactions amount to approximately EUR 111 billion, resulting in an effect of around 0.01‰.
Additionally, three industries with negligible or zero presence were completely removed: U (“Services provided by extraterritorial organizations and bodies”), L68A (“Imputed rents of owner-occupied dwellings”), and T (“Services of households as employers; undifferentiated goods and services produced by households for own use”). These industries made no contribution to the added value and did not show any significant transactions.
Following the adjustments mentioned previously, the dimensions of the matrix became 62 × 62 (reduced from the 65 × 65 version officially published by Eurostat), containing a total of 3844 entries. Of these, 416 entries (10.8%) were zeros, compared to 780 zeros (18.5%) in the original matrix. Further simplification eliminated very small transaction values, which were replaced with zero. As a result, the number of zero entries increased to 2328 (60.6% of the total). It should be noted that this adjustment preserved 98% of the original sum of values from the 62 × 62 matrix before the interventions, amounting to EUR 109.077 billion out of EUR 111.614 billion. This modified matrix was subsequently used for cluster identification and visualization using the method described earlier.
In the presentation and commentary on the results, industries appearing in clusters were categorized by technology level and knowledge intensity. This categorization followed Eurostat’s guidelines (see Eurostat, 2016). The intensity of research and technological development (R&D) was used to classify two-digit manufacturing industries, using R&D expenditures as a percentage of gross value added. Four categories emerged: High Technology (HT), Medium–High Technology (MHT), Medium–Low Technology (MLT), and Low Technology (LT).
For service industries, the criterion was the percentage of employees in the corresponding two-digit economic activity industries who have a tertiary education degree. These service industries were classified in line with the two main categories in manufacturing (i.e., high and low technology) into two primary groups: Knowledge-Intensive Services (KIS) and Less-Knowledge-Intensive Services (LKIS). Furthermore, the first category (KIS) was subdivided into Knowledge-Intensive Market Services (KI_m_S), High Technology Knowledge-Intensive Services (Ht_KIS), Knowledge-Intensive Financial Services (KI_f_S), and Other Knowledge-Intensive Services (O_KIS). Less-Knowledge-Intensive Services were subdivided into Less-Knowledge-Intensive Market Services (LKI_m_S) and Other Less-Knowledge-Intensive Services (O_LKIS).
It should be emphasized that all the previous technology and knowledge intensity categories exclude the three industries of the primary sector as well as certain secondary sector industries, namely Mining (B), Electricity–Gas (D35), Water Supply (E36), Waste Management (E37–E39), and Construction (F). Due to the absence of an “official” classification from Eurostat, we designated these industries as “traditional” and marked them with the label “TR” in the related tables.
In the tables and commentary that follow, industries are identified using the NACE Rev. 2 classification codes. The description of the industries used for presentation purposes is a shortened version of their official description, which is provided in Appendix A.

3. Results

3.1. The Clusters and the Reliability of the Division

The outcome of dividing the transaction matrix into five clusters is shown in Table 1. It is important to note that, using both methods for maximizing the modularity (the Louvain method and the Girvan–Newman method modified by Arenas et al.), the initial division produced a sixth “cluster”, which consisted of the “isolated” industry H53 Postal Services. After a separate analysis of its connections and to achieve a more coherent presentation of the results, this industry was integrated into the “Mega-cluster”. Due to the large size of the Mega-cluster (24 industries), incorporating Postal Services as its 25th member did not affect its overall character.
Differences between the two methods were observed in only two cases:
  • Industry M74_M75 Other Scientific Services: The Louvain method placed it in the “Mega-cluster”, while the Arenas et al. method (i.e., the modified G-N method) placed it in the “Knowledge–Education” cluster.
  • Industry S95 Repair of Computers and Household Appliances: The Louvain method placed it in the “Construction” cluster, while the Arenas et al. method placed it in the “Mega-cluster”.
Overall, both methods produced nearly identical results, revealing the internal organization of the production system into six initial clusters, which were effectively consolidated into five cohesive groups (clusters). From a technical perspective, based on the modularity coefficient (Q), the Arenas et al. method yielded a value of Q = 0.2923 for the division into six clusters, while the Louvain method produced a value of Q = 0.3005. It should be noted that the Arenas et al. method approaches the resolution limit issue differently, arriving at an optimal solution that includes resolution considerations (Arenas et al., 2008). In contrast, the Louvain method allows for the parameterization of the resolution limit (r), which affects the results. The default value in Pajek is r = 1, but for this study, after extensive testing, the value r = 0.95 was selected, which is very close to the default.
The reliability of the division into five clusters was tested using the E-I index developed by Krackhardt and Stern (1988, p. 127). This index, which is used in social network analysis, compares the number of links (edges) outside the clusters (Εl) with those within the clusters (Il). This index is formulated as follows:
E I = E l I l E l + I l
The E-I index is the ratio of the difference between the external and internal links of the nodes (industries) within the clusters to the total number of links in the entire network (production system). To calculate the index, the underlying graph is considered without taking into account the direction of the links, effectively transforming it into an undirected network with loops. The index theoretically has a maximum value of +1 when all the links are external to the clusters, meaning that each node forms its own “cluster”, and a minimum value of −1 when all the links are internal to the clusters, indicating a fully partitioned network. Thus, the smaller the index value, the better the network is divided into cohesive subgroups, as a lower value indicates higher internal cohesion and introversion.
The results were obtained using the specific implementation of the index in the Ucinet v.6 social network analysis software (Borgatti et al., 2002). To better interpret the results, the weights of the links were disregarded during the calculation. This means that in the adjacency matrix (transaction matrix), any values greater than zero were replaced with one. The final adjusted (rescaled) value of the index was EI = −0.533. The negative value on the scale from −1 to +1 clearly indicates that the network (i.e., the production system), with the given division into five clusters, is introverted and that the clusters are significantly cohesive.

3.2. Main Characteristics of Clusters and Visualization of Results

Based on the results obtained with both methods, the Greek production system is organized into five clusters (Table 1, Figure 2, Figure 3 and Figure 4). These clusters are as follows:
  • Agriculture–Tourism Cluster: This cluster comprises eight industries, namely the three industries of the primary sector (Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishing), the Food–Beverages industry, and Accommodation–Restaurants, which is the basic industry of Tourism.
  • Energy–Transport Cluster: Consisting of nine industries, this cluster includes the Electricity, Mining, and Petroleum industries. It also encompasses all the Transportation and Warehousing industries (excluding Postal Services).
  • Construction Cluster: This cluster includes eight industries related to the production of Metal and Non-metallic products, Machinery manufacturing, and the Construction and Architects–Engineers industries.
  • Knowledge–Education Cluster: Encompassing twelve industries, this cluster contains most of the knowledge-intensive industries, particularly those connected to Mass Media, Communication, Education, and Research and Development.
  • Mega-Cluster: This is the largest cluster, consisting of twenty-five industries. It includes Real Estate, Public Administration, Health and Social Care, Trade, Chemical, Plastic, Pharmaceutical production, the Financial industry, and various other industries. This cluster forms the core of the production system in terms of the volume of total gross value added (GVA) produced in Greece.

4. Discussion

4.1. The Production System as a Whole

Based on the division results, the production system and its clusters are visualized in three distinct ways: as a grid diagram, as a circular chord diagram and as a network diagram. Figure 2 shows the modified transaction matrix rearranged according to the division into clusters in the form of a square grid. It has 62 rows and 62 columns, which reflects the number of industries in the transaction matrix. Its gray-scaled cells represent transactions between industries as a percentage of the total interindustry transactions. There are three shades of gray, along with white, which indicates the absence of transactions.
The vertical and horizontal dark lines indicate the boundaries of the clusters. The internal transactions between the industries of the clusters appear on the main diagonal and form squares with dimensions equal to the number of industries participating in each cluster. From this image, it is apparent that the intensity and density of the links is greater around the main diagonal—that is, within the clusters.
In the circular chord diagram (Figure 3), industries are arranged clockwise according to their clusters, starting from the “twelve o’clock” position. Each cluster is color-coded (green for the Agriculture–Tourism cluster, red for the Energy–Transport cluster, and so on). The chords are colored based on the originating industry.
The circle’s inner perimeter is divided into arcs corresponding to the number of industries, with the length of each arc being proportional to the industry’s transaction volume (both inputs and outputs). The outer perimeter is similarly divided, with the arc lengths being proportional to the total transaction volume. The arcs are segmented into percentages, with each segment’s color indicating transactions with other industries. Moving inward, the first layer of arcs represents the industry’s outputs (to itself and others), and the second layer depicts inputs. Industries are ordered from those with the largest to the smallest transaction volume along these three perimeters.
In Figure 4, the production system is presented as a network, with clusters distinguished by different colors assigned to the nodes/vertices (industries). The lines (links) are colored according to the industry of origin (representing output), and their thickness reflects the transaction size. The size of each node and the font size of the industry labels correspond to the “influence” of the industry, measured by the eigenvector centrality (PageRank).8
Table 2 summarizes the main economic characteristics of the clusters. The ratio of the transaction value within the clusters to that outside them indicates the effectiveness of the division: 56% of the total transaction value occurs internally. The Mega-cluster stands out in terms of most economic metrics (except exports). Despite its large number of industries, it has significant internal cohesion, with 53% of its transaction value occurring within the cluster. It also contributes more than 53% of total gross value added of the production system, which is equivalent to the gross domestic product of the country minus taxes on products plus subsidies on products. The presence of such a large grouping, or “giant component”, in real networks such as production systems is common and can include most of the network’s nodes.9
The second most significant cluster, based on several indicators, is the Agriculture–Tourism cluster, which has a comparatively much smaller number of industries (eight) but exhibits exceptional internal cohesion, with almost 80% of its transaction value occurring within the cluster. It also makes a substantial contribution to employment (24.3%) and to final demand (19%).
The Construction cluster also demonstrates high cohesion (68%) and contributes significantly to employment (12.2%) and exports (12%). On the other hand, the Knowledge–Education cluster has the lowest cohesion (39%) and the smallest contribution to exports, despite having a relatively large number of industries (12). Nevertheless, it features the highest technical coefficient of gross value added (66%). The Energy–Transport cluster is characterized by high external orientation (extroversion 39.5%) and remarkable export performance (52.5%) but makes a lower contribution to employment. These five clusters are described in greater detail and depicted diagrammatically in the following sections.

4.2. Agriculture–Tourism Cluster

The Agriculture–Tourism cluster consists of eight industries: the primary sector industries (A01 Agriculture, A02 Forestry, A03 Fishing), C10_C12 Food–Beverages, I Accommodation and Restaurants, C33 Repair/Installation of Machinery, S94 Membership Organizations, and S96 Personal Services. This cluster therefore combines the primary, manufacturing, and service sectors. The name of the cluster underscores the prominence of agricultural production and tourism activity in the cluster, as is evident in the following paragraphs.
As shown in Table 3, the Agriculture–Tourism cluster demonstrates a high degree of cohesion, with almost 80% of its transaction value occurring within the cluster. It significantly contributes to employment (24.3%), demand (18.8%), added value (15.2%), and exports (9.2%). The technical coefficient of added value is relatively high (52.7%), while the index of external orientation (Extroversion) is low (6.4%), well below the average (11.1%).
The Agriculture–Tourism cluster is structured around the relationship between the industries A01, C10, C12, C33, and I. This forms a robust agriculture–food–tourism axis, complemented by inputs and outputs from industry S94 to I and from A01 and C33, as well as outputs from C33 primarily directed toward A01. Industries A02, A03, and S96 complete the cluster, with smaller transaction flows to C33 (for the first two) and to I and S94 (for S96). This composition suggests that this cluster equally produces goods and services, as seen from its added value structure. A significant share of its production is directed toward international markets, particularly those of industries A03, A01, and C10-C12, and I, although for the latter (tourism from abroad), this is not captured in the input–output tables.
From the circular diagram (Figure 5), it is apparent that this cluster’s structure revolves around three key industries, namely Agriculture, Food–Beverages, and Accommodation–Restaurants, with the other industries playing a complementary role. This structure is illustrated differently in the network diagram (Figure 6), where the importance of each industry is depicted by the size of the network nodes (vertices) and labels. This importance is measured using the eigenvector centrality index (“PageRank”), and the thickness of the lines represents the volume of transactions. The network diagram highlights the prominence of A01 Agriculture, C10–C12 Food–Beverages, I Accommodation–Restaurants, and S94 Membership Organizations, which primarily receive outputs from industries I and C10–C12.
Finally, from a technological perspective, as shown in Table 3, this is a low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive cluster. Only C33 Repair/Installation of Machinery is a medium–low technology industry, while the others are either traditional (the three primary sector industries) or low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive industries.

4.3. Energy–Transport Cluster

The Energy–Transport cluster (Figure 7 and Figure 8) consists of nine industries: B Mining, C19 Petroleum Products, D35 Electricity–Gas, E36 Water Supply, H49 Land Transport, H50 Water Transport, H51 Air Transport, H52 Warehousing, and N77 Rental and Leasing Activities. As shown in Table 4, this cluster could alternatively be described as the Export cluster, as it accounts for more than half of the country’s exports (52.5%). However, considering that all the transport and logistics services along with the energy production industries are found in this cluster, it is appropriate to name it the Energy–Transport cluster.
This cluster has moderate cohesion, with the value of the inter-industry transactions divided equally between internal and external transactions (50–50). At the industry level, Mining (B), Electricity–Gas (D35), Petroleum Products (C19), and Warehousing (H52) display a clear “introversive” orientation, meaning that most of their transaction value occurs with other industries within the cluster rather than with the rest of the production system, as indicated in the relevant columns (Outputs, Inputs) of the table. The remaining industries in the cluster exhibit varying degrees of volume of external transactions, interacting more with industries outside the cluster.
The Energy–Transport cluster makes a relatively low contribution to employment (5.6%) and has a low technical coefficient of added value (38.3%). This indicates that this cluster is characterized by low added value or, conversely, a high intensity of intermediate inputs. Most of the industries in this cluster are classified as low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive. Only industries H50 Water Transport and H51 Air Transport are classified as knowledge-intensive (ΚΙ_m_S), while the C19 Petroleum Products industry is medium–low technology (MLT). In Figure 7 and Figure 8, the cluster’s structure is illustrated, which is centered around Mining (B), Petroleum Products (C19), Electricity–Gas (D35), and Transportation (primarily maritime H50 but also land H49). Complementing this core structure are industries such as H52 Warehousing, H51 Air Transport, N77 Rental/Leasing Activities, and E36 Water Supply. The D35 Electricity–Gas industry serves as a supplier for all the other industries within the cluster, as do C19 Petroleum Products and N77 Rental and Leasing Activities. The B Mining industry primarily supplies C19 Petroleum Products and D35 Electricity–Gas, while H50 Water Transport receives inputs mainly from H52 Warehousing and C19 Petroleum Products, with minimal outputs.
Considering the overall characteristics of the Energy–Transport cluster and the industries that comprise it, this cluster emerges as a critical component of the production system, primarily due to its strong orientation toward the international market. Several of its industries are internationally competitive, notably H50 Water Transport, C19 Petroleum Products, and H52 Warehousing.

4.4. Construction Cluster

The Construction cluster (Figure 9 and Figure 10) is composed of eight industries, including six manufacturing industries: C16 Wood, C23 Non-Metallic Products, C24 Basic Metals, C25 Metal Products, C27 Electrical Equipment, and C28 Machinery. It also includes F Construction and M71 Architects–Engineers from the service sector. This cluster is particularly cohesive, with over two-thirds of its transactions (0.68) occurring internally (Table 5). Most industries, except for C28 Machinery and M71 Architects–Engineers, engage in internal transactions in terms of either outputs or inputs. Its name underlines the central role of the Construction industry in the cluster.
The Construction cluster is the smallest of the five clusters in terms of production volume, contributing only 7.3% of the total gross value added (GVA). Nearly half of this output (3.6%) comes solely from the Construction (F) industry. The other half comes from the other five industries, each contributing less than 1% of the total GVA of the production system. The added value technical coefficient is the lowest among all five clusters (33.5%) due to the exceptionally low values across its industries, some of the lowest in the production system.
Generally, apart from the Construction industry, this cluster consists of relatively small industries. This is reflected in the modest share of total employment (12.7%) and demand (10.7%) of the cluster, with the Construction industry accounting for the majority (7.5% in employment and 8.1% in demand). Despite the small size of its industries, the Construction cluster has a notable export contribution (11.9% of total exports of the production system), mainly from its six manufacturing industries. The C24 Basic Metals industry leads exports (5.2%), followed by the C27 Electrical Equipment industry (2.1%), with the remaining four Manufacturing industries contributing 2.9%. This export strength is evident in the high export index (Extroversion) of most Manufacturing industries in the cluster.
Technologically, most industries in the Construction cluster are of low or medium–low technology (LT, MLT), apart from M71 Architects–Engineers, which is knowledge-intensive (ΚΙ_m_S), while the Construction (F) industry is traditional (T). However, the central role of the Construction industry enables it to activate other industries in the cluster through its backward linkages, 65% of which are internal. Most industries, with the internal forward linkages ranging from 58% to 96%, are interconnected within the cluster. This means that changes in the demand for the Construction industry can propagate through inter-industry relationships and stimulate demand for higher-technology and knowledge-intensive industries, such as C27 Electrical Equipment (medium–high technology), C28 Machinery (medium–high technology), and M71 Architects–Engineers (knowledge-intensive).

4.5. Knowledge–Education Cluster

The Knowledge–Education cluster is composed of 12 industries; one is a Manufacturing industry and 11 are from the Service sector (Figure 11 and Figure 12). Its name highlights two primary characteristics: the economic significance of the Education (P85) industry and the high concentration of service industries in this cluster, with 11 out of a total of 21 knowledge-intensive service industries in the production system being in this cluster. Alternatively, it could also be called the Knowledge–Communication cluster, as at least six of its industries are involved in producing, supporting, and managing traditional mass and newer Internet-based interactive communication media. These include C18 Printing, J58 Publishing, J59_J60 Cinema–TV, J61 Telecommunications, J62_J63 Computer–Information Services, and M73 Advertising. Additionally, this cluster incorporates activities from the R90-R92 Creative Activities and Gambling industry, which include the R90 Creative Arts and Entertainment industry.
Many of these industries rely on telecommunications services provided by J61 Telecommunications as well as on the production and services of C18 Printing and J58 Publishing to create and manage mass communication and entertainment. These industries represent the majority of the so-called “creative industries”, which employ the members of the “creative class” (Florida, 2012, pp. 35–62). Ultimately, the name Knowledge–Education cluster was preferred because of the economic structure of the cluster and the significance of knowledge production and dissemination, which is primarily a result of educational processes.
One distinguishing feature of the Knowledge–Education cluster, as shown in Table 6, is its relatively low cohesion (0.39) compared to the other four clusters in the production system. It also makes the smallest contribution to demand (10.5%) and is the second smallest in terms of employment (12.3%) and gross value added (13.4%). The significance of P85 Education is evident in its impact on these indicators, as it accounts for approximately half or more of the cluster’s total value in each case. Aside from Education, no other industry makes a notable contribution to employment, with Education itself representing 7.5%.
This is a cluster that operates with a very high technical coefficient of added value (66%), the highest among the five clusters and above the overall production system average (55.6%). According to the detailed industry-specific data in Table 6, this high coefficient arises from the extremely high values in certain industries. Most industries in this cluster use minimal intermediate inputs, and in some cases, such as J61 Telecommunications, J58 Publishing, and R90–R92 Creative Activities–Gambling, a significant portion of their transactions are intra-industry.
On the other hand, M73 Advertising (9.8%) and M72 Research and Development (27.1%) have relatively high volumes of inputs. This cluster performs particularly poorly in exports (3.2%), with the highest export-contributing industry, J62_J63 Computer–Information Services, contributing only 0.8% to the total exports of the production system. Similarly, this cluster has a low external orientation (Extroversion) index (3.3%), with nearly all its industries, except for M72 Research and Development (12.5%) and J62_J63 Computer–Information Services (17.3%), having significantly lower values than the production system average (11.1%). This indicates that while the cluster is composed of knowledge-intensive services, it lacks an export orientation. The exceptions are M72 Research and Development and J62_J63 Computer–Information Services, which show potential for exports.

4.6. Mega-Cluster

The Mega-cluster, as suggested by its name, is the largest cluster in the production system in terms of almost all aspects except for exports (Table 7). It consists of 25 industries in total: 10 from the secondary sector (8 of which are manufacturing) and 15 from the service sector. It includes some of the largest industries by employment, such as G47 Retail Trade (12.3%), O84 Public Administration (8.5%), and Q86 Health (4.7%), as well as some of the strongest in terms of demand and added value, like L68 Real Estate (10.3% and 15.1%, respectively), O84 Public Administration–Defense (9.9% and 8.7%), and G46 Wholesale Trade (6.3% and 6.0%).
In terms of exports, the Mega-cluster ranks second (23.0%), but this is largely due to the sheer number of its industries rather than the strength of any individual export industry. It is a cohesive cluster, the third highest in terms of cohesion among the five clusters, with 53% of its transaction volume occurring internally. This cohesion persists despite the cluster having twice or even more than triple the number of industries (25) compared to the other clusters (8 to 12). Almost all of its industries have a transaction index for both inputs and outputs that exceeds 0.5.
The relatively high degree of cohesion makes further division attempts unreliable. When the cluster was subjected to the same division process as the overall network (a production system composed of 62 industries), using the same method (modularity optimization algorithms including the Louvain and Arenas et al. based on the modified G-N method), the results were inconsistent. The Louvain method produced three new sub-clusters: one with a single isolated industry (C13-C15 Textiles–Apparel), a second with six industries that could be referred to a “healthcare-pharmaceutical sub-cluster” (including C20 Chemicals, C21 Pharmaceuticals, C22 Plastics, C31_C32 Furniture, and healthcare and social welfare services Q86 Health, Q87_Q88 Social Care), and a third sub-cluster containing the remaining 18 industries. The Arenas et al. method resulted in five sub-clusters, with only the isolated C13-C15 Textiles–Clothing sub-cluster matching the Louvain results. The remaining four sub-clusters varied, with two containing four industries each and two containing nine industries each.
The significant variation in the results between the two methods indicates that further division of the Mega-cluster is particularly unreliable. The outcome from the Lou-vain method seems to make more economic sense, as it identifies a grouping centered around healthcare and social welfare services, along with the pharmaceutical industry, drawing in related industries like chemicals and plastics. Additionally, this division has a higher modularity index (Q = 0.2681) compared to the second method (Q = 0.1575). It should be noted, however, that the modularity values in both cases are significantly lower than those for the main division, which were Q = 0.3005 for the Louvain method and Q = 0.2923 for the Arenas et al. method. Overall, these results are insufficient to confidently claim that the production system consists of seven or, even more unlikely, nine clusters. Nevertheless, these findings can guide a better understanding of how the Mega-cluster functions, especially when combined with diagrammatic representations.
The diagrams reveal the density of the inter- and intra-industry relationships within the Mega-cluster, contributing to its relatively high cohesion index. In the circular diagram (Figure 13), the quantitative prominence of the Trade industries (G45, G46, G47) is evident, marked with brown-shaded arcs and connections, both forward and backward. The second most significant group is the Financial sector (K64 Financial Services, K65 Insurance, and K66 Other Financial Services), depicted in gray shades. Business service providers (M69_M70 and N80–N82) and N79 Travel Agencies, marked in shades of blue, form another major group with strong ties to both the Trade and Financial sectors.
The L68 Real Estate industry, shown in dark green, also has notable links with Trade and Finance. Public sector industries (O84 Public Administration, Q85 Health, and Q86_Q87 Social Care), shaded in purple, mainly serve as recipients of forward linkages from other industries within the cluster. The linkage between Q86 Health and C21 Pharmaceuticals and C31_C32 Furniture is notable, which justifies their appearance as a separate “healthcare-pharmaceutical sub-cluster” in the Louvain results. The Manufacturing industries, marked in red, have a relatively small size but maintain a significant number of inter-industry linkages within the cluster. Lastly, the diagrams show that H53 Postal Activities and C13-C15 Textiles–Apparel have a higher volume of intra-industry linkages compared to inter-industry ones, explaining their isolation as individual clusters in the initial production system division and the Mega-cluster sub-division attempts.
The network diagram (Figure 14) of the Mega-cluster emphasizes the topological significance of industries rather than the volume of inter-industry relations highlighted in the previous circular chord diagram. In this visualization, as with the corresponding diagrams for the other clusters, the size and placement of the industries (nodes/vertices) indicate their importance or “influence” within the network (cluster). This influence is summarized by the eigenvector centrality (PageRank), which considers both the number and strength of the linkages as well as the significance of the connected industries.
The network diagram of the Mega-cluster reveals three groups of industries:
  • Public Sector Industries: Including O84 Public Administration and Defense and Q86 Health.
  • Trade Industries: Comprising G46 Wholesale Trade, G47 Retail Trade, and G45 Automotive Trade and Repairs.
  • Financial Sector Industries: Consisting of K64 Financial Services and K65 Insurance.
The L68 Real Estate industry is less prominent in this network view compared to the previous circular diagram, while the M69_M70 Legal–Accounting Services and N80–N82 Protection and Other Services industries, despite being positioned peripherally, have some influence on the cluster’s dynamics. Notably, C21 Pharmaceuticals and C31_C32 Furniture, located near Q86 Health at the top of the diagram, and the nearby Q86_Q87 Social Care, C20 Chemicals, and C22 Plastics form the “healthcare-pharmaceutical sub-cluster” previously identified.
The Mega-cluster exhibits a balance between high-technology and knowledge-intensive industries on the one hand and low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive industries on the other. Specifically, this cluster includes five high- and medium–high-technology industries and five low- and low–medium-technology industries (including E37–E39 Waste Management). In the service sector, there are eight knowledge-intensive industries and seven less-knowledge-intensive ones, totaling 13 high-technology and knowledge-intensive industries versus 12 low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive industries.
Despite this numerical balance, the outcomes of the cluster favor low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive production. High-technology (HT and MHT) and knowledge-intensive industries (KI_f_S and O_KIS) contribute 21.5% to the total gross value added (GVA) of the production system, compared to 31.7% for low-technology (LT, MLT and TR) and less-knowledge-intensive industries (LKI_m_S and O_LKIS). Similarly, in terms of employment, high-technology (HT and MHT) and knowledge-intensive industries (KI_f_S and O_KIS) account for 20%, while less-intensive ones account for 23.6%. For the overall demand, the figures are 19.2% versus 25%, and for exports, they are 6.8% versus 16.2%, respectively. Thus, despite the numerical balance, the Mega-cluster operates as a low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive cluster.
The Mega-cluster contributes 43.6% of the total employment in the production system, making it the second most labor-intensive cluster after the Agriculture–Tourism cluster. However, the employment distribution is highly uneven among its industries. G47 Retail Trade alone accounts for 12.3% of employment, and when combined with G46 Wholesale Trade (3.7%) and G45 Trade and Repair of Motor Vehicles (2.0%), the Trade industries collectively contribute 18.0%. The next most significant industry is O84 Public Administration and Defense, contributing 8.5%, while the whole public sector, i.e., including Q86 Health (4.7%) and Q87_Q88 Social Care (0.9%), contributes 14.1% of employment.
The remaining employment in this cluster is distributed mainly across the industries of the secondary sector, including the nine manufacturing industries and E37-E39 Waste Management (4.2%), along with business support services (3.9%) and the financial sector (2.6%). Finally, L68 Real Estate, H53 Postal Services, and S95 Computer Repairs contribute minimal employment shares at 0.1%, 0.5%, and 0.3%, respectively.
This cluster’s share in adding to the total demand is equally significant as in employment, reaching 44.2%. Of this total, almost a quarter (10.3%) is attributed to the L68 Real Estate industry. The O84 Public Administration industry has a similar share of 9.9%, and when combined with the other public sector industries, Q86 Health (5.5%) and Q87_Q88 Social Care (0.4%), the total demand of the public sector reaches 15.8%.
The Trade industries collectively contribute to the total demand with a smaller but still substantial share of 11.5%, distributed among G46 Wholesale Trade (6.3%), G47 Retail Trade (3.3%), and G45 Trade and Repair of Motor Vehicles (1.9%). Manufacturing industries, along with E37–E39 Waste Management, provide a combined 3.6%, while the remaining eight industries together add 3.0%. Notably, K64 Financial Services stands out among these, with a contribution of 1.2%.
The 25 industries within the Mega-cluster collectively contribute more than half (53.2%) of the gross value added (GVA) of the production system. The most significant contributor is the L68 Real Estate industry, which accounts for 15.1% of the total GVA. The O84 Public Administration and Defense industry is the second most significant, contributing 8.7%, while the entire public sector (including Q86 Health at 4.6% and Q87_Q88 Social Care at 0.3%) collectively contributes 13.7%.
The Trade industries collectively provide 12.0% of the GVA, with G46 Wholesale Trade standing out at 6.0%. The nine Manufacturing industries have a relatively weak presence, contributing only 2.1% in total. Interestingly, the M69_M70 Legal and Accounting Services industry alone makes the same contribution of 2.1%. Lastly, the Financial sector contributes 4.7%, with K64 Financial Services accounting for 3.7 percentage points of this total.
The Mega-cluster functions with a very high value added technical coefficient (65.1%), making it the second “high-value-added” cluster of the production system, with the Knowledge–Education cluster being the first. This high coefficient is due to the significant value added contributions from some of its main industries. Notably, the L68 Real Estate industry has a value added technical coefficient of 93.2%, that of O84 Public Administration and Defense stands at 71.8%, that of Q86 Health is 67.6%, K64 Financial Services has a value added technical coefficient of 69.3%, and that of G45 Trade and Repair of Motor Vehicles is at 66.4%.
Exports are the only economic category in which the Mega-cluster does not rank first among the production system’s clusters, despite having the largest number of industries. It holds the second largest share of exports (23.0%), following the Energy–Transport cluster (52.5%). However, it also has the second lowest export orientation (Extroversion) index (5.6%), just ahead of the Knowledge–Education cluster (3.3%). This is the reason why, considering its size, its export volume appears relatively low. Notably, only 9 out of the 25 industries in the cluster have an export orientation index (Extroversion) equal to or higher than the production system average (11.1%).
The very low export performance of the cluster should be, to some extent, expected given the nature of several industries in the cluster, which are almost exclusively domestic-market-oriented (e.g., L68 Real Estate, O85 Public Administration and Defense, Q87_Q88 Social Care). Even though most manufacturing industries in this cluster are export-oriented, their small size results in a limited overall contribution to exports (9.0%). By contrast, the Trade industries, despite their very low export orientation indices, contribute a significant 10.6% to exports due to their size.
In summary, the Mega-cluster is a central structural element of the production system, not only due to the number of industries it encompasses but also because of the scale of its economic outcomes, particularly in terms of employment, demand, and most significantly, the creation of added value. It is a cohesive cluster structured around three main groups of industries: the Public sector, Trade, and the Financial sector. Except for its Manufacturing industries, the rest of this cluster does not exhibit a significant outward orientation, leading to relatively low export performance. Finally, while it operates at high levels of added value, the economic impact of the Mega-cluster is predominantly driven by low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive industries, despite a numerical balance between high-technology and knowledge-intensive and low-technology and less-knowledge-intensive industries.

5. Conclusions

The aim of this article was to present a method for identifying and visualizing clusters, as well to apply this method, using Greece as a case study. This was achieved by treating the transaction matrix of the input–output table as a graph (or network) and employing graph-theoretical division methods and visualization techniques. The modularity method of network analysis yielded reliable results. As demonstrated, the domestic input–output table of the production system of Greece reveals five functional internal industry groupings (clusters). It is important to note that these five clusters appear to follow an economic logic, with all of them being organized cohesively around the key industries that define their main characteristics.
The Agriculture–Tourism cluster is built around the primary production industries (Agriculture, Forestry, and Fishing), the Food–Beverages industry, and the Accommodation–Restaurants industry. The Energy–Transport cluster is structured around the Mining, Petroleum, Electricity, and Transport industries. The Construction cluster consists of various manufacturing industries that all interact significantly with the Construction sector, and it also includes services related to Architecture and Engineering. The Knowledge–Education cluster is mainly composed of service industries tied to knowledge creation and dissemination (such as Research and Development and Education) and all types of communication (print, publishing, television, film, etc.). The Mega-cluster, the fifth identified cluster, serves to validate the division’s effectiveness, as, according to the relevant literature, large clusters of this kind frequently appear in real networks. This cluster is organized around three distinct axes: public sector industries (Public Administration, Defense, and Health), Trade, and Financial Services. Additionally, there is evidence of a potential functional Health–Pharmaceutical sub-cluster.
From the overall study of the structure of the clusters, the weak presence of manufacturing industries in the production system is evident. Although there is complete diversification, i.e., all the industries of the NACE Rev. 2 classification are present in the production system of Greece, most manufacturing industries make a low contribution to the majority of indicators in the production system. Furthermore, the overall picture is that the production system lags behind in terms of technology and knowledge.
This article’s approach to clusters prioritizes functional–economic rather than geographic proximity. However, given Greece’s geographical scale and the spatial structure of its economy, there are also geographic dimensions too. It is well known that economic activity in Greece is heavily concentrated in two major urban centers (Athens and Thessaloniki) and that tourism is prominent in certain island and coastal regions of the country. The existence of regional clusters could be a fruitful future research direction, supported by regional input–output tables and other regional economic data. Furthermore, future updated research using the latest available data could show if, how, and to what extent the economic crisis in Greece affected the structure and functionality of the clusters in the production system.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Dataset available on request from the author.

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflicts of interest.

Appendix A. NACE Rev. 2 Classification Codes and Descriptions of Industries

NACE Rev.2 CodesShort DescriptionDescription
1A01AgricultureCrop and animal production, hunting and related service activities
2A02ForestryForestry and logging
3A03FishingFishing and aquaculture
4BMiningMining and quarrying
5C10–C12Food–BeveragesManufacture of food products, beverages and tobacco products
6C13–C15Textiles–Apparel Manufacture of textiles, manufacture of wearing apparel and manufacture of leather and related products
7C16WoodManufacture of wood and of products of wood and cork, except furniture; manufacture of articles of straw and plaiting materials
8C17PaperManufacture of paper and paper products
9C18PrintingPrinting and reproduction of recorded media
10C19Petroleum productsManufacture of coke and refined petroleum products
11C20ChemicalsManufacture of chemicals and chemical products
12C21PharmaceuticalsManufacture of basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations
13C22Plastic productsManufacture of rubber and plastic products
14C23Non-metallic mineral productsManufacture of other non-metallic mineral products
15C24Basic metalsManufacture of basic metals
16C25Metal productsManufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment
17C26Computers–ElectronicsManufacture of computer, electronic and optical products
18C27Electrical equipment Manufacture of electrical equipment
19C28MachineryManufacture of machinery and equipment n.e.c.
20C29Motor vehiclesManufacture of motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers
21C30Other transport equipmentManufacture of other transport equipment
22C31_C32Furniture—other manufacturingManufacture of furniture, other manufacturing
23C33Repair-installation of machineryRepair and installation of machinery and equipment
24D35Electricity–GasElectricity, gas, steam and air conditioning supply
25E36Water supplyWater collection, treatment and supply
26E37–E39Waste managementSewerage, waste management and remediation activities
27FConstruction Construction
28G45Trade and repair of motor vehiclesWholesale and retail trade and repair of motor vehicles and motorcycles
29G46Wholesale tradeWholesale trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles
30G47Retail tradeRetail trade, except of motor vehicles and motorcycles
31H49Land transportLand transport and transport via pipelines
32H50Water transportWater transport
33H51Air transportAir transport
34H52WarehousingWarehousing and support activities for transportation
35H53Postal activitiesPostal and courier activities
36IAccommodation–RestaurantsAccommodation and food service activities
37J58PublishingPublishing activities
38J59_J60Cinema–TelevisionMotion picture, video and television program production, sound recording and music publishing activities; Programming and broadcasting activities
39J61TelecommunicationsTelecommunications
40J62_J63Computer–Information servicesComputer programming, consultancy and related activities; Information service activities
41K64Financial servicesFinancial service activities, except insurance and pension funding
42K65InsuranceInsurance, reinsurance and pension funding, except compulsory social security
43K66Other financial services Activities auxiliary to financial services and insurance activities
44L68BReal estateReal estate activities
45L68AImputed rents of owner-occupied dwellingsImputed rents of owner-occupied dwellings
46M69_M70Legal, accounting, management activitiesLegal and accounting activities; Activities of head offices; management consultancy activities
47M71Architects–EngineersArchitectural and engineering activities; technical testing and analysis
48M72Research and developmentScientific research and development
49M73AdvertisingAdvertising and market research
50M74_M75Other scientific activitiesOther professional, scientific and technical activities; Veterinary activities
51N77Rental/leasing activitiesRental and leasing activities
52N78Employment activitiesEmployment activities
53N79Travel agenciesTravel agency, tour operator and other reservation service and related activities
54N80–N82Security, services to buildingsSecurity and investigation activities; Services to buildings and landscape activities; Office administrative, office support and other business support activities
55O84Public administration, defense, social security Public administration and defense; compulsory social security
56P85EducationEducation
57Q86HealthHuman health activities
58Q87_Q88Social careResidential care activities; Social work activities without accommodation
59R90-R92Creative activities–GamblingCreative, arts and entertainment activities; Libraries, archives, museums and other cultural activities; Gambling and betting activities
60R93Sports–RecreationSports activities and amusement and recreation activities
61S94Membership organizationsActivities of membership organizations
62S95Repair of computers and household goodsRepair of computers and personal and household goods
63S96Personal services Other personal service activities
64TActivities of households as employersActivities of households as employers of domestic personnel; Undifferentiated goods- and services-producing activities of private households for own use
65UExtraterritorial organizations Activities of extraterritorial organizations and bodies
Source: (Eurostat, 2008) and own elaboration.

Notes

1
In the intervening period, clusters were introduced in the form of “growth poles” by Perroux (1950, 1955/1970) and Boudeville (1966), only to be abandoned some years later, along with spatial Keynesianism, in the 1970s. However, clusters reappeared in the same decade and into the early 1980s, occasionally either under their current name (clusters) or as “industrial complexes” (Czamanski, 1971; Czamanski & Ablas, 1979; Loviscek, 1982; Huallachain, 1984).
2
This article draws from Foutakis (2019).
3
Examples include Rasmussen (1957), Hirschman (1958/1960), and Chenery and Watanabe (1958). For an in-depth discussion, see Sonis and Hewings (2009) and Miller and Blair (2009).
4
Applications in input–output analysis have emerged over the past 15 years (Muñiz et al., 2011; Miller & Blair, 2009; Montresor & Marzetti, 2008), especially for Greece, see Aroche-Reyes and Garcia-Muniz (2018) and Tsekeris (2017).
5
A random graph (or network) is an unstructured graph, first studied by Erdös and Rényi in 1959. In such a graph, “the probability of having an edge between a pair of vertices is equal for all possible pairs”, whereas “real networks are not random graphs, as they display big inhomogeneities, revealing a high level of order and organization”. Additionally, “the distribution of edges is not only globally, but also locally inhomogeneous, with high concentrations of edges within special groups of vertices, and low concentrations between these groups. This feature of real networks is called community structure, or clustering” (Fortunato, 2010, pp. 76–77). Comparing a real network with its null model confirms whether a true community structure exists. For more on random networks, see (Fortunato, 2010; Newman, 2010, Chapters 12–13).
6
A more recent method, as suggested by anonymous reviewer two, whom we thank, is the Leiden algorithm (Traag et al., 2019), which is considered by its authors to be an improvement over the Louvain method. We intend to test it in future research.
7
The link provided in the references section (Eurostat, 2013) is no longer available from Eurostat. The original Eurostat tables for Greece are available from the author on demand.
8
The PageRank eigenvector centrality index (Brin & Page, 1998) was used, implemented in the network analysis software Gephi 0.901, which was also used to create the network visualizations of the production system. The concept behind the eigenvector centrality is that the “a vertex’s importance in a network is increased by having connections to other vertices that are themselves important […] eigenvector centrality gives each vertex a score proportional to the sum of the scores of its neighbors” (Newman, 2010, p. 169). For a detailed discussion and presentation of eigenvector centrality, including PageRank, see (Newman, 2010, pp. 169–181).
9
For more on giant components in networks, see Newman (2003, 2010) and Barabási (2014).

References

  1. Amin, A. (1999). An institutionalist perspective on regional economic development. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 23, 365–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Amin, A., & Thrift, N. (1995). Institutional issues for the European regions: From markets and plans to socioeconomics and powers of association. Economy and Society, 24, 41–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Arenas, A., Duch, J., Fernández, A., & Gómez, S. (2008). Size reduction of complex networks preserving modularity. New Journal of Physics, 10, 1–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Arenas, A., Fernández, A., & Gómez, S. (2007). Analysis of the structure of complex networks at different resolution levels. New Journal of Physics, 9, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Aroche-Reyes, F., & Garcia-Muniz, A. S. (2018). Modelling economic structures from a qualitative input–output perspective: Greece in 2005 and 2010. Metroeconomica, 69, 251–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Barabási, A. -L. (2014). Network science. Creative Commons License. Available online: https://networksciencebook.com/chapter/9 (accessed on 5 December 2024).
  7. Bastian, M., Heymann, S., & Jacomy, M. (2009, 17–20 May). Gephi: An open source software for exploring and manipulating networks. Third International AAAI Conference on Weblogs and Social Media, San Jose Mc Enery Convention Center (pp. 1–2), San Jose, CA, USA. [Google Scholar]
  8. Blondel, V. D., Guillaume, J. -L., Lambiotte, R., & Lefebvre, E. (2008). Fast unfolding of communities in large networks. Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment, 2008, P10008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Borgatti, S., Everett, M., & Freeman, L. (2002). Ucinet for windows: Software for social network analysis. Analytic Technologies. [Google Scholar]
  10. Boudeville, J. -R. (1966). Problems of regional economic planning. Edinburgh University Press. [Google Scholar]
  11. Brin, S., & Page, L. (1998). The anatomy of a large-scale hypertextual web search engine. Computer Science and ISDN Systems, 30, 107–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Chenery, H. B., & Watanabe, T. (1958). International comparisons of the structure of production. Econometrica, 26, 487–521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Cook, P. (2002). Knowledge economies. Clusters, learning and cooperative advantage. Routledge. [Google Scholar]
  14. Cook, P., & Morgan, K. (1998). The associational economy: Firms, regions, and innovation. Oxford Press. [Google Scholar]
  15. Crnovrsanin, T., Muelder, C. W., Faris, R., Felmlee, D., & Ma, K. -L. (2014). Visualization techniques for categorical analysis of social networks with multiple edge sets. Social Networks, 37, 56–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Czamanski, S. (1971). Some empirical evidence of the strengths of linkages between groups of related industries in urban-regional complexes. Papers of the Regional Science Association, 27, 136–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Czamanski, S., & Ablas, L. A. d. (1979). Identification of industrial clusters and complexes: A comparison of methods and findings. Urban Studies, 16, 61–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Di Battista, G., Eades, P., Tamassia, R., & Tollis, I. G. (1994). Algorithms for drawing graphs: An annotated bibliography. Computational Geometry, 4, 235–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Di Battista, G., Eades, P., Tamassia, R., & Tollis, I. G. (1999). Graph drawing: Algorithms for the visualization of graphs. Prentice Hall. [Google Scholar]
  20. Duncan, C. A., Eppstein, D., Goodrich, M. T., Kobourov, S. G., & Nöllenburg, M. (2012). Lombardi drawings of graphs. Journal of Graph Algorithms and Applications, 16(1), 37–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Eades, P. (1984). A heuristic for graph drawing. Congressus Numerantium, 42(11), 149–160. [Google Scholar]
  22. European Union. (2008). Regulation (EC) No 451/2008 of the European parliament and of the council of 23 April 2008 establishing a new statistical classification of products by activity (CPA) and repealing council regulation (EEC) No 3696/93. Available online: http://data.europa.eu/eli/reg/2008/451/2019-07-26 (accessed on 6 December 2024).
  23. Eurostat. (2008). NACE rev. 2 Statistical classification of economic activities in the european community. Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. [Google Scholar]
  24. Eurostat. (2013). Input-output tables for Greece (2005–2010), version 2, 24 January 2013, MS-Excel file: Greece_suiot_130124. [Dataset available on request from the author].
  25. Eurostat. (2016). High-tech industry and knowledge-intensive services (HTEC). Annexes, Annex 3: High-Tech Aggregation by NACE Rev. 2. Available online: https://goo.gl/MmZmRf (accessed on 5 December 2024).
  26. Florida, R. (1995). Toward the learning region. Futures, 27, 527–536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Florida, R. (2012). The rise of the creative class, revisited. Basic Books. [Google Scholar]
  28. Fortunato, S. (2010). Community detection in graphs. Physics Reports, 486, 75–174. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Fortunato, S., & Castellano, C. (2012). Community structure in graphs. In R. A. Meyers (Ed.), Computational complexity: Theory, techniques, and applications (pp. 490–512). Springer. [Google Scholar]
  30. Foutakis, D. (2019). Restructuring of local production systems and spatial competitiveness: Theoretical interpretations and the Greek experience [Ph.D. thesis, (In Greek). Panteion University of Social and Political Sciences]. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Fruchterman, T. M. J., & Reingold, E. M. (1991). Graph drawing by force-directed placement. Software-Practice and Experience, 21, 1129–1164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Girvan, M., & Newman, M. E. J. (2002). Community structure in social and biological networks. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 99, 7821–7826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Gómez, S., & Fernández, A. (2016). Radatools. A Set of Freely Distributed Applications to Analyze Complex Networks, Ver. 4.0. Available online: https://webs-deim.urv.cat/~sergio.gomez/radatools.php (accessed on 5 December 2024).
  34. Hellenic Statistical Authority-ELSTAT. (2010). Labour Force Survey (LFS), Quarterly Data, 2nd Quarter 2010. Analytical data provided by ELSTAT on demand. [Google Scholar]
  35. Hirschman, A. O. (1960). The strategy of economic development (3rd printing ed.). Yale University Press. (Original work published 1958). [Google Scholar]
  36. Huallachain, B. O. (1984). The Identification of Industrial Complexes. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 74, 420–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Jacomy, M., Venturini, T., Heymann, S., & Bastian, M. (2014). ForceAtlas2, a continuous graph layout algorithm for handy network visualization designed for the Gephi software. PLoS ONE, 9, e98679. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Krackhardt, D., & Stern, R. N. (1988). Informal networks and organizational crises: An experimental simulation. Social Psychology Quarterly, 51, 123–140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Krzywinski, M., Schein, J., Birol, Ç., Connors, J., Gascoyne, R., Horsman, D., Jones, S. J., & Marra, M. A. (2009). Circos: An information aesthetic for comparative genomics. Genome Research, 19, 1639–1645. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  40. Leontief, W. (1986). Input-Output Economics (2nd ed.). Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  41. Loviscek, A. L. (1982). Industrial cluster analysis-backward or forward linkages? The Annals of Regional Science, 16, 36–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Marshall, A. (1964). Principles of Economics (8th ed.; sixth reprint). Macmillan. (Original work published 1890). [Google Scholar]
  43. Martin, R., & Sunley, P. (2003). Deconstructing clusters: Chaotic concept or policy panacea? Journal of Economic Geography, 3(1), 5–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Miller, R. E., & Blair, P. D. (2009). Input–output analysis: Foundations and extensions (2nd ed.). Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
  45. Montresor, S., & Marzetti, G. V. (2008). Constructing intersectoral innovation diffusion networks with input-output: How to get relative flows? An illustrative application to six OECD technological systems for the middle ’90 (Working Paper No. 649/2008, pp. 1–30). Department of Economics Bologna.
  46. Morgan, K. (1997). The learning region: Institutions, innovation, and regional renewal. Regional Studies, 31, 491–503. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Morgan, K., & Nauwelaers, C. (1999). A regional perspective to innovation: From theory to strategy. In K. Morgan, & C. Nauwelaers (Eds.), Regional innovation strategies. The challenge for less-favored regions. The Stationary Office and Regional Studies Association. [Google Scholar]
  48. Mrvar, A., & Batagelj, V. (2016). Pajek: Analysis and visualization of large networks (ver. 4.10). Available online: http://mrvar.fdv.uni-lj.si/pajek/ (accessed on 5 December 2024).
  49. Muñiz, A. S. G., Raya, A. M., & Carvajal, C. R. (2011). Core periphery valued models in input-output field: A scope from network theory. Papers in Regional Science, 90, 111–121. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Newman, M. E. J. (2003). Mixing patterns in networks. Physical Review E, 67, 026126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Newman, M. E. J. (2004). Analysis of weighted networks. Physical Review E—Statistical, Nonlinear, and Soft Matter Physics, 70, 056131-1–056131-9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Newman, M. E. J. (2010). Networks: An Introduction. Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
  53. Newman, M. E. J., & Girvan, M. (2004). Finding and evaluating community structure in networks. Physical Review E—Statistical, Nonlinear, and Soft Matter Physics, 69(2 Pt 2), 026113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Perroux, F. (1950). Economic space: Theory and applications. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64, 89–104. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Perroux, F. (1970). Note on the concept of ‘growth poles’. In D. L. MacKee, R. D. Dean, & W. H. Leahy (Eds.), Regional economics (pp. 93–103). The Free Press. (Original work published 1955). [Google Scholar]
  56. Porter, M. E. (1998). The competitive advantage of the nations (New Edition with updates in an Introduction by the Author). Macmillan. [Google Scholar]
  57. Rasmussen, P. N. (1957). Studies in inter-sectoral relations (E. Harck, Ed.; 2nd printing). Revue Économique. [Google Scholar]
  58. Scott, J. (2000). Social network analysis, a handbook (2nd ed.). Sage Publications. [Google Scholar]
  59. Sonis, M., & Hewings, G. J. D. (2009). New Developments in Input–output analysis: Fields of influence of changes, the temporal leontief inverse and the reconsideration of classical key sector analysis. In M. Sonis, & G. J. D. Hewings (Eds.), Tool kits in regional science: Theory, models, and estimation (pp. 69–117). Springer. Chapter 3. [Google Scholar]
  60. Storper, M. (1997). The regional world: Territorial development in a global economy. The Guilford Press. [Google Scholar]
  61. Traag, V. A., Waltman, L., & van Eck, N. J. (2019). From Louvain to Leiden: Guaranteeing well-connected communities. Scientific Reports, 9, 5233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Tsekeris, T. (2017). Network analysis of inter-sectoral relationships and key sectors in the Greek economy. Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination, 12, 413–435. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Wasserman, S., & Faust, K. (1994). Social network analysis. Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Different representations of the same graph.
Figure 1. Different representations of the same graph.
Economies 13 00015 g001
Figure 2. Visualization of the production system and its clusters as a grid.
Figure 2. Visualization of the production system and its clusters as a grid.
Economies 13 00015 g002
Figure 3. Circular chord diagram of the production system and its clusters.
Figure 3. Circular chord diagram of the production system and its clusters.
Economies 13 00015 g003
Figure 4. Network diagram of the production system and its clusters.
Figure 4. Network diagram of the production system and its clusters.
Economies 13 00015 g004
Figure 5. Circular diagram of the Agriculture–Tourism cluster.
Figure 5. Circular diagram of the Agriculture–Tourism cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g005
Figure 6. Network diagram of the Agriculture–Tourism cluster.
Figure 6. Network diagram of the Agriculture–Tourism cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g006
Figure 7. Circular diagram of the Energy–Transport cluster.
Figure 7. Circular diagram of the Energy–Transport cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g007
Figure 8. Network diagram of the Energy–Transport cluster.
Figure 8. Network diagram of the Energy–Transport cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g008
Figure 9. Circular diagram of the Construction cluster.
Figure 9. Circular diagram of the Construction cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g009
Figure 10. Network diagram of the Construction cluster.
Figure 10. Network diagram of the Construction cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g010
Figure 11. Circular diagram of the Knowledge–Education cluster.
Figure 11. Circular diagram of the Knowledge–Education cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g011
Figure 12. Network diagram of the Knowledge–Education cluster.
Figure 12. Network diagram of the Knowledge–Education cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g012
Figure 13. Circular diagram of the Mega-cluster.
Figure 13. Circular diagram of the Mega-cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g013
Figure 14. Network diagram of the Mega-cluster.
Figure 14. Network diagram of the Mega-cluster.
Economies 13 00015 g014
Table 1. Clusters in the production system of Greece, 2010.
Table 1. Clusters in the production system of Greece, 2010.
CodeDescription of Cluster and Industry CodeDescription of Cluster and Industry
A.AGRICULTURE–TOURISMD.KNOWLEDGE–EDUCATION (cont.)
1.A01Agriculture6.M72Research and development
2.A02Forestry7.M73Advertising
3.A03Fishing8.M74_M75 *Other scientific activities
4.C10–C12Food–Beverages9.N78Employment activities
5.C33Repair/installation of machinery10.P85Education
6.IAccommodation–Restaurants11.R90-R92Creative activities—Gambling
7.S94Membership organizations12.R93Sports–Recreation
8.S96Personal services E.MEGA-CLUSTER
Β.ENERGY–TRANSPORT1.C13–C15Textiles–Apparel
1.BMining2.C17Paper
2.C19Petroleum products3.C20Chemicals
3.D35Electricity–Gas4.C21Pharmaceuticals
4.E36Water supply5.C22Plastic products
5.H49Land transport6.C26Computers–Electronics
6.H50Water transport7.C29Motor vehicles
7.H51Air transport8.C30Other transport equipment
8.H52Warehousing9.C31_C32Furniture–Other manufacturing
9.N77Rental/leasing activities10.E37–E39Waste management
C.CONSTRUCTION11.G45Trade and repair of motor vehicles
1.C16Wood12.G46Wholesale trade
2.C23Non-metallic mineral products13.G47Retail trade
3.C24Basic metals14.H53 **Postal activities
4.C25Metal products15.K64Financial services
5.C27Electrical equipment 16.K65Insurance
6.C28Machinery17.K66Other financial services
7.FConstruction18.L68Real estate
8.M71Architects–Engineers19.M69_M70Legal, accounting, management activities
D.KNOWLEDGE–EDUCATION20.N79Travel agencies
1.C18Printing21.N80-N82Security, services to buildings
2.J58Publishing22.O84Public administration, defense
3.J59_J60Cinema–Television23.Q86Health
4.J61Telecommunications24.Q87_Q88Social care
5.J62_J63Computer–Information services25.S95 *Repair of computers and household goods
Source: Modified transaction matrix. Data processed with the Louvain and Arenas et al. methods. (*) These industries were appointed by the Louvain method: (a) M74_M75 to cluster E, (b) S95 to cluster C. (**) The industry H53 in the original divisions of both methods was a separate “cluster”.
Table 2. Main economic characteristics of the clusters.
Table 2. Main economic characteristics of the clusters.
ClustersIndustries (Num.)Transactions Inside
Cluster
Employment (%)Demand (%)Added ValueExports
(%)Technical Coefficient (%)Extroversion
A. Agriculture–Tourism80.7824.318.815.252.79.26.4
B. Energy–Transport90.505.615.310.238.352.539.5
C. Construction80.6812.210.77.333.511.910.9
D. Knowledge–Educ.120.3912.310.513.466.03.23.3
E. Mega-Cluster250.5343.644.253.265.123.05.6
Production System *620.5698.099.599.355.699.811.1
Source: Domestic input–output table for Greece 2010 (Eurostat, 2013, Table 18). Labour Force Survey, 2010 (ELSTAT, 2010). Own processing. (*) Industry “T Activities of households as employers” not included. This is why the sum of employment, demand and value added does not add up to 100%. The sum of exports is not 100% due to rounding. Transactions inside cluster = the ratio of the value of transactions between the industries of the cluster to the value of the sum of all the transactions of the industries of the cluster (2010). Employment % = Employment as a percentage of total employment (2010). Demand % = Demand as a percentage of total demand (final use), 2010. Added Value % = percentage (%) of total added value 2010. Technical Coefficient = GVA as a percentage total value of production (P.1), 2010. Exports % = the value of exports of the industries of the cluster as a percentage of total value of exports, 2010. Extroversion = Exports as a percentage of total value of production (P.1), 2010.
Table 3. Agriculture–Tourism cluster: main economic characteristics.
Table 3. Agriculture–Tourism cluster: main economic characteristics.
NACE CodeDescriptionTechnologyTransactions
Inside Cluster
Empl. (%)Demand (%)Added ValueExports
OutputInput(%)Technical Coefficient (%)Extroversion
A01AgricultureTR0.970.4711.92.02.550.13.213.0
A02ForestryTR0.520.520.10.00.058.004.3
A03FishingTR1.000.330.40.40.464.60.928.9
C10–C12Food–BeveragesLT0.880.443.15.93.641.25.111.7
C33Repair/installation of machineryMLT0.320.010.30.00.254.100
IAccommodation–RestaurantsLKI_m_S0.380.376.87.86.762.700
S94Membership organizationsO_LKIS0.340.340.41.50.733.400
S96Personal services O_LKIS0.690.511.21.21.178.800
Total Agriculture–Tourism Cluster0.7824.318.815.252.79.26.4
Table 4. Energy–Transport cluster: main economic characteristics.
Table 4. Energy–Transport cluster: main economic characteristics.
NACE CodeDescriptionTechnologyTransactions
Inside Cluster
Empl. (%)Demand (%)Added ValueExports
OutputInput(%)Technical Coefficient (%)Extroversion
BMiningTR0.980.300.30.10.347.50.412.4
C19Petroleum productsMLT0.560.480.23.81.014.510.731.3
D35Electricity–GasTR0.420.720.61.82.353.80.52.2
E36Water supplyTR0.100.500.20.20.248.100
H49Land transportLKI_m_S0.190.382.42.11.543.30.53.0
H50Water transportΚΙ_m_S0.410.470.76.23.747.037.496.0
H51Air transportΚΙ_m_S0.280.540.20.60.328.1118.2
H52WarehousingLKI_m_S0.800.450.90.30.642.01.927.6
N77Rental/leasing activitiesLKI_m_S0.380.160.10.10.351.10.13.4
Total Energy–Transport Cluster0.505.615.310.238.352.539.5
Table 5. Construction cluster: main economic characteristics.
Table 5. Construction cluster: main economic characteristics.
NACE CodeDescriptionTechnologyTransactions
Inside Cluster
Empl. (%)Demand (%)Added ValueExports
OutputInput(%)Technical Coefficient (%)Extroversion
C16WoodLT0.670.540.50.00.229.70.13.1
C23Non-metallic mineral productsMLT0.960.340.60.20.750.50.811.1
C24Basic metalsMLT0.830.520.50.80.624.45.243.5
C25Metal productsMLT0.650.481.20.40.733.30.76.4
C27Electrical equipment MHT0.620.470.30.40.342.82.167.9
C28MachineryMHT0.310.420.20.50.350.11.342.9
FConstructionTR0.500.647.58.13.631.81.42.5
M71Architects–EngineersΚΙ_m_S0.580.091.50.30.935.40.32.3
Total Construction Cluster0.6812.210.77.333.511.910.9
Table 6. Knowledge–Education cluster: main economic characteristics.
Table 6. Knowledge–Education cluster: main economic characteristics.
NACE CodeDescriptionTechnologyTransactions
Inside Cluster
Empl. (%)Demand (%)Added ValueExports
OutputInput(%)Technical Coefficient (%)Extroversion
C18PrintingLT0.260.040.60.00.244.60.00.2
J58PublishingO_KIS0.430.430.41.21.362.00.44.1
J59_J60Cinema–TelevisionHt_KIS0.770.590.40.50.330.50.35.1
J61TelecommunicationsHt_KIS0.370.580.71.92.763.60.73.5
J62_J63Computer–Information servicesHt_KIS0.320.490.50.40.664.00.817.3
M72Research and developmentHt_KIS0.830.500.20.20.127.10.212.5
M73AdvertisingΚΙ_m_S0.340.490.40.10.29.80.34.5
M74_M75Other scientific activitiesΚΙ_m_S0.110.520.50.20.547.50.37.0
N78Employment activitiesΚΙ_m_S0.650.300.10.00.192.80.00.0
P85EducationO_KIS0.270.487.54.85.794.50.10.2
R90-R92Creative activities—GamblingO_KIS0.640.940.71.21.679.80.10.7
R93Sports–RecreationO_KIS0.620.490.40.10.134.90.00.2
Total Knowledge–Education Cluster0.3912.310.513.466.03.23.3
Table 7. Mega-cluster: main economic characteristics.
Table 7. Mega-cluster: main economic characteristics.
NACE CodeDescriptionTechnologyTransactions Inside ClusterEmpl. (%)Demand (%)Added ValueExports
OutputInput(%)Technical Coefficient (%)Extroversion
C13–C15Textiles–Apparel LT0.830.851.10.80.542.92.945.5
C17PaperLT0.570.850.20.30.229.50.311.1
C20ChemicalsMHT0.520.700.30.50.327.62.245.5
C21PharmaceuticalsHT0.970.780.40.50.558.61.945.7
C22Plastic productsMLT0.500.790.30.20.118.11.024.9
C26Computers–ElectronicsHT0.370.760.10.10.158.400
C29Motor vehiclesMHT0.870.690.10.10.148.00.115.7
C30Other transport equipmentMHT0.180.640.20.10.165.00.114.0
C31_C32Furniture—other manufacturingLT0.920.521.00.50.333.60.511.7
E37–E39Waste managementTR0.580.400.50.40.758.10.69.4
G45Trade and repair of motor vehiclesLKI_m_S0.320.772.01.92.366.41.26.6
G46Wholesale tradeLKI_m_S0.380.693.76.36.046.36.29.5
G47Retail tradeLKI_m_S0.400.6812.33.33.755.23.29.4
H53Postal activitiesO_LKIS0.650.830.50.00.337.40.01.1
K64Financial servicesKI_f_S0.610.641.81.23.669.30.83.1
K65InsuranceKI_f_S0.390.900.40.50.444.60.818.2
K66Other financial servicesKI_f_S0.620.740.40.00.676.400
L68Real estateLKI_m_S0.690.610.110.315.193.200
M69_M70Legal, accounting, management activitiesΚΙ_m_S0.570.622.40.42.162.20.84.5
N79Travel agenciesLKI_m_S0.580.590.30.40.331.600
N80–N82Security, services to buildingsLKI_m_S0.550.531.20.21.753.00.21.2
O84Public administration, defense, social security O_KIS1.000.598.59.98.771.800
Q86HealthO_KIS0.860.874.75.54.667.60.10.3
Q87_Q88Social careO_KIS0.810.480.90.40.355.800
S95Repair of computers and household goodsLKI_m_S0.350.770.30.30.481.60.14.8
Total Mega-Cluster0.5343.644.253.265.123.05.6
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Foutakis, D. Identification and Visualization of Clusters Using Network Theory Methods: The Case of the Greek Production System. Economies 2025, 13, 15. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13010015

AMA Style

Foutakis D. Identification and Visualization of Clusters Using Network Theory Methods: The Case of the Greek Production System. Economies. 2025; 13(1):15. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13010015

Chicago/Turabian Style

Foutakis, Dimitris. 2025. "Identification and Visualization of Clusters Using Network Theory Methods: The Case of the Greek Production System" Economies 13, no. 1: 15. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13010015

APA Style

Foutakis, D. (2025). Identification and Visualization of Clusters Using Network Theory Methods: The Case of the Greek Production System. Economies, 13(1), 15. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies13010015

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop